Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-02T20:42:23.510Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 March 2016

Erwin Dekker
Affiliation:
Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
The Viennese Students of Civilization
The Meaning and Context of Austrian Economics Reconsidered
, pp. 203 - 216
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adorno, Theodor W. 1969. “Scientific Experiences of a European Scholar in America.” In The Intellectual Migration: Europe and America, 1930–1960, ed. Fleming, Donald. and Bailyn, Bernard, pp. 338370. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A. and Kranton, Rachel E.. 2010. Identity Economics: How Our Identities Shape Our Work, Wages and Well-Being. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Robert L. 1994. Opening Doors the Life and Work of Joseph Schumpeter, Volume 1: Europe. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Amadae, S. M. 2003. Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy: The Cold War Origins of Rational Choice Liberalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah. 1968. Men in Dark Times. San Diego: Harcourt Brace Janovich.Google Scholar
Aristotle, . 2009. Nichomachean Ethics, ed. Ross, David and Brown, Lesley. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bailes, Christopher. 2012. “Ludwig Wittgenstein and Hermann Broch: The Need for Fiction and Logic in Moral Philosophy”. Washington University Open Scholarship.Google Scholar
Berger, Peter L. 1963. Invitation to Sociology: A Humanistic Perspective. New York: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
Berger, Peter L. and Kellner, Hansfried. 1982. Sociology Reinterpreted. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Berman, Sheri. 1997. “Civil Society and the Collapse of the Weimar Republic.” World Politics 49 (3): 401429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernal, J. D. 1939. The Social Function of Science. London: Routledge & Sons.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Michael A. 2001. A Perilous Progress: Economists and Public Purpose in Twentieth-Century America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birner, Jack. 1999. “The Surprising Place of Cognitive Psychology in the Work of F.A. Hayek.” History of Economic Ideas 7 (1–2): 4384.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1962. Economic Theory in Retrospect. London: Heinemann.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1992. The Methodology of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boettke, Peter J. 1994. The Elgar Companion to Austrian Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boettke, Peter J. 2010. Handbook on Contemporary Austrian Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boettke, Peter J. 2012. Living Economics: Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow. Oakland: The Independent Institute.Google Scholar
Bohm, Franz, Eucken, Walter, and Grossmann-Doerth, Hans. 1936/1989. “The Ordo Manifesto of 1936.” In Germany’s Social Market Economy, ed. Peacock, Alan and Wilgerodt, Hans, 1526. London: Trade Policy Research Centre.Google Scholar
Boltanski, Lu and Thévenot, Laurent. 2006. On Justification: Economies of Worth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1963. “Towards a Pure Theory of Threat Systems.” The American Economic Review 53 (2): 424434.Google Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1969. “Economics as a Moral Science.” The American Economic Review 59 (1): 112.Google Scholar
Broch, Hermann. 1946a. “Geschichtsgesetz Und Willensfreiheit.” In Massenpsychologie: Schriften Aus Dem Nachlass, 237312. Zürich: Rhein-Verlag.Google Scholar
Broch, Hermann. 1946b. The Death of Virgil. London: George Routledge & Sons.Google Scholar
Broch, Hermann. 2002. “Hugo von Hofmannstahl and His Time: Art and Its Non-Style at the End of the Nineteenth Century.” In Geist and Zeitgeist: The Spiritual in an Unspiritual Age, ed. Hargraves, John, 141210. New York: Counterpoint.Google Scholar
Buck, Peter. 1985. “Adjusting to Military Life: The Social Sciences Go to War, 1941–1950.” In Military Enterprise and Technological Change: Perspectives on the American Experience, ed. Smith, Merritt Roe, 203–52. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Burgin, Angus. 2012. The Great Persuasion: Reinventing Free Markets Since the Depression. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von. 1891. The Positive Theory of Capital. London: Macmillan and Company.Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von. 1914/1924. “Macht Oder Ökonomisch Gesetz.” In Gesammelte Schriften von Eugen von Böhm Bawerk, ed. Weiss, Franz X., 230300. Wien: Hölder-Pichler-Tempsky.Google Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce. 1988. “Hayek’s Transformation.” History of Political Economy 20 (4): 513541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce. 1997. “Introduction.” In The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek: Volume X. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce. 2004. Hayek’s Challenge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cassidy, John. 2000. “The Hayek Century.” Hoover’s Digest (3). www.hoover.org/publications/hoover-digest/article/6405.Google Scholar
Cassidy, John. 2010. “Interview with John Cochrane (After the Blow-up Series).” The New Yorker (January 13). www.newyorker.com/online/blogs/johncassidy/2010/01/interview-with-john-cochrane.html.Google Scholar
Clarke, Maurice D. 1888. “Therapeutic Nihilism.” Boston Medical and Surgical Journal 119 (9): 199201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1934. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4 (16): 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coen, Deborah R. 2007. Vienna in the Age of Uncertainty: Science, Liberalism, and Private Life. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, Randall. 1998. The Sociology of Philosophies: A Global Theory of Intellectual Change. Harvard: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Collins, Randall. 2004. Interaction Ritual Chains. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Congdon, Lee. 1991. Exile and Social Thought: Hungarian Intellectuals in Germany and Austria 1919–1934. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowen, Tyler. 2007. Discover Your Inner Economist. New York: Dutton.Google Scholar
Cowen, Tyler. 2013. “One Further Thought on the Reinhart and Rogoff Fracas.” Marginal Revolution. http://marginalrevolution.com/marginalrevolution/2013/04/one-further-thought-on-the-reinhart-and-rogoff-fracas.html.Google Scholar
Crankshaw, Edward. 1938. Vienna: The Image of a Culture in Decline. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Cravens, Hamilton. 2012. “Column Right, March! Nationalism, Scientific Positivism, and the Conservative Turn of the American Social Sciences in the Cold War Era.” In Cold War Social Science: Knowledge Production, Liberal Democracy, and Human Nature, ed. Solovey, Mark and Cravens, Hamilton, 117–35. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Craver, Earlene. 1986. “The Emigration of the Austrian Economists.” History of Political Economy 18 (1): 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craver, Eearlen and Leijonhufvud, Axel. 1987. “Economics in America: the Continental Influence.” History of Political Economy, 19 (2): 173182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cushing, James T. 1994. Quantum Mechanics: Historical Contingency and the Copenhagen Hegemony. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Dahms, Hans-Joachim. 1995. The Migration of the Vienna Circle. In Vertreibung der Vernunft: The Cultural Exodus from Austria, ed. Stadler, Friedrich and Weibel, Peter, 5779. Wien: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. 2011. Individuals and Identity in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dekker, Erwin (2014). “The Intellectual Networks of Otto Neurath: Between the Coffeehouse and Academia.” In European Encounters: Intellectual Exchange and the Rethinking of Europe 1914–1945.Google Scholar
Dietl, Joseph. 1845. “Praktische Wahrnehmungen Nach Den Ergebnissen Im Wiedner-Bezirkskrankenhause.” Zeitschrift Der K.u.k. Gesellschaft Der Aerzte Zu Wien 1 (2): 926.Google Scholar
Dietl, Joseph. 1849. Der Aderlass in Der Lungentzündung. Klinisch Und Physiologisch Erötert. Wien: Kaulfuss Witwe, Prandel & Comp.Google Scholar
Drucker, Peter F. 1939. The End of Economic Man: A Study of the New Totalitarianism. London: William Heinemann.Google Scholar
Dunning, Eric and Mennell, Stephen. 1996. “Preface.” In The Germans: Power Struggles and the Development of Habitus in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries, viixvi. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Ebenstein, Alan. 2003. Hayek’s Journey: The Mind of Friedrich Hayek. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ebner, Alexander. 2005. “Hayek on Entrepreneurship: Competition, Market Process and Cultural Evolution.” In Entrepreneurship, Money and Coordination, ed. Backhaus, Jürgen G., 131149. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B. and Hébert, Robert F.. 1983. A History of Economic Theory and Method. Auckland: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Elias, Norbert. 1939/2000. The Civilizing Process: Sociogenetic and Psychogenetic Investigations. Malden: Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Elias, Norbert. 1996. The Germans: Power Struggles and the Development of Habitus in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. Oxford: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Engel-Janosi, Friedrich. 1974. … Aber ein Stolzer Bettler: Erinnerungen aus einer Verlorenen Generation. Graz: Styria.Google Scholar
Fleck, Christian. 1996. Emigration of Social Scientists’ Schools from Austria. In Forced Migration and Scientific Change, eds. Ash, Mitchell G. & Söllner, Alfons, 198223. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, Nicolai Juul. 1995. “More on ‘Hayek’s Transformation’.” History of Political Economy 27 (2): 345364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francis, Mark and Stacy, Barrie. 1985. “Freud and the Enlightenment.” In The Viennese Enlightenment, ed. Francis, Mark, pp. 88128. Kent: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. 2008. The Economic Naturalist. London: Virgin Books.Google Scholar
Franz, Georg. 1955. Liberalismus: Die Deutschliberale Bewegung in der Habsburgischen Monarchie. München: G.D.W. Callwey.Google Scholar
Freud, Sigmund. 1930. Civilization and Its Discontents. London: Hogarth Press.Google Scholar
Fuchs, Albert. 1949. Geistige Strömungen in Österreich 1867–1918. Wien: Globus Verlag.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis. 1989. “The End of History?” National Interest (16): 3–18.Google Scholar
Gadamer, Hans-Georg. 1975. “Philosophy & Social Criticism.” Philosophy & Social Criticism 2: 307.Google Scholar
Gadamer, Hans-Georg. 2004. Truth and Method. London: Continuum.Google Scholar
Gray, John. 1984. Hayek on Liberty. New York: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Gray, John. 2000. Two Faces of Liberalism. New York: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Grillparzer, Franz. 1962. King Ottocar: His Rise and Fall. Ed. Burkhard, Arthur. Yarmouth Port: The Register Press.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, Peter D. 2001. Physicians and Political Economy: Six Studies of the Work of Doctor-Economists. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruen, William. 1939. “What Is Logical Empiricism.” Partisan Review 6 (5): 6477.Google Scholar
Haag, John. 1976. “Othmar Spann and the Quest for a ‘True State’.” Austrian History Yearbook 12: 227250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haberler, Gottfried von. 1983. “Fritz Machlup: In Memoriam.” Cato Journal 3: 1114.Google Scholar
Hacohen, Malachi H. 2000. Karl Popper, the Formative Years, 1902–1945: Politics and Philosophy in Interwar Vienna. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hahn, Hans, Neurath, Otto, and Carnap, Rudolf. 1929/1979. “Wissenschaftliche Weltauffassung: Der Wiener Kreis.” In Otto Neurath: Wissenschaftliche Weltauffassung, Sozialismus Und Logischer Empirismus, ed. Hegelsmann, Rainer, 79101. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp Verlag.Google Scholar
Hahn, Robert W. 1989. “Economic Prescriptions for Environmental Problems: How the Patient Followed the Doctor’s Orders.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (2): 95114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamann, Brigitte (ed ). 1979. Majestät, Ich Warne Sie …: Geheime Und Private Schriften. Wien: Amalthea.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1926/1992. “Friedrich von Wieser (1851–1926).” In The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek: Volume IV, The Fortunes of Liberalism, 108125. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1933. “The Trend of Economic Thinking.” Economica (40): 121–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1937. “Economics and Knowledge.” Economica 4 (13): 3354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1939. Freedom and the Economic System. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1944/1992. “Historians and the Future of Europe.” In The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek: Volume IV, The Fortunes of Liberalism, ed. Klein, Peter G., 201215. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1944. The Road to Serfdom. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” The American Economic Review 35 (4): 519530.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1947/1967. “Opening Address to a Conference at Mont Pèlerin.” In Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics, 148159. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1948. “Individualism: True and False.” In Individualism & Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1949. “The Intellectuals and Socialism.” The University of Chicago Law Review 16 (3): 417433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1952. The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the Abuse of Reason. Glencoe: Free Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1956/2007. “Foreword to the 1956 American Paperback Edition.” In The Road to Serfdom: The Definitive Edition, ed. Caldwell, Bruce, 3952. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1962. “The Moral Element in Enterprise.” The Freeman 8 (July): 4451.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1962. “The Pretence of Knowledge.” The Swedish Journal of Economics 77 (4): 433442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1979. “Interviews with Hayek.” http://mises.org/books/hayek_oral_history.pdf.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1981. “Foreword.” In Socialism, ed. von Mises, Ludwig, xixxxiv. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1982. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 3: The Political Order of a Free People. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1988. The Collected Works of Friedrich August Hayek Vol I, The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, ed. Bartley, W.W. III. Vol. I. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1994. Hayek on Hayek. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heilbroner, Robert L. 1953. The Worldly Philosophers: The Lives, Times, and Ideas of the Great Economic Thinkers. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Heims, S. J. 1991. “Fritz London and the Community of Quantum Physicists.” In World Views and Scientific Discipline Formation, ed. Woordward, William R.. Vol. 134. Dordrecht: Kluwer.Google Scholar
Heizmann, Jürgen. 2003. “A Farewell to Art: Poetic Reflection in Broch’s Der Tod Des Vergil.” In Hermann Broch, Visionary in Exile: The 2001 Yale Symposium, ed. Lützeler, Paul Michael, 187200. Rochester: Camden House.Google Scholar
Helling, Ingeborg Katharina. 1984. “A. Schutz and F. Kaufmann: Sociology Between Science and Interpretation.” Human Studies 7: 141161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hennecke, Hans Jörg. 2000. Friedrich August von Hayek: Die Tradition Der Freiheit. Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen.Google Scholar
Hermann, Friedrich Wilhelm. 1832. Staatswirtschaftliche Untersuchungen. München: Anton Weberschen Buchhandlung.Google Scholar
Heyne, Paul T. 1973. The Economic Way of Thinking. Chicago: Science Research Associates.Google Scholar
Heyt, Friso D. 1999. “Popper’s Vienna. A Contribution to the History of the Ideas of Critical Rationalism.” Innovation: The European Journal of Social Science Research 12 (4): 525541.Google Scholar
Hicks, John. 1939. Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, John. 1984. “The Formation of an Economist.” In The Economics of John Hicks, ed. Helm, Dieter, 281290. New York: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1977. The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism Before Its Triumph. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1982. “Rival Interpretations of Market Society: Civilizing, Destructive, or Feeble?Journal of Economic Literature 20 (4): 14631484.Google Scholar
Homans, Jennifer. 2012. “Tony Judt: A Final Victory.” New York Review of Books (March).Google Scholar
Horwitz, Steven. 2005. “Review Essay Friedrich Hayek, Austrian Economist.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (1): 7185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howson, Susan. 2006. “Hayek’s Journey: The Mind of Friedrich Hayek Review.” History of Political Economy 38 (3): 555556.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Stuart H. 1956. “Is the Intellectual Obsolete?Commentary 22 (4): 313.Google Scholar
Hughes, Stuart H. 1958. Consciousness and Society: the Reorientation of European Social Thought, 1890–1930. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Huizinga, Johan. 1938. Homo Ludens: Proeve Eener Bepaling Van Het Spel-element Der Cultuur. Haarlem: H.D. Tjeenk Willink & Zoon.Google Scholar
Huizinga, Johan. 1949. Homo Ludens-A Study of the Play - Element in Culture. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hülsmann, Jörg Guido. 2007. Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Auburn: Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1998. The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order. London: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hutchison, Terence W. 1964. Positive Economics and Policy Objectives. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ingrao, Bruno and Israel, Giorgio. 1990. The Invisible Hand. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Jabloner, Clemens. 1998. “Kelsen and His Circle: The Viennese Years.” European Journal of International Law 9 (2): 368385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janik, Allan. 1981. “Therapeutic Nihilism: How Not to Write About Otto Weininger.” In Structure and Gestalt, ed. Smith, Barry, 263292. Amsterdam: John Benjamins.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janik, Allan. 1985. Essays on Wittgenstein and Weininger. Amsterdam: Rodopi.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janik, Allan and Toulmin, Stephen. 1973. Wittgenstein’s Vienna. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Johnston, William M. 1972. The Austrian Mind: An Intellectual and Social History, 1848–1938. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judson, Pieter M. 1996. Exclusive Revolutionaries: Liberal Politics, Social Experience, and National Identity in the Austrian Empire 1848–1914. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judt, Tony. 2010. Ill Fares the Land. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, Felix. 1992. Wiener Lieder zu Philosophie und Ökonomie. Stuttgart: Gustav Fischer Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1924. “Alfred Marshall 1842–1924.” The Economic Journal 34 (135): 311372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1930/1963. Essays in Persuasion. London: W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan and Co.Google Scholar
Kirzner, Israel M. 1987. “The Austrian School of Economics.” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, ed. Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, Peter. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Klamer, Arjo. 2007. Speaking of Economics: How to Get in the Conversation. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klausinger, Hansjörg. 2005. Die Austroliberalen und die Kampagne in “Neuen Wiener Tagblatt”, 1931–1934. In Wirtschaftspolitische Beiträge in kritischer Zeit (1931–1934), 1136. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Klausinger, Hansjörg. 2006. “In the Wilderness”: Emigration and the Decline of the Austrian School. History of Political Economy, 38(4), 617664.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klausinger, Hansjörg. 2013. Academic Anti-Semitism and the Austrian School: Vienna, 1918–1945 (No. 155) (pp. 1–25).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klausinger, Hansjörg. 2014. Hans Mayer, Last Knight of the Austrian School, Vienna Branch. Paper presented at HOPE, Duke University. http://hope.econ.duke.edu/sites/default/files/Klausinger_CHOPE1.pdfGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1923. “The Ethics of Competition.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 37 (4): 579624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konrád, György. 1984. Antipolitics. New York: Harcourt Brace Janovich.Google Scholar
Koppl, Roger, Horwitz, Steve, and Desrochers, Pierre. 2010. What Is so Austrian About Austrian Economics. Bingley: Emerald Group.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter. 2003. “The Viennese Connection: Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School.” The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 6 (2): 3567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lavoie, Don. 1985. Rivalry and Central Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Reconsidered. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lavoie, Don. 2011. “The Interpretive Dimension of Economics.” The Review of Austrian Economics 24 (2): 91128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lachmann, Ludwig M. 1982. “The Salvage of Ideas: Problems of the Revival of Austrian Economic Thought.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 138: 629–45.Google Scholar
Lederer, Emil. 1940. State of the Masses: The Threat of the Classless Society. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 1998. “The History of Science Society, Ethics and the Excluded Middle: Karl Menger and Social Science in Interwar Vienna.” Isis 89 (1): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 2010. Von Neumann, Morgenstern, and the Creation of Game Theory: From Chess to Social Science, 1900–1960. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 2011. “The Collapse of Interwar Vienna: Oskar Morgenstern’s Community, 1925–50.” History of Political Economy 43 (1) (February 28): 83130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leser, Norbert. 1981. Das Geistige Leben Wiens in Der Zwischenkriegszeit. Wien: Österreichischer Bundesverlag.Google Scholar
Lesky, Erna. 1976. The Vienna Medical School of the 19th Century. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Liebersohn, Harry. 1990. Fate and Utopia in German Sociology, 1870–1923. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Lipking, Lawrence. 1981. The Life of the Poet: Beginning and Ending of Poetic Careers. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Littlechild, Stephen. 1990. Austrian Economics: Volume 1–3. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
MacIntyre, Alasdair C. 1984. After Virtue: A Study in Moral Theory. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1932/2005a. “Kontingentverträge?”. In Wirtschaftpublizistische Beiträge in kritischer Zeit (1931–1934) ed. Klausinger, H., 6972. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1932/2005b. “Währungspolitische Quacksalbereien”. In Wirtschaftpublizistische Beiträge in kritischer Zeit (1931–1934) ed. Klausinger, H., 7274. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1932/2005c. “Industrieförderung?”. In Wirtschaftpublizistische Beiträge in kritischer Zeit (1931–1934) ed. Klausinger, H., 116117. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1933/2005b. “Ärzte der Wirtschaft”. In Wirtschaftpublizistische Beiträge in kritischer Zeit (1931–1934) ed. Klausinger, H., 202206. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1959. “Statics and Dynamics: Kaleidoscopic Words.” Southern Economic Journal 26 (2): 91110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1962. The Production and Distribution of Knowledge in the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Madison, G Brent. 1990. “How Individualistic Is Methodological Individualism.” Critical Review 4 (1–2): 4160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magris, Claudio. 1989. Danube. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Malinowski, Bronislaw. 1941. “Man’s Culture and Man’s Behaviour.” Sigma Xi Quarterly 29 (3–4): 182196.Google Scholar
Malinowski, Bronislaw. 1947. Freedom and Civilization. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 1994. Knowledge and Persuasion in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCraw, Thomas K. 2007. Prophet of Innovation: Joseph Schumpeter and Creative Destruction. Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
McGill, V. J. 1936. “An Evaluation of Logical Positivism.” Science & Society 1 (1): 4580.Google Scholar
McGucken, William. 1978. “On Freedom and Planning in Science: The Society for Freedom in Science, 1940-46.” Minerva 16 (1): 4272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2009. The Hesitant Hand: Taming Self-Interest in the History of Economic Ideas. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, Anton. 1886. Das Recht Auf Den Vollen Arbeitsertrag in Geschichtlicher Darstellung. Stuttgart: J.G. Cotta.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1871/1950. Principles of Economics. Glencoe: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1883/2009. Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences. Auburn: Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1891/1935. The Collected Works of Carl Menger Vol. 3: Kleinere Schriften zur Methode und Geschichte der Volkswirtschaftslehre. London: The London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Menger, Karl. 1994. Reminiscences of the Vienna Circle and the Mathematical Colloquium, eds. Golland, Louise, McGuiness, Brian, and Sklar, Abe. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, Max. 1866. Die Auf Selbsthilfe Gestützten Genossenschaften Im Handwerker-Und Arbeiterstande: Vorträge Gehalten Im Fortbildungs-Verein Für Buchdrucker in Wien. Wien: Fortbildungs-Verein für Buchdrucker in Wien.Google Scholar
Menger, Max. 1873. Die Wahlreform in Österreich. Vienna: Verlag von K. Rosner.Google Scholar
Mennell, Stephen and Goudsblom, Johan. 1997. “Civilizing Processes-Myth or Reality? A Comment on Duerr’s Critique of Elias.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 39 (4): 729733.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 2002. Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 2009. “Postface: Defining Neoliberalism.” In The Road from Mont-Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective, ed. Mirowski, Philip and Plehwe, Dieter, pp. 417455. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 2012. A History Best Served Cold. In Uncertain Empire: American History and the Idea of the Cold War, ed. Isaac, Joel and Bell, Duncan, pp. 6174. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip, and Plehwe, Dieter. 2009. The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1919/1983. Nation, State and Economy: Contributions to the Politics and History of Our Time. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1922/1951. Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1926/1977. A Critique of Interventionism. New York: Arlington House.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1931. “Die Psychologischen Wurzeln des Widerstandes gegen die Nationaloekonomische Theorie.” Eds. von Mises, Ludwig and Spiethoff, Arthur. Schriften Des Vereins Für Sozialpolitik 183 (1): 275295.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1932. “Review of ‘Die Letzten Jahrzehnte Einer Groβmacht’ by Rudolph Sieghart.” Economica 38: 477–78.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1942/1978. Ludwig Von Mises, Notes and Recollections. South Holland: Libertarian Press.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1949/2007. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1944. Omnipotent Government: The Rise of the Total State and Total War. Yale: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 2002. Selected Writings of Ludwig von Mises: Between Two World Wars. Ed. Ebeling, Richard M. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar. 1928. Wirtschaftsprognose: Eine Untersuchung Ihrer Voraussetzungen Und Möglichkeiten. Wien: Julius Fischer Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mulder, Henk L. 1968. “Wissenschaftliche Weltauffassung - Der Wiener Kreis.” Journal of the History of Philosophy 6 (4): 386390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, Karl H. 1998. “The Ideal Worlds of the Austrian Political Economists.” In Vertreibung Der Vernunft: The Cultural Exodus from Austria, ed. Stadler, Friedrich and Weibel, Peter, 146159. Wien: Springer.Google Scholar
Musil, Robert. 1930. Der Mann Ohne Eigenschaften. Berlin: Rowohlt.Google Scholar
Neider, Heinrich. 1973. “Memories of Otto Neurath.” In Empiricism and Sociology, ed. Neurath, Marie and Cohen, Robert S., 4549. Dordrecht: D. Reidel Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julie A. 2006. Economics for Humans. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neurath, Otto. 1916/2004. “Economics in Kind, Calculation in Kind and Their Relation to War Economics.” In Economic Writings: Selections 1904–1945, ed. Uebel, Thomas E. and Cohen, Robert S., 299311. Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
Neurath, Otto. 1917/2004. “The Economic Order of the Future and the Economic Sciences.” In Economic Writings: Selections 1904–1945, ed. Uebel, Thomas E. and Cohen, Robert S., 241261. Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
Neurath, Otto. 1919/2004. “War Economy.” In Economic Writings: Selections 1904–1945, ed. Uebel, Thomas E. and Cohen, Robert S., 153199. Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
Nietzsche, Friedrich. 1887/2006. On the Genealogy of Morality. Ed. Ansell-Pearson, Keith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Novick, Peter. 1988. That Noble Dream: The “Objectivity Question” and the American Historical Profession. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nozick, Robert. 1974. Anarchy, State and Utopia. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
O’Hear, A. (2009). Popperian Individualism Today. In Rethinking Popper eds. Parusnikova, Z. and Cohen, Robert S., 205214. Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oakeshott, Michael. 1962. Rationalism in Politics and Other Essays. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plehwe, Dieter. 2009. “Introduction.” In The Road from Mont-Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective, 142. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Plener, Ernst von. 1911. Erinnerungen - Bd. 1. Jugend, Paris und London bis 1873. Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt.Google Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. 2009. Political Thought and History: Essays on Theory and Method. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl. 1945. Origins of Our Time: The Great Transformation. Ed. Gollancz, Victor. London.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Michael. 1940. The Contempt of Freedom: The Russian Experiment and After. London: Watts & Co.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Michael. 1958. Personal Knowledge: Towards a Post-Critical Philosophy. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1945. The Open Society and Its Enemies, Volume 1: The Spell of Plato. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1950/2003. “Preface to the Second Edition.” In The Open Society and Its Enemies. Volume One: The Spell of Plato, xixiii. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. (1950/2008). The Open Society after Five Years: Prefaces to the American Edition. In After the Open Society: Selected Social and Political Writings, eds. Shearmur, J. & Turner, P. Norris, 169181. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1963/2008. The Open Society and the Democratic State. In After the Open Society: Selected Social and Political Writings, eds. Shearmur, J. & Turner, P. Norris, 231248. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1976. Unended Quest: An Intellectual Autobiography. Glasgow: William Collins Sons & Co.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1994. The Myth of the Framework: In Defence of Science and Rationality. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Porter, Theodore M. 2012. “Positioning the Social Sciences in Cold War America.” In Cold War Social Science: Knowledge Production, Liberal Democracy, and Human Nature, ed. Solovey, Mark and Cravens, Hamilton, xxvi. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge: Belknap Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John. 1996. Political Liberalism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Reisch, George A. 2005. How the Cold War Transformed Philosophy of Science: To the Icy Slopes of Logic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, Lionel R. 1932. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. Macmillan and Co.Google Scholar
Roll, Eric. 1973. A History of Economic Thought. London: Faber.Google Scholar
Rorty, Richard. 1979. Philosophy and the Mirror of Nature. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin E. 2002. “The Economist as Engineer: Game Theory, Experimentation, and Computation as Tools for Design Economics.” Econometrica 70 (4): 13411378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, Joseph. 1996. The Radetzky March. New York: Everyman’s Library.Google Scholar
Sandel, Michael J. 2012. What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Schäffle, Albert Eberhard Friedrich. 1861. Die Nationalökonomie oder allgemeine Wirtschaftslehre. Leipzig: Verlag von Otto Spamer.Google Scholar
Schlant, Ernestine. 1971. “Hermann Broch Als Politischer Utopist Zwischen’Geschichtsgesetz Und Willensfreiheit.” Literatur Und Kritik 6: 207213.Google Scholar
Schorske, Carl E. 1980. Fin-de-siècle Vienna: Politics and Culture. New York: Alfred Knopf.Google Scholar
Schorske, Carl E. 1997. “The New Rigorism in the Human Sciences, 1940–1960.” Daedalus 126 (1): 289309.Google Scholar
Schulak, Eugen M. and Unterköfler, Herbert. 2011. Austrian School of Economics: A History of Its Ideas, Ambassadors, and Institutions. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1912. Theorie Der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1919/1950. “The Crisis of the Tax-State.” In International Economic Papers: Translations Prepared for the International Economic Association. Vol. 6. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1919/1951. Imperialism and Social Classes. Ed. Sweezy, Paul M. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1943/1976. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1946/1976. “Preface to the Second Edition” In Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 411414. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1949. “Science and Ideology.” The American Economic Review 39 (2): 346359.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sedlacek, Tomas. 2011. Economics of Good and Evil: The Quest for Economic Meaning from Gilgamesh to Wall Street. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shearmur, Jeremy. 1996. Hayek and After: Hayekian Liberalism as a Research Programme. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sieghart, Rudolf. 1932. Die Letzten Jahrzehnte Einer Grossmacht: Menschen, Völker, Probleme Des Habsburger-Reichs. Berlin: Ullstein.Google Scholar
Small, Albion W. 1924. “Some Contributions to the History of Sociology. Section XVII. The Attempt (1860–80) to Reconstruct Economic Theory on a Sociological Basis.” American Journal of Sociology 30 (1): 4986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam. 1975. The Wealth of Nations: The Prosperity Classic. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Barry. 1990. “On the Austrianness of Austrian Economics.” Critical Review 4 (1–2): 212238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smithies, Arthur. 1951. “Memorial: Joseph Alois Schumpeter, 1883–1950.” In Schumpeter, Social Scientist, ed. Harris, Seymour E, 1123. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sombart, Werner. 1908. Sozialismus Und Soziale Bewegung. Jena: Gustav Fischer Verlag.Google Scholar
Spiegel, Henry W. 1983. The Growth of Economic Thought. Revised and Expanded Edition. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Spiel, Hilde. 1987. Vienna’s Golden Autumn. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.Google Scholar
Stadler, Friedrich. 1994. “Heinrich Gomperz Und Karl Popper im Kontext des Logischen Empirismus.” In Heinrich Gomperz, Karl Popper und die Österreichische Philosophie. Amsterdam: Rodopi.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stadler, Friedrich. 2003. “What Is the Vienna Circle?: Some Methodological and Historiographical Answers.” In The Vienna Circle and Logical Empiricism: Re-evaluation and Future Perspectives, XIXXIII. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starr, Paul. 1976. “The Politics of Therapeutic Nihilism.” The Hastings Center Report 6 (5): 2430.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Steiner, George. 1967. Language and Silence: Essays 1958–1966. London: Faber and Faber.Google Scholar
Sternhell, Zeev, and Talmon, Jacob L.. 1996. The Intellectual Revolt Against Liberal Democracy, 1870–1945: International Conference in Memory of Jacob L. Talmon. Jerusalem: Israel Academy of Sciences and Humanities.Google Scholar
Storr, Virgil. 2013. Understanding the Culture of Markets. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streissler, Erich and Streissler, Monika. 1994. Carl Menger’s Lecture to Crown Prince Rudolf of Austria. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Strigl, Richard. 1932/2005. “Rückkehr zu gesunder Währungspolitik!”. In Wirtschaftspublizistische Beiträge in kritischer Zeit (1931–1934), ed. Klausinger, H., 100112. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Szeps, Berta. 1938. My Life and History. London: Cassell.Google Scholar
Thomas, Richard F. 2004. Virgil and the Augustan Reception. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Timms, Edward. 1986. Karl Kraus, Apocalyptic Satirist: Culture and Catastrophe in Habsburg Vienna. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Timms, Edward. 1993. “Die Wiener Kreise: Schöpferische Interaktionen in Der Wiener Moderne.” In Die Wiener Jahrhundertwende: Einflüsse, Umwelt, Wirkungen, ed. Nautz, Jürgen and Vahrenkamp, Richard, 128143. Wien: Böhlau Verlag.Google Scholar
Timms, Edward. 2009. “Cultural Parameters Between the Wars: A Reassessment of the Vienna Circles.” In Vienna, Interwar, ed. Deborah Holmes and Lisa Silverman, 2130. Rochester: Camden House.Google Scholar
Uchitelle, Louis. 1999. “A Challenge to Scientific Economics: An Older School Looks at a Broad, More Intuitive Picture While Modernists See Just the Numbers and Facts.” The New York Times.Google Scholar
Vaughn, Karen I. 1994. Austrian Economics in America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wasserman, Janek. 2014. Black Vienna: The Radical Right in the Red City, 1918–1938. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watkins, John. 1997. “Karl Popper: A Memoir.” The American Scholar 66(2): 205–19.Google Scholar
Weber, Alfred. 1998. “Civilization and Culture - A Synthesis.” In Classical Readings in Culture and Civilization. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Weigand, Hermann J. 1947. “Broch’s Death of Vergil: Program Notes.” PMLA 62 (2): 525554.Google Scholar
Weintraub, Roy E. 2002. How Economics Became a Mathematical Science. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
White, Leslie A. 1949. The Science of Culture: A Study of Man and Civilization. New York: Farrar, Straus and Company.Google Scholar
Wiesemann, C. 1991. Josef Dietl Und Der Therapeutische Nihilismus. Zum Historischen Und Politischen Hintergrund Einer Medizinischen These. Frankfurt am Mainz: Peter Lang.Google Scholar
Wieser, Friedrich von. 1907a. “Unsere Gesellschaftliche und Politische Entwicklung Seit 1848, Teil I.” Neue Freie Presse, 8th of February.Google Scholar
Wieser, Friedrich von. 1907b. “Unsere Gesellschaftliche und Politische Entwicklung Seit 1848, Teil II.” Neue Freie Presse, 9th of February.Google Scholar
Wieser, Friedrich von. 1907c. “Unsere Gesellschaftliche und Politische Entwicklung Seit 1848, Teil III.” Neue Freie Presse, 12th of February.Google Scholar
Wieser, Friedrich von. 1910. Recht und Macht: Sechs Vorträge. Leipzig: Verlag von Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Wistrich, Robert S. 1996. “Intellectuals and Mass Politics in Fin-de-siècle Vienna.” In The Intellectual Revolt Against Liberal Democracy 1870–1945, eds. Sternhell, Zeev and Talmon, Jacob L., 7086. Jerusalem: The Israel Academy of Sciences and Humanities.Google Scholar
Wouters, Cas. 1986. “Formalization and Informalization: Changing Tension Balances in Civilizing Processes.” Theory Culture Society 3 (2): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yagi, Kiichiro. 1991. “Max Menger’s Liberal Position.” The Kyoto University Economic Review 61(1–14): 114.Google Scholar
Zuidhof, P.W. 2011. Imagining Markets: The Discursive Politics of Neoliberalism. University of Amsterdam, unpublished dissertation.Google Scholar
Zweig, Stefan. 1943. The World of Yesterday. New York: The Viking Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Erwin Dekker, Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam
  • Book: The Viennese Students of Civilization
  • Online publication: 05 March 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316411162.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Erwin Dekker, Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam
  • Book: The Viennese Students of Civilization
  • Online publication: 05 March 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316411162.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Erwin Dekker, Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam
  • Book: The Viennese Students of Civilization
  • Online publication: 05 March 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316411162.011
Available formats
×