Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-s22k5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-03T00:51:29.985Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Endogenous reward is a bridge between social/cognitive and behavioral models of choice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 January 2025

George Ainslie*
Affiliation:
Department of Veterans Affairs Medical Center, Coatesville, PA, USA [email protected] www.picoeconomics.org
*
*Corresponding author.

Abstract

Endogenous reward (intrinsic reward at will) is a fiat currency that is occasioned by steps toward any goals which are challenging and/or uncommon enough to prevent its debasement by inflation. A “theory of mental computational processes” should propose what properties let goals grow from appetites for endogenous rewards. Endogenous reward may be the universal selective factor in all modifiable mental processes.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ainslie, G. (1992). Picoeconomics: The strategic interaction of successive motivational states within the person. Cambridge U.Google Scholar
Ainslie, G. (2005). Précis of Breakdown of Will. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28(5), 635673.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ainslie, G. (2013). Grasping the impalpable: The role of endogenous reward in choices, including process addictions. Inquiry, 56, 446469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ainslie, G. (2017). De gustibus disputare: Hyperbolic delay discounting integrates five approaches to choice. Journal of Economic Methodology, 24(2), 166189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ainslie, G. (2023). Behavioral construction of the future. Psychology of Addictive Behaviors, 37(1), 1324.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ainslie, G., & Monterosso, J. (2005). Why not emotions as motivated behaviors? Behavior and Brain Sciences, 28, 194195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beecher, H. K. (1948). Pain in men wounded in battle. Annals of Surgery, 123(1), 96105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior. Plenum.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldwater, B. C. (1972). Psychological significance of pupillary movements. Psychological Bulletin, 77(5), 340.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Heyman, G. M., & Moncaleano, S. (2021). Behavioral psychology's matching law describes the allocation of covert attention: A choice rule for the mind. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 150(2), 195.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Keramati, M., Smittenaar, P., Dolan, R. J., & Dayan, P. (2016). Adaptive integration of habits into depth-limited planning defines a habitual-goal-directed spectrum. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113(45), 1286812873.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Miller, N. (1969). Learning of visceral and glandular reÂsponses. Science, 163, 434445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murayama, K. (2022). Motivation resides only in our language, not in our mental processes. In Bong, M., Kim, S., & Reeve, J. (Eds.), Motivation science: Controversies and insights. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rachlin, H. (1995). Behavioral economics without anomalies. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 64, 396404.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Read, D., Lowenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (1999). Choice bracketing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19(1), 171197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Redish, A. D. (2016). Vicarious trial and error. Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 17(3), 147159.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed