We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
At any moment in time, you can ride a bike with least effort by cycling in first gear. But if you want to ride around the block with least effort, first gear will not be ideal. By failing to distinguish between these two different situations, economists have recommended the worst possible climate change policy to governments. Contrary to their belief, emissions trading will achieve decarbonisation at maximum cost, and minimum speed.
Governments may impose a carbon emission charge to address environmental externalities. If implemented, this will drive up the cost of energy-intensive production. To level the playing field, domestic carbon pricing can be extended to carbon-embedding imports. The recent legislative movements in the EU and elsewhere show that the issue of adjusting carbon prices at the border is entering the mainstream of climate policymaking. At the same time, carbon is not the only target of energy-affecting trade control measures. Other typical examples of such measures include air quality regulations with import-restrictive impacts and the localization of clean energy production, which some States may portray as environmentally necessary. Products with health-threatening content associated with unsafe energy use can face market access barriers as well. When energy production causes ecological or public health problems at home or depletes natural resources, export restrictions are usually among candidate measures that governments consider for mitigating such adverse effects. Therefore, it is imperative to examine trade rules and case law to check the legality of these energy–environment measures.
Political opposition to fiscal climate policy, such as a carbon tax, typically appeals to fiscal conservative ideology. Here, we ask to what extent public opposition to the carbon tax in Canada is, in fact, ideological in origin. As an object of study, ideology is a latent belief structure over a set of issue topics—and in particular their relationships—as revealed through stated opinions. Ideology is thus amenable to a generative modeling approach within the text-as-data paradigm. We use the Structural Topic Model, which generates word content from a set of latent topics and mixture weights placed on them. We fit the model to open-ended survey responses of Canadians elaborating on their support of or opposition to a carbon tax, then use it to infer the set of mixture weights used by each response. We demonstrate this set, moreso than the observed word use, serves efficient discrimination of opposition from support, with near-perfect accuracy on held-out data. We then operationalize ideology as the empirical distribution of inferred topic mixture weights. We propose and use an evaluation of ideology-driven beliefs based on four statistics of this distribution capturing the specificity, variability, expressivity, and alignment of the underlying ideology. We find that the ideology behind responses from respondents who opposed the carbon tax is more specific and aligned, much less expressive, and of similar variability as compared with those who support the tax. We discuss the implications of our results for climate policy and of broad application of our approach in social science.
To get to a net-zero-carbon economy, we will need a new generation of sustainable technologies and the financing infrastructure to channel novel ideas into viable products and companies.
Border Carbon Adjustments (BCAs) may play an important role in lowering the economic costs of greenhouse gas mitigation and in overcoming political-economy constraints on the use of carbon taxes or equivalent measures. A carbon tax plus a full BCA could deal with the competitiveness challenges arising from carbon taxes by using the WTO's National Treatment principle to apply equal levies on domestic production and on imports, and by symmetrically rebating the carbon tax on exports in the manner of a value-added tax (VAT) export rebate. This approach would shift the base for carbon taxation from production to demand and potentially achieve substantial reductions in the cost of cutting emissions. It would avoid the massive measurement and compliance problems associated with BCAs based on foreign emission intensities. By contrast, import-only BCAs distort prices of importables relative to exportables; create divisive trade conflicts and deterioration in the terms of trade for developing countries; and likely require development of complex sets of import preferences.
Edited by
Alan Fenna, Curtin University, Perth,Sébastien Jodoin, McGill University, Montréal,Joana Setzer, London School of Economics and Political Science
Drawing on abundant fossil fuels endowments, Canada has built one of the most carbon-intensive economies in the world. Within the Canadian federation, provincial governments control the vast majority of natural resources, including both hydro-electric potential and fossil fuels. However, the uneven distribution of those resources has yielded tremendous variation in the carbon intensity of provincial economies, and equally great variation in provincial governments’ climate ambitions. In this chapter, I identify three phases in Canadian climate federalism. From 1990 to 2006 a ‘joint decision trap’ prevailed in which the most fossil fuel-dependent provinces vetoed national solutions. From 2007 to 2015 a truncated innovation and diffusion dynamic emerged in which provincial leaders adopted ambitious and sometimes innovative climate policies. However, fossil fuel-dependent provinces did not follow their lead. Emissions reductions hard won by provincial leaders were undone by emissions growth by their recalcitrant neighbours. The third phase, since 2016, is characterised by federal unilateralism. While the mere threat of federal action initially yielded provincial collaboration in an ambitious pan-Canadian climate plan, successful implementation ultimately turned on the federal government’s willingness to follow on that threat. I conclude that, on balance, federalism has exacerbated the challenge of climate action in Canada.
At any moment in time, you can ride a bike with least effort by cycling in first gear. But if you want to ride around the block with least effort, first gear will not be ideal. By failing to distinguish between these two different situations, economists have recommended the worst possible climate change policy to governments. Contrary to their belief, emissions trading will achieve decarbonisation at maximum cost, and minimum speed.
The limited success of employment-based social protection measures under the diverging patterns of post-COVID-19 recovery rekindled interest in a social policy framework known as the Basic Income (BI) support. We test the potential of the BI program using five alternative scenarios ranging from households with income less than half of median income to all adults with estimates of their respective fiscal costs. We then employ an applied general equilibrium model to analyze the economy-wide effects and welfare implications for Turkey in the long run through 2030. We evaluate the macroeconomic and welfare effects of both a business-as-usual fiscal program and an alternative (green BI scenario) comprising of (i) carbon tax levied on the fossil fuel producing industry; (ii) corporate income taxation policy reform that aims at expanding the revenue base and consolidation of the fiscal space of the government; and (iii) restructuring of public consumption expenditures by introducing rationality and efficiency in the structure of fiscal expenditures. Our model solutions reveal that a green BI scenario not only achieves a higher GDP and welfare in the medium to long run but also helps Turkey to reduce its carbon emissions in line with the global policy challenges of a green recovery.
We propose a carbon tax policy for Delhi—the most polluted capital globally—which will fundamentally change the energy mix of Delhi’s economy toward clean, green energy and guarantee universal access to electricity, transport, and food, up to a certain amount. Any carbon mitigation strategy needs to alter our dependence on fossil fuels, requiring a systemic overhaul of its energy mix. Implementing a carbon tax will mitigate emissions and mobilise revenue for our proposed redistributive program: Right to Food, Energy, and Travel (RFET). The policy is designed to advocate for the ‘poor over the rich’ to compensate for the ‘rich hiding behind’ the poor by emitting the majority of carbon and pollutants. Using input–output analysis, we estimate the class-wise distribution of carbon emissions in Delhi. We find that the necessary tax would be US$112.5 per metric ton of carbon dioxide in order for this program to work. The free entitlement of fuel and electricity per household comes out to be 2040 kWh per annum, and there is an annual universal travel pass of US$75 per person for use in public transport and an annual per capita availability of food of US$205.
Chapter 8 argues that any steps or program can be effective only if they adopt a justice lens and reject proposed technical and market fixes that threaten to perpetuate the same inequities, corporate agendas, and extractivist mentality that created the climate and ecological crisis in the first place.
The top priority in addressing climate change is to reduce net emissions of greenhouse gases to zero as swiftly as possible. Among the policy instruments for achieving this goal: carbon markets and carbon taxes; subsidies and incentives for energy conservation and for developing renewable energy technologies; building a new network of advanced nuclear reactors to provide carbon-free energy; imposing restraints on deforestation and planting large numbers of new trees; developing powerful new technologies for removing carbon dioxide from the atmosphere; incentivizing private citizens to reduce the carbon footprint of their lifestyles; and introducing new governmental policies for decarbonizing national economies. By combining all these strategies, humankind could realistically reach net zero emissions by the middle years of this century. From that point forward, it can start actively removing existing accumulations of carbon dioxide, eventually bringing global warming to a halt and reversing some of the damage that’s already been done.
Voluntary or local renunciation of fossil fuels will not keep us within a carbon budget, and direct control along the lines of wartime rationing would be overbearing and inefficient. This leaves either carbon taxes or carbon permits as the main instrument. At a first approximation these are mirror images of each other: raising the price to reduce emissions or vice versa. Under uncertainty, however, taxes make prices predictable but leave emissions unpredictable, while permit systems do the reverse, which should be an argument for permits. Moreover, quantity controls better manage interdependent (multiple equilibrium) economic structures than price controls. Real-world implementation has been poor, as seen in the European Trading System and California’s Cap-and-Trade program. The culprits are weak targets, widespread exemptions, handouts to business and abundant offsets. The dismal experience of the Clean Development Mechanism shows that such offsets function mainly as loopholes. Better would be a system of permits with universal coverage, auctioned rather than given away, and not exchangeable for offsets. It should be accompanied by other policies to mitigate the distortions caused by rapid carbon price increases and to accelerate the development of non-carbon energy sources and non-carbon-using goods and services.
Climate change is a time horizon problem. Economics proposes a carbon tax and leaving the rest to the market. Tax levels are calculated by combining an economic growth model with climate projections. Such models predict very little economic impact, at odds with the alarmist projections of climate science. Economic methodology and selective evidence combine to induce complacency. This was endorsed by a Nobel Prize for William Nordhaus, its leading exponent. Complacency was challenged within economics for not being predicted by extrapolation, disregarding future generations, and modelling the risks incorrectly. Economics bears some responsibility for the problem it tries to solve. It ignores non-rational forms of denial, and falls victim to them itself. With no guidance from economics on how to address climate change, the actual approach chosen is central government precommitment, in line with our own time-horizon model.
Chapter 4 focuses on addressing climate change. International action is failing to deliver on slowing greenhouse gas emissions to keep the planet from warming dangerously, yet considerable progress is occurring by some countries, companies, states or provinces, and even cities. The chapter argues that ending the underpricing of fossil fuels is essential to a low-carbon transition. Major economies must lead by removing fossil fuel subsidies and employing carbon taxes and other policies to further reduce the social cost of fossil fuel use, and allocate any resulting revenue to public support for green innovation and key infrastructure investments. Ending the underpricing of fossil fuels in low- and middle-income countries must occur through policies that are compatible with achieving immediate development objectives, such as ending poverty and especially the widespread “energy poverty” in rural areas. Climate policies need also to expand beyond actions by national governments and instead focus on a “bottom-up” strategy that supports and expands initiatives by corporations, local governments and other “subnational” entities that are pushing and innovating low-carbon strategies.
Our review of climate economics begins with the Kaya identity, which portrays our emissions pathway not as a smooth glideslope to net zero but as a tug of war between opposing forces. We then review the stunning impact that continued compounded economic growth could have on the ability of future generations to adapt to climate change, particularly in the Global South. The concepts of externalities and market failures are considered, along with the widely held view that a significant element in any climate solution will need to be some form of carbon tax. The recognition that mitigation comes at a cost leads to the question of climate cost/benefit analysis and the notion that the economically optimal quantum of further climate change that rational actors might prefer would not necessarily be zero. We close by pivoting to fat tails and the extent to which opting for some economically optimal amount of climate change may expose the future to small probabilities of utterly unacceptable outcomes and therefore unjustifiable risks.
The literature on carbon pricing offers competing explanations for the introduction of carbon taxation. This article contributes to the field by highlighting the interaction of dynamic political factors and external pressures in explaining the timing of the adoption of carbon taxes. Focusing on the second wave of European countries, the study combines the multiple streams framework with qualitative comparative analysis to identify conditions favourable to the introduction of carbon taxes. Additional case studies on Ireland and Portugal serve to illuminate the reform process, especially the role of policy entrepreneurs. This approach yields three insights. First, fiscal crises provide political actors with an opportunity to raise environmental taxes. Second, the introduction of carbon taxation is most likely when push and pull factors come together, i.e. when high problem pressure coincides with governments receptive to environmental issues. Finally, the prospects of “green” policy entrepreneurs are strongly determined by their standing within the government.
We test a method for applying a network-based approach to the study of political attitudes. We use cognitive-affective mapping, an approach that visually represents attitudes as networks of concepts that an individual associates with a given issue. Using a software tool called Valence, we asked a sample of Canadians (n = 111) to draw a cognitive-affective map (CAM) of their views on the carbon tax. We treat these networks as a series of undirected graphs and examine the extent to which support for the tax can be predicted based on each graph’s emotional and structural properties. We find evidence that the emotional but not the structural properties significantly predict individuals’ attitudes toward the carbon tax. We also find associations between CAMs’ structural properties (density and centrality) and several measures of political interest. Our results provide preliminary evidence for the efficacy of CAMs as a tool for studying political attitudes. The study data are available at https://osf.io/qwpvd/?view_only=6834a1c442224e72bf45e7641880a17f
This introduction summarizes the nine central chapters that make up this volume. Martin Feldstein examines the structural reasons for relatively high US growth rates, notes fiscal problems inhibiting future growth including in deficits in social insurance programs, and suggests reforms. Flávio Cunha examines how the development of human capital, especially at early ages, affects economic growth. George Borjas analyzes how increased immigration would affect economic growth in the United States. Glenn Hubbard explores the debate between “techno-optimists” and “techno-pessimists” on the growth effects of technological progress, while Timothy Bresnahan examines in detail the commercial applications of Artificial Intelligence Technologies (AITs). Robert Barro estimates the macroeconomic effects of the recently enacted Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, while John Diamond and George Zodrow examine the macroeconomic and distributional effects of a carbon tax. Ross Levine discusses the links between banking and economic prosperity, and Stephen Turnovsky examines the relationships among income, wealth inequality, and economic growth.
Although economic growth has historically been an engine of prosperity in the United States, recent trends have generated uncertainty regarding the prospects for sustaining such growth. Economists disagree about the relative importance of many factors affecting future growth, including rapid technological advances, immigration, the growth of the financial sector, problems with the educational system, increasing income inequality, an aging population, and large fiscal imbalances that have not been addressed by the political system. This collection of chapters, authored by many of today's leading economists, addresses the prospects for economic growth in the United States over the next few decades. During a time of great economic uncertainty, this book engages with both sides in the debate over economic growth, focusing on policy options that increase the prospects for vigorous economic growth in the future.