Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-ndw9j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-16T10:21:23.971Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The International Law of Property

Review products

The Political Economy of the Investment Treaty Regime. By JonathanBonnitcha, Lauge N. SkovgaardPoulsen and MichaelWaibel. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press, 2017. Pp. xxviii, 314. Index.

The Great Property Fallacy: Theory, Reality, and Growth in Developing Countries. By Frank K.Upham. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press, 2018. Pg. xi, 146. Index.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 October 2018

José E. Alvarez*
Affiliation:
Herbert and Rose Rubin Professor of International Law, NYU School of Law

Extract

On the surface, the two books under review seem to have little in common. The Bonnitcha/Poulsen/Waibel (BPW) book, written by two legal academics and a political scientist, provides a balanced, fact-grounded account of international investment agreements (IIAs) and investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS). This is the “international treaty regime” in that book's title which the authors argue needs to be distinguished from the broader “international regime complex” that their book explicitly does not address, namely the number of other international instruments that at least incidentally also protect foreign investments (including, for example, political risk insurance, tax treaties, certain World Trade Organization agreements, and certain human rights treaties like the European Convention on Human Rights (ECHR)) (p. 7 and Figure 1.2). As one of the encomiums on its back cover page suggests, the BPW book seeks to answer the fraught competing contentions of defenders and critics of the regime that all too frequently generate “more heat than light.” Their book dispassionately synthesizes the available legal, economic, and political literature relevant to understanding the investment treaty regime's oft-proclaimed “legitimacy crisis.” It seeks to supply lawyers needing political context and political scientists needing legal knowledge with the unfiltered facts required to assess whether such a “crisis” exists and, if so, what the ways forward might be.

Type
Review Essay
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 by The American Society of International Law 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See, e.g., Simpson, George G., The Principles of Classification and a Classification of Mammals, 85 Bull. Am. Museum Nat. Hist. 1, 23 (1945)Google Scholar (“Splitters make very small units—their opponents say that if they can tell two animals apart, they place them in different genera, and if they cannot tell them apart, they place them in different species. Lumpers make large units—their opponents say that if a carnivore is neither a dog nor a bear they call it a cat.”).

2 Hernando de Soto, The Other Path (1989).

3 See Guzman, Andrew T., Why LDCs Sign Treaties that Hurt Them: Explaining the Popularity of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 38 Va. J. Int'l L. 639 (1998)Google Scholar.

4 See Stephan W. Schill, The Multilateralization of International Investment Law (2009).

5 See, for example, BPW at 84 (“If mutually beneficial solutions existed, one would expect the parties to be able to negotiate settlement privately without any need for mediation or conciliation.”).

6 Upham cites to Coase, Ronald H., The Problem of Social Cost, 1 J. L. & Econ. 3 (1960)Google Scholar; Demsetz, Harold, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 Am. Econ. Rev. 347 (1967)Google Scholar; Douglas North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (1981). Upham, at 1.

7 Upham is referring to the theories propounded by Coase and Demsetz (supra note 6)—namely the propositions that private property (e.g., ownership in beaver fur) is economically efficient to the extent it helps internalize negative externalities (e.g., the decline in beavers due to hunting) while reducing the transactions costs of enforcing such rights. For one attempt to describe the insights of Coase and Demsetz and enumerate the misunderstandings generated by them, see, e.g., Douglas W. Allen, Transaction Costs, Encyclopedia L. & Econ. 893 (1998).

8 See, e. g., Vandevelde, Kenneth, Investment Liberalization and Economic Development: The Role of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 36 Colum. J. Transnat'l L. 501 (1998)Google Scholar.

9 See, e.g., Koskenniemi, Martti, Empire and International Law: The Real Spanish Contribution, 61 U. Toronto L.J. 1 (2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Koskenniemi, Martti, Sovereignty, Property and Empire: Early Modern English Contexts, 18 Theoretical Inquiries 355 (2017)Google Scholar; Koskenniemi, Martti, International Law and the Emergence of Mercantile Capitalism: Grotius to Smith, in The Roots of International Law 3 (Dupuy, Pierre-Marie and Chetail, Vincent eds., 2014)Google Scholar.

10 See, e.g., Alvarez, José E., The Human Right of Property, 72 U. Miami L. Rev. 580, 690 (2018)Google Scholar (Appendix of Significant International Instruments Recognizing the Right to Property in International Law).

11 Id. See generally John G. Sprankling, The International Law of Property (2014).

12 See, e.g., Rep. and Op. of Prof. Joseph H.H. Weiler, at 4, 9–11, Mezerhane v. República Bolivariana de Venezuela, No. 1:11-CV-23983-MGC, ECF No. 59-1 (S.D. Fla. Nov. 30, 2012); Sprankling, John G., The Global Right to Property, 52 Colum. J. Transnat'l L. 464, 495–97 (2014)Google Scholar.

13 See, e.g., Sprankling, supra note 12, at 485, 492–93 (noting that 95% of the nations of the world guarantee the right to property under their national laws, commonly in their constitutions).