Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T18:12:45.031Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Partisanship, political constraints, and employment protection reforms in an era of austerity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 October 2012

Sabina Avdagic*
Affiliation:
Department of Politics, University of Sussex, Brighton, UK

Abstract

Why do some governments adopt unpopular reforms entailing far-reaching liberalization of the labor market, while others opt only for marginal adjustments or even regulatory reforms? This paper explains the likelihood of different types of reforms as an effect of different constellations of government partisanship and veto players. Combining the ‘blame avoidance’ and ‘veto players’ logics of politics, I argue that veto players have either a constraining or enabling effect depending on the partisan orientation of government. Liberalization is most likely to be adopted either by right parties facing few veto players, or by left parties in contexts with a high degree of power sharing. Regulatory reforms are most likely when left governments enjoy strong power concentration, but marginal regulation may also be adopted under external pressure by right governments facing many veto players. An analysis of employment protection reforms in 24 European Union countries during 1990–2007 supports the argument that the effect of political constraints and opportunities on the choice of reforms is shaped by partisan differences.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © European Consortium for Political Research 2012 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Allan, J.P.Scruggs, L. (2004), ‘Political partisanship and welfare state reform in advanced industrial societies’, American Journal of Political Science 48(3): 496512.Google Scholar
Allard, G. (2005), ‘Measuring job security over time: in search of a historical indicator’. Instituto de Empressa Working Paper WP-05.Google Scholar
Allard, G. (2010), The Employment Protection Index in OECD Countries, 1950–2008, Madrid: IE Business School.Google Scholar
Alt, J.E.Lowry, R.C. (1994), ‘Divided governments, fiscal institutions, and budget deficits: evidence from the states’, American Political Science Review 88(4): 811828.Google Scholar
Alt, J.E.Lowry, R.C. (2000), ‘A dynamic model of state budget outcomes under divided partisan government’, Journal of Politics 62(4): 10351069.Google Scholar
Amable, B., Gatti, D., Schumacher, J. (2006), ‘Welfare state retrenchment: the partisan effect revisited’. Paris-Jourdamn Sciences Economiques, Working Paper No. 2006–07.Google Scholar
Armingeon, K., Careja, R., Engler, S., Gerber, M., Leimgruber, P.Potolidis, P. (2009), Comparative Political Data Set III: 35 OECD Countries and/or EU-Member Countries, Switzerland: University of Bern.Google Scholar
Avdagic, S. (2012a), ‘EPL Index in Central and Eastern Europe, 1990–2009’. UK Data Archive, Economic and Social Data Service. Retrieved 31 May 2012 from http://store.data-archive.ac.uk:80/store/collectionEdit.jsp?collectionPID=archive:598Google Scholar
Avdagic, S. (2012b), ‘Database of Employment Protection Reforms in Central and Eastern Europe, 1990–2009’. UK Data Archive, Economic and Social Data Service. Retrieved 31 May 2012 from http://store.data-archive.ac.uk:80/store/collectionEdit.jsp?collectionPID=archive:598Google Scholar
Baccaro, L.Rei, D. (2007), ‘Institutional determinants of unemployment in OECD countries: does the deregulatory view hold water?’, International Organization 6(3): 527569.Google Scholar
Baetschmann, G., Staub, K.E.Winkelmann, R. (2011), Consistent Estimation of the Fixed Effects Ordered Logit Model. Discussion Paper No. 5443. Bonn: Institute for Labor Studies (IZA).Google Scholar
Baker, D., Glyn, A., Howell, D.Schmitt, J. (2005), ‘Labor market institutions and unemployment: a critical assessment of the cross-country evidence’, in D. Howell (ed.), Fighting Unemployment. The Limits for Free Market Orthodoxy, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 72118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bawn, K. (1999), ‘Money and majorities in the federal Republic of Germany: evidence for a veto players model of government spending’, American Journal of Political Science 43(3): 707736.Google Scholar
Becher, M. (2010), ‘Constraining ministerial power: the impact of veto players on labor market reforms in industrial democracies, 1973–2000’, Comparative Political Studies 43(1): 3360.Google Scholar
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P.Walsh, P. (2001), ‘New tools and new tests in comparative political economy: the database of political institutions’, World Bank Economic Review 15(1): 165176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blyth, M., Hopkin, J., Pelizzo, R. (2010), ‘Liberalization and cartel politics in Europe: why do centre-left parties adopt market liberal reforms?’ 16th Conference of Europeanists, 15–17 April 2010, Montreal.Google Scholar
Boeri, T., Ruiz, J.I.C.Galasso, V. (2011), ‘The political economy of flexicurity’, The Journal of European Economic Association 10(4): 684715.Google Scholar
Bonoli, G. (2001), ‘Political institutions, veto points, and the processes of welfare state adaptation’, in P. Pierson (ed.), The New Politics of the Welfare State, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 238265.Google Scholar
Braeuninger, T. (2003), ‘Partisan veto players, party preferences, and the composition of government expenditures’. Annual Meeting of the Public Choice Society, March 21–23, Nashville, TN.Google Scholar
Budge, I., Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., Bara, J.Tanenbaum, E. (2001), Mapping Policy Preferences. Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945–1998, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Cameron, C.McCarty, N. (2004), ‘Models of vetoes and veto bargaining’, Annual Review of Political Science 7: 409435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cusack, T.Engelhardt, L. (2007), Parties, Governments and Legislatures Data Set, Berlin: Social Science Center (WZB).Google Scholar
Eichhorst, W., Konle-Seidl, R. (2005), ‘The interaction of labor market regulation and labor market policies in welfare state reform’. Discussion Paper No. 19, Institut für Arbeitsmarkt-und Berufsforschung (IAB).Google Scholar
Eichhorst, W.Marx, P. (2011), ‘Reforming German labor market institutions: a dual path to flexibility’, European Journal of Social Policy 21(1): 7387.Google Scholar
Emmenegger, P. (2009), ‘Barriers to entry: insider–outsider politics and the political determinants of job security regulations’, European Journal of Social Policy 19(2): 131146.Google Scholar
Esping-Andersen, G.Regini, M. (eds) (2000), Why Deregulate Labor Markets?, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
fRDB-IZA. (2010), Social Reforms Database, Milan and Bonn: Fondazione Rodolfo de Benedetti and IZA (Institute for the Study of Labor).Google Scholar
Garrett, G. (1998), Partisan Politics in the Global Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Greene, W.H.Hensher, D.A. (2010), Modeling Ordered Choices: A Primer, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, M.Basinger, S. (1998), ‘Internationalization and changes in tax policy in OECD countries: the importance of domestic veto players’, Comparative Political Studies 31(3): 321352.Google Scholar
Häusermann, S., Schwander, H. (2009), ‘Who are the outsiders and what do they want? Welfare state preferences in dualized societies’. Paper presented at the 5th General Conference of the European Consortium for Political Research, 10–12 September, Potsdam, Germany.Google Scholar
Henisz, W. (2010), ‘The Political Constraint Index (Polcon) Dataset’. Wharton School of Management.Google Scholar
Heston, A., Summers, R., Aten, B. (2009), Penn World Table, Version 6.3, University of Pennsylvania: Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices.Google Scholar
Huber, E.Stephens, J.D. (2001), Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets, Chicago: Chicago University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, E., Ragin, C.Stephens, J.D. (1993), ‘Social democracy, Christian democracy, constitutional structure and the welfare state’, American Journal of Sociology 99(3): 711749.Google Scholar
Immergut, E. (1992), Health Politics: Interests and Institutions in Western Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Keman, H. (2011), ‘Third ways and social democracy: the right way to go?’, British Journal of Political Science 41(3): 671680.Google Scholar
Kitschelt, H. (2004), ‘Diversification and reconfiguration of party systems in postindustrial democracies’. Europaeische Politik 03, Friedrich Ebert Stiftung.Google Scholar
Kittel, B.Obinger, H. (2003), ‘Political parties, institutions, and the dynamics of social expenditure in times of austerity’, Journal of European Public Policy 10(1): 2045.Google Scholar
Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., Budge, I.McDonald, M. (2006), Mapping Policy Preferences II. Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments in Eastern Europe, the European Union and the OECD, 1990–2003, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Korpi, W.Palme, J. (2003), ‘New politics and class politics in the context of austerity and globalization: welfare state regress in 18 countries, 1975–95’, American Political Science Review 97(3): 425446.Google Scholar
Palier, B.Thelen, K. (2010), ‘Institutionalizing dualism: complementarities and change in France and Germany’, Politics & Society 38(1): 119148.Google Scholar
Pierson, P. (1996), ‘The new politics of the welfare state’, World Politics 48(2): 143179.Google Scholar
Pierson, P. (2001), ‘Coping with permanent austerity: welfare state restructuring in affluent democracies’, in P. Pierson (ed.), The New Politics of the Welfare State, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 410456.Google Scholar
Ross, F. (2000), ‘Beyond left and right: the new partisan politics of welfare’, Governance 13(2): 155183.Google Scholar
Rueda, D. (2007), Social Democracy Inside Out: Partisanship & Labor Market Policy in Industrialized Democracies. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rueda, D. (2005), ‘Insider–outsider politics in industrialized democracies: the challenge to social democratic parties’, American Political Science Review 99: 6174.Google Scholar
Saint-Paul, G. (1996), ‘Exploring the political economy of labor market institutions’, Economic Policy 11(23): 263316.Google Scholar
Schumacher, G., Vis, B., van Kersbergen, K. (2009), ‘Playing the blame avoidance game? Party competition, electoral punishment and welfare state reform’. Paper presented at the NIG Work Conference, Leiden, 12–13 November, the Netherlands.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. (2002), Veto Players. How Political Institutions Work, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Visser, J. (2009), ICTWSS: Database on Institutional Characteristics of Trade Unions, Wage Setting, State Intervention and Social Pacts in 34 Countries between 1960 and 2007, Version 2, the Netherlands: University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Williams, R. (2006), ‘Generalized ordered logit/partial proportional odds models for ordinal dependent variables’, The Stata Journal 6(1): 5882.Google Scholar