6.1 Introduction
More than 130 jurisdictions around the world now have competition, or antitrust,Footnote 2 systems in place. Many of these, to prevent firms from distorting competition in a free market economy, stand upon three main substantive pillars:
i. provisions prohibiting restrictive agreements (e.g., in the United States (U.S.) and the European Union (EU), Section 1 of the Sherman Act 1890 and Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), respectively);
ii. provisions prohibiting monopolization (or attempts to monopolize) or abusive conduct of dominant firmsFootnote 3 (Sherman Act Section 2 and Article 102 TFEU); and
iii. provisions prohibiting mergers that will substantially lessen or significantly impede competition (Clayton Act 1914 Section 7 and the EU Merger Regulation, Council Regulation 139/2004).
This chapter considers the extent to which, in the area of complex products, competition laws can, or should, (i) affect remedies available for patent infringement; and/or otherwise (ii) limit the conduct of patentees, particularly when transferring or licensing their patents.
In examining the tensions that have arisen between patent and antitrust law in this sphere of complex products, this chapter scrutinizes issues that have arisen in a series of cases across the globe; these have principally emerged in relation to a subset of patents that are “essential” to the implementation of standardized technologies (standard-essential patents – SEPs). It explains that, in most jurisdictions, competition law accepts both the importance of patents to the competitive process and that standards are critical to innovation in industries where compatibility between manufacturers’ products is expected by customers. Nonetheless, antitrust enforcers worldwide have been concerned about the potential anticompetitive consequences that may flow from standardization processes (particularly in relation to mobile communication standards) and especially the behavior of SEP owners.
Section 6.2 considers the objectives of both antitrust and patent law focusing on whether, and if so how, they respectively seek to increase efficiency and welfare in markets – through promoting competition that delivers lower prices, greater quality of products, greater consumer choice, and/or innovation and dynamic efficiency. Despite relatively broad acceptance of the complementary nature of the antitrust and IP laws, it examines the inherent tension arising from the different methods deployed by the two systems to increase efficiency – grant of exclusionary rights versus protecting competition – and interactions between them. Further, Section 6.2 considers whether competition law should simply assume that the protection conferred by IP law is required for the creation and commercialization of new technology or whether competition law should intervene where conduct based on patent law seems to go beyond what is necessary and, for example, may be distorting competition in a downstream market and/or allowing the patentee to exploit users of the technology.
Section 6.3 examines whether and when there might be scope for antitrust law to “override” patent law, in particular in two interconnected circumstances, by:
preventing a patentee from seeking, or limiting when it may seek (restorative), patent remedies, for example, an injunction to prevent future infringement of its patent or damages for past infringement, and thus the judicial protection of its rights; and
limiting the commercial exploitation of patents, for example, by controlling the pricing of patent licenses (price levels or methodologies and how the requirement in some antitrust systems that dominant firms may not charge excessive or exploitative prices for their products or discriminate in prices between customers relates to fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory (FRAND)Footnote 4 licensing requirements); the structure of patent licenses (e.g., portfolio licensing, the bundling of patents in licenses, or the level at which the license is granted); collective licensing through patent pools; and the splitting or sale of patent portfolios.
When examining the antitrust jurisprudence one question arising is whether some cases have arisen, partly at least, as a response to a perceived failure of the patent system or as a result of concern that patent law has been unable to deal adequately or effectively with remedies and breakdowns in licensing negotiations. Broader questions, therefore, are whether there would be a need for competition law to play such an important supplemental role in this sphere if a more efficient and principled system of patent remedies is put in place, in line with that proposed in this book, or whether, even with such a system in place, competition law systems provide more flexible techniques for solving some of the problems arising in this sphere.
Finally, the chapter considers whether antitrust remedies allow competition law to be effectively enforced and thus serve as a helpful supplement to other patent law solutions without becoming too intrusive or regulatory in nature. The answer to this question may shape the contours of substantive antitrust liability.
6.2 Objectives of Intellectual Property and Competition Law
It is often said that patent law (and intellectual property (IP) law more broadly) and competition law “constitute complementary components of a modern industrial policy” that aims to improve innovation and consumer welfare.Footnote 5 However, because of the different approaches they employ to achieve their objectives – the conferral of exclusive rights compared to the maintenance of effective competition – sometimes patent and competition law solutions to an identical issue appear to collide. Furthermore, even if it is recognized that they strive to achieve complementary goals, it does not mean that antitrust law should not sometimes constrain patent law, or vice versa; these distinct areas of law must be interpreted to accommodate each other.
Before examining those apparent collisions in the subsequent sections, this part considers the ostensible tensionFootnote 6 between competition and patent law, focusing on the question of whether they are designed to achieve the same objectives – that is to improve welfareFootnote 7 and solve the same basic economic problem. Do they both aim to optimize the use of scarce resources in pursuit of providing the things that consumers want and need?Footnote 8 If so, the systems should then work harmoniously together and yield to each other when required. Where exclusion or unrestrained exploitation is necessary for the creation and commercialization of a new technology, competition law should defer to patent law. In contrast, where unconstrained exercise of IP rights goes beyond what is necessary for the creation and commercialization of a new technology and is detrimental to competition and efficiency, patent law should defer to competition law. With their unified goals, such trade-offs and concessions should be quite natural. In practice, however, things are not so simple and harmonious for a number of reasons.
First, although in some jurisdictions, including the United States, there has, until recently at least, been a growing consensus that competition law is “technocratic”Footnote 9 and built on the “broad professional and policy consensus” that surrounds the basic microeconomic model of perfect competition,Footnote 10 such an approach is by no means universal or without challenges.Footnote 11 Further, there is no broad consensus on objectives on the patent side. Rather it is generally recognized that the patent system is a welfare enhancing, multipurpose instrument serving a variety of objectives, includingFootnote 12 the provision of incentives to innovation and technology development,Footnote 13 the promotion of technology dissemination,Footnote 14 and the coordination of “the search for technological and market enhancement” (like prospects signal territories of interest to mine developers).Footnote 15 Furthermore, despite broad accord that innovation is crucial to technological growth, some disagreement as to how to foster such growth exists. For example, it may be difficult to know how best to incentivize both innovation and follow-on innovation or improvements. Although conferral of patents may incentivize innovation, it is possible that in some circumstances, rights conferred may be used to stifle competition that uses those patents and, consequently, subsequent innovation.
Secondly, in each field, agreement is lacking on how to achieve the objectives pursued.Footnote 16 Even in jurisdictions where a competition consumer welfare goal is clearly pursued, there is still considerable scope for debate as to how to reflect that underpinning aim, and in particular how to balance competing economic factors and, for example, how allocative efficiency (e.g., price equals marginal cost or price efficiency), productive efficiency (e.g., cost optimization), and/or dynamic efficiency (e.g., supply of improved and or new products/services) can be ensured. For example, a policy of ex post antitrust enforcement that prioritizes allocative efficiency over dynamic efficiency would almost inevitably upset a patent policy that aimed ex ante to maximize innovators’ rewards through extensive patent protection.Footnote 17
Another important issue relevant in the context of complex products is whether competition law should ever “regulate” the conduct of a dominant firm (or IP holder) by preventing it from engaging in exploitative conduct, for example through extracting “unfair” licensing terms from a licensee or implementer.Footnote 18 This matter is controversial not only from a competition perspective but also because it seems to go so fundamentally against the grain of patent law, which aims to incentivize by giving a patentee freedom to exploit the fruit of its invention for a limited period of time. Purely exploitative pricing behavior of dominant firms is not prohibited by monopolization laws set out in Section 2 of the Sherman Act in the United States,Footnote 19 but is specifically prohibited in the European Union and a number of other jurisdictions.Footnote 20 Although the European Commission (the Commission), like many other competition agencies, has to date rarely intervened in cases that purely involve unfair pricing,Footnote 21 and has generally preferred to focus its resources on exclusionary conduct (see Section 6.3), it is now clear that a number of competition agencies are becoming increasingly interested in such cases, especially in the sphere of SEPs and pharmaceutical products.Footnote 22
Thirdly, antitrust and patent laws involve different processes and are not enforced by common institutions. Rather, antitrust agencies and patent offices generally operate at arm’s length from each other. This may create an initial disconnect that needs to be resolved ex post when competition enforcement action is taken in individual cases or where patent issues are litigated in the courts.
As a result of these factors, the interface between patent and competition law can be mired in an uneasy stand-off. In an ideal world, there should not be such a disconnect. Rather a rational social planner should ensure wholesale consistency across policies in both fields and conflicts should not occur. Reality does not, however, match such an abstract model.
The tension between antitrust and patent laws should not be exaggerated, however. Competition law is case specific. It is generally respectful of patent rights and only prohibits certain types of conduct, leaving patent owners free to behave as they see fit outside of its strictures.Footnote 23 In particular, it generally only interferes with unilateral conduct of a patentee where that patentee is dominant or has a significant degree of market power.Footnote 24 This point means that innovation-minded patent practitioners should not overreact to antitrust enforcement.
Indeed, coordination between competition law and patent law is, frequently, left to doctrinal tools and techniques that are designed to balance the laws on a case-by-case basis, such as:
a. Division of competences. Competition law application may recede in spheres that the legislature has previously covered with IP rights. The idea behind this doctrine is that there is a core of IP law with which competition law cannot interfere. For example, in the European Union, the case law has accepted that EU competition law cannot deprive the holder of an IP right of the specific subject matter of its IP right but can only regulate the exercise of the right.Footnote 25
b. An enhanced intervention threshold. Competition law frequently sets the bar particularly high for a finding of breach of its rules when an IP right is involved (the rules of engagement of antitrust liability are set higher than in non-IP rights cases). Put differently, antitrust law is only likely to interfere with the exercise of IP rights in “exceptional circumstances.” Exceptionalism has been the approach ordinarily followed in, for example, refusal-to-license cases, both in the United StatesFootnote 26 and the European Union, although the authorities in the European Union have arguably been more willing to find that exceptional circumstances exist than their U.S. counterparts. For example, in MicrosoftFootnote 27 the General Court upheld the Commission’s finding that Microsoft had unlawfully withheld essential interoperability information from rivals, in a bid to leverage its dominant position on the market for Operating Systems (OS) for PCs into the adjacent market for work group servers OS. The theory of exceptionalism has also been applied to IP remedy cases in the European Union.
c. Complementarity. Given their complementary goals, the ex post application of competition law generally takes into account the need to protect investment in a patented invention. Thus, competition law recognizes that dynamic efficiency, and in particular the need to preserve the incentives to innovate provided by patent and IP law, could, under certain circumstances, be a crucial factor in crafting a test to identify anticompetitive conduct or a valid business justification of conduct that would otherwise be held to be anticompetitive.Footnote 28 Indeed in the European Union, the Commission has published a Communication on SEPs that sets out two objectives pursued in this sphere, “incentivising the development and inclusion of top technologies in standards, by preserving fair and adequate return for these contributions, and ensuring smooth and wide dissemination of standardized technologies based on fair access conditions.”Footnote 29
d. Patent Misuse. In the United States, the patent/antitrust interface had, historically, been governed by the judge-made patent misuse doctrine. Today, the doctrine has been significantly narrowed. Congress explicitly removed some practices from patent misuseFootnote 30 and the remainder of the doctrine has been narrowly interpreted by the courts.Footnote 31
e. Misrepresentation by a patentee. In some jurisdictions a relevant factor in determining whether antitrust liability should ensue may be whether a patentee has made misrepresentations to an authority (such as a patent office), for example to acquire IP protection or otherwise to exclude a competitor.Footnote 32
6.3 Antitrust Liability for Enforcement or Exploitation of Patents
6.3.1 Background
In the area of complex products, tensions arising at the interface of patent and antitrust law have largely emerged in relation to the exploitation, commercialization, or enforcement of SEPs. Many of these cases initially focused on the risk of capture of the standard-setting process or the conduct of a patentee that resulted in the nondisclosure of the existence of a relevant patent during a standardization process.Footnote 33 In more recent years, attention has concentrated on the risk that SEP holders might use market power acquired as a result of the standardization process to exploit customers and/or to hold up implementers of the standard and adversely impact on innovation and the quality, variety, and cost of products/services available in a downstream market. This could, for example, be through demanding unreasonable, excessive (in excess of the patentee’s true contribution),Footnote 34 or discriminatory royalties/licensing terms or through seeking injunctive relief against an implementer that does not agree to the patentee’s licensing demands.
It is true that to minimize such risks many, or most, standard-development organizations (SDOs) have for some time required participating firms to disclose SEPs and to commit, as a condition to having their technology integrated into the standard, to licensing of any SEPs on FRAND terms.Footnote 35 It is well known, nonetheless, that SDO rules, which mainly relate to technical issues, leave open the answer to a number of complex questions, including how valid patents can be identified and invalid assertions quickly weeded out; how infringement can be tested in relation to a portfolio of SEPs (how it can be determined whether over-declarations of essentiality have been made); whether and how FRAND commitments can be enforced, initially or following transfer of the SEP to a third party; exactly how a FRAND royalty can be assessed (whether an ex ante definition and specification of FRAND can be identified); and how a FRAND commitment deals with the potential risk of royalty stacking.Footnote 36 As a result of these open issues FRAND commitments have not been as effective as hoped, and negotiating firms have frequently been unable to agree on FRAND licensing arrangements. Many disputes have thus required resolution ex post not only before courts and in alternative dispute resolution, but also before competition agencies.Footnote 37 Amongst other things, such courts and agencies have frequently been asked to consider whether SEP owners who seek injunctions to prevent infringement of their patents or who pursue other ways to monetize their patents (e.g., through licensing practices or splitting portfolios) may be violating competition law.Footnote 38
These types of action might be reduced if SDO rules and processes were improved. The Commission Communication on SEPs thus calls upon SDOs to improve their processes and policies in several respects, including by:
a. providing more detailed and accessible information on their databases to facilitate patentees, implementers, and third parties obtaining information on declared patents and their current status, for example, by providing links to information held by patent offices on patent status, ownership, and transfer;Footnote 39
b. providing for the possibility, and incentives, for patentees and technology users to report cases on declared SEPs, particularly on essentiality and patent validity;Footnote 40
c. providing for a balanced and proportionate system of essentiality checks by a qualified third party, at the request of patentees or implementers, limiting, for example, the checks to one patent per family or samples (with patent offices being well placed to carry out such essentiality checks);Footnote 41 and
d. introducing systems whereby SEPs may be certified as complying with transparency criteria.Footnote 42
Although the Commission believes that its proposals may facilitate FRAND negotiations between SEP holders and implementers,Footnote 43 it remains to be seen whether, and to what extent, they will be followed. Further, even if SDOs were to accept such recommendations, which are not binding, the process improvements proposed are unlikely to resolve, by themselves, the problems that are discussed in this chapter. No matter how transparent, accurate, and robust SDOs’ processes and procedures are, competition law issues cannot be completely avoided or resolved ex ante, particularly because, in the current context, it is not the role of SDOs to set royalties and the terms and conditions of licenses or to make final and binding determinations on the validity and essentiality of SEPs, which is where most of the problems arise.
A preliminary issue in cases raising antitrust law arguments is, as discussed in Section 6.2, how antitrust law should interact with IP (and contract) law in this area and, in particular, whether there should be any role for antitrust law at all.Footnote 44 In many jurisdictions it has been accepted that competition law can play a role in certain circumstances, subject perhaps to application of the type of doctrinal tools described in Section 6.2 above. Thus in the European Union, in the 2015 landmark ruling of the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) in Huawei,Footnote 45 the Court stressed that (i) a balance must be maintained between free competition and safeguarding IP rights, and their effective judicial protection,Footnote 46 and (ii) although the exercise of an exclusive IP right (e.g., seeking an injunction against an alleged infringer) cannot, in itself, constitute a violation of EU competition law, in exceptional circumstances competition law might constrain the conduct of a SEP holder that holds a dominant position.Footnote 47
6.3.2 Antitrust Limits on a Patent Holder Seeking Restorative Patent Remedies (and Judicial Exploitation of Patents)
1 Seeking an Injunction Following a Failure of Licensing Negotiations
An explosion of disputes and worldwide litigation in the mobile communication sector has, in recent years, raised a plethora of patent, contract, and competition law issues. These cases followed the change in incentives and the shift in bargaining position between SEP holders and implementers created when, in particular:Footnote 48 (1) a number of implementers entered the market, for example, Apple (with the iPhone), Google (with its open-source Android operating system), and Microsoft (with Windows Mobile), which did not originally have the same number of patents essential to European Telecommunications Standards Institute (ETSI) standardsFootnote 49 as their competitors (although Apple and Microsoft, for example, held a significant portfolio of design and software patents that are not standard-essential (non-SEPs)); and (2) some of the original players in the market either sold off their patent portfolios to patent assertion entities (PAEs) or their position in the final product market began to decline.
The cases have raised issues in relation both to the infringement of non-SEPs and SEPs, and have included the question of whether a SEP holder should be able to enforce its exclusive rights through the bringing of an injunction claim in court. A particular concern in such cases has been how to balance the risk of holdup against the risk that an implementer who operates on the market without a license, thus infringing the patent, will seek to hold out by refusing to bargain in good faith (identified by some commentators as the “reverse holdup” problem).Footnote 50 (Although there is no agreed definition of holdup, the term is used, for present purposes, to describe any anticompetitive consequence of a refusal to license or the extraction of excessive royalties.)Footnote 51 For example, there is a concern that SEP holders may be able to secure rewards for innovation beyond their true value to consumers; to preclude open and effective access to the standard, thus allowing competition to be distorted through the exclusion, elimination, or hampering of competition,Footnote 52 new entry, and innovation downstream; and/or to undermine confidence in, and the working of, the standard-setting process.
In a number of jurisdictions, including the United States, the United Kingdom, and the Netherlands,Footnote 53 courts have, without needing recourse to antitrust law, refused to grant injunctions to patentees, and, in particular, have been unwilling to exercise their discretion to grant them to FRAND-committed SEP holders where the implementer, against whom the injunction is sought, is “willing” to take a license on FRAND terms.
In other jurisdictions, such as Germany, Japan,Footnote 54 and Korea, however, where a stronger legal tradition of providing security to patentees prevails,Footnote 55 courts generally require injunctions to be granted to protect patents when infringed.Footnote 56 It is in these latter jurisdictionsFootnote 57 that antitrust law has most often been raised as a possible mechanism for precluding the grant of the injunction on the basis that an injunction might harm competition and that the patentee’s investment incentives can be protected, as envisaged, not through exclusion but through FRAND licensing. In 2012, the European Commission launched investigations against both Samsung and Motorola Mobility for possible breaches of Article 102,Footnote 58 in particular by seeking injunctions to enforce the SEPs in Germany. It articulated concerns that in the exceptional circumstances of the case (involving a standard-setting process and Samsung’s and Motorola’s commitments to license their SEPs on FRAND terms and conditions), the seeking of preliminary and permanent injunctions against Apple might be incompatible with Article 102. These actions, which eventually culminated in, respectively a commitments and infringement decision,Footnote 59 fuelled concern that, in the context of SEPs at least, German law might be making injunctions available in circumstances in which the seeking, and subsequent enforcing, of the injunction violated Article 102.Footnote 60 It was for this reason that the Landgericht Düsseldorf stayed patent litigation between Huawei and ZTE and referred a number of questions to the CJEU relating to the application of Article 102 to the conduct of SEP holders. Essentially, the questions referred asked whether German law was sufficient to prevent abusive conduct by SEP holders or whether Article 102 applies more stringently to constrain the ordinary rights of patentees, at least where the IP at issue is a FRAND-committed SEP.
In its Huawei judgment, the CJEU confirmed that although antitrust does not generally interfere with the exercise of IP rights, it might constrain the behavior of an IP rightsholder that has a dominant position in exceptional circumstances. In addition, the Court clarified that such circumstances might exist in a case such as the one before it, involving de jure standardization and a dominant SEP holderFootnote 61 that had made a FRAND commitment. The Court held that such a patentee may infringe Article 102 if it seeks an injunction, or an order for recall of products, in patent litigation against the user of standardized technology in circumstances where it had not taken certain steps to comply with its FRAND commitment and to ensure a fair balance between the interests involved.Footnote 62 Such compliance requires as a starting point that the SEP holder: (i) give the alleged infringer notice of its infringement (even if the latter was already using the teaching of the SEP); and, if the implementer expresses a willingness to conclude a FRAND license, (ii) present a specific, written FRAND offer specifying the royalty and the way it is to be calculated. If these steps are taken, the Court held that the implementer must diligently respond to that offer, in accordance with recognized commercial practices in the field and in good faith,Footnote 63 and, if it does not accept the offer, respond promptly and in writing with a specific counteroffer that corresponds to FRAND terms.Footnote 64 Where no FRAND agreement is reached following a counteroffer,Footnote 65 the parties may, by common agreement, request that the amount of the royalty be determined by an independent third party, by decision without delay.Footnote 66
The Commission Communication on SEPs sheds light, taking account of subsequent case law in national courts, on the Commission’s understanding of the Huawei criteria. In particular, it states:Footnote 67
a. A prospective licensee is entitled to receive sufficiently detailed information to determine the relevance of the SEP portfolio and the compliance of the offer with FRAND requirements. Determination of whether this requirement has been met is fact sensitive and will vary from case to case. However, the Commission believes that clear explanations are necessary on such matters as “the essentiality for a standard, the allegedly infringing products of the SEP user, the proposed royalty calculation and the non-discrimination element of FRAND.”
b. The prospective licensee’s counteroffer “should be concrete and specific” and “cannot be limited to contesting the SEP holder’s offer” and making “a general reference to third-party determination of the royalty.” The counteroffer should also provide information “on the exact use of the standard in the specific product.” The willingness of the parties to submit to a binding third-party FRAND determination is considered to be evidence of FRAND-compliant behavior.
c. No general benchmark can be established to determine the timeliness of the counteroffer by the prospective licensee. Relevant factors include “the number of asserted SEPs and the details contained in the infringement claim.” The Commission considers that there may well be a “trade-off between the time considered as reasonable for responding to the offer and the detail and quality of the information provided in the SEP holder’s initial offer.” Furthermore, the more (reliable and up-to-date) information available to the prospective licensee through the SDO’s database, the shorter the time required to make a counteroffer.
d. The security to be provided by the implementer as protection for the SEP holder when a claim for an injunction is denied “should be fixed at a level that discourages patent hold-out strategies.” The Commission considers that “similar considerations could apply when assessing the magnitude of damages.”
The judgment in Huawei, complemented by national case law and the Commission Communication on SEPs, thus seeks to craft, for the European Union, some degree of operational guidance for both SEP owners and implementers to follow.Footnote 68 Not only do these allow SEP owners to ensure that their conduct is compatible with Article 102 (compliance with the stipulated procedure provides an antitrust safe harbor for them), but it clearly delineates steps that implementers must take in the FRAND negotiation process (to prevent holdout).
Although the judgment is very fact specific, the Court stressed the salient features of the case that contributed to its finding that, in exceptional circumstances, seeking an injunction or an order for recall by a patentee may constitute an abuse of a dominant position contrary to Article 102:
The patents at issue only had SEP status because of the owner’s irrevocable FRAND commitment.
The SEPs were essential to the standard and, consequently, indispensable to competitors manufacturing products complying with the standard. This meant that a SEP holder could, by bringing an action for injunction or recall, prevent competitors’ products from appearing or remaining on the market and reserve to itself the manufacture of products.
The FRAND commitment created legitimate expectations that a FRAND license would be granted (so a refusal to do so may in principle constitute an abuse).Footnote 69
The Court thus referred to some likely anticompetitive effects on products reading on the standard: Products manufactured by competitors could be prevented from being launched or remaining on the market so that a vertically integrated SEP holder could “reserve to itself the manufacture of the product in question.”Footnote 70 This identified concern thus relates to the parameters of product competition in the market for the products reading on the standard: price, innovation, and choice. The Court was not, however, explicit about the impact of the conduct under review on the standard-setting process itself.Footnote 71 Yet, the emphasis placed on the legitimate expectation that a FRAND commitment creates as one of the grounds or conditions for a potential finding of infringementFootnote 72 might suggest that the Court was also concerned, implicitly, about likely anticompetitive effects on the integrity of the standard-setting process and, ultimately, on the success of the standard. From a policy perspective, it would indeed appear that the undermining of the standard-setting process (and, ultimately, of the success of the standard) as a result of non-FRAND-compliant behavior by any SEP holder is capable of having the same type of a negative impact on price, innovation, and choice on the market for the products reading on the standard as non-FRAND-compliant behavior by a vertically integrated SEP holder who reserves to itself the manufacture of the product in question.
As regards the need to ensure an adequate protection of the SEP, the Court seemed to consider that the patentee’s investment incentives would be protected by its ability to recover FRAND licensing terms and that by giving the FRAND commitment it had demonstrated its intention to monetize its patents in this way.Footnote 73 The benefits to competition safeguarded in the manufactured product market would not therefore be offset by damage to investment in the upstream market.
In some respects, however, the Court left certain matters, or the exact scope of its judgment, unclear. For example, national courts in the EU Member States have subsequently had to wrestle with the question of exactly how the procedure described within it is actually to be implemented and, consequently, when a SEP holder can seek an injunction without infringing Article 102 and when an implementer can resist an injunction application on competition law grounds.Footnote 74 Chapter 5 discusses cases that deal with the question of what each party needs to do to establish it has been engaged in good-faith licensing negotiations.Footnote 75
In addition, by confining the scope of its judgment to the facts of the case, namely a situation where the SEP holder that had given the FRAND commitment manufactured and sold products on the basis of the licensed technology, and placing emphasis both on competition between the patentee and implementer in the manufactured product market and the giving of the FRAND commitment, the Court did not clarify whether the same obligations would bind a subsequent nonpracticing purchaser of the SEPs that does not compete in the market for products based on the licensed technology and that did not give the original FRAND commitment. Although in such cases the nature of the conduct is exploitative rather than exclusionary,Footnote 76 it is possible that the Court would reach the same conclusion on the question of whether the conduct is abusive. If a FRAND commitment is given by, or binds, the subsequent purchaser, that purchaser also agrees not to exploit the SEP’s market power and to license only on FRAND terms. Further, the impact of the conduct on competition in the products market and on standardization is potentially the same – irrespective of whether the SEP holder competes in the product market or whether it was the PAE itself or its predecessor that created legitimate expectations that the technology would be licensed on FRAND terms.
Chapter 5 explains that competition authorities in other jurisdictions (including Korea) have also considered whether injunction actions by SEP holders might result in violations of both FRAND commitments and antitrust laws. For example, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) in the United States has been concerned that seeking injunctive relief can be coercive and oppressive and an “unfair method of competition” contrary to Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914.Footnote 77
2 Monetary Damages and Future Licensing Terms
Even if a SEP holder is not permitted to seek an injunction against a willing licensee, it is still entitled to damages for past infringement of the patent and to royalties for future licensing.
Indeed, in the European Union the General Court in ITT Promedia NV v. Commission stressed the importance of the principle of access to court both as a fundamental right and a general principle ensuring the rule of law.Footnote 78 In Huawei, the CJEU also recognized the high level of protection conferred by EU law on patentees who could not in principle be deprived of their right to have recourse to legal proceedings to ensure effective enforcement of their exclusive rights. Its acceptance in that case that the seeking of an injunction by a FRAND-committed SEP holder might, exceptionally, constitute an abuse of a dominant position, did not deny the patentee access to court or the right to bring legal proceedings. On the contrary, it made clear that a SEP holder was not prohibited “from bringing an action for infringement against the alleged infringer of its SEP and seeking the rendering of accounts in relation to past acts of use of that SEP or an award of damages in respect of those acts of use”;Footnote 79 if an injunction is not available the SEP holder may thus seek other remedies to safeguard its patent rights in the legal proceedings, including damages for past infringement and the determination of future licensing terms.
Chapter 5 discusses the extent to which principles governing damages awarded in cases where a SEP holder has given a FRAND commitment should differ from those generally governing damages awards in patent infringement cases and how damages should relate to any determination of future FRAND licensing terms.Footnote 80 The sections below consider whether competition law might, however, impose additional obligations that may affect SEP licensing arrangements above and beyond those imposed by the FRAND commitment, and hence the level of monetary damages to which a FRAND-committed SEP holder is entitled when an unlicensed implementer infringes the SEP. In particular, it considers whether, and if so when, competition law may control unfair royalty levels, the tying or bundling of SEPS, price discrimination, and the transfer of SEPs.
6.3.3 Antitrust Limits on the Commercial Exploitation of Patents
1 Pricing of Patent Licenses: Excessive or Unfair Pricing
Competition law may in certain circumstances constrain the ability of a SEP holder to set the royalty rate for its SEPs or to negotiate the licensing conditions that it thinks fit. This is particularly true in jurisdictions, such as the European Union, the People’s Republic of China, and India, that prohibit not only exclusionary abuses by dominant firms but also exploitative conduct, consisting in the application of excessive or unfair prices or other unfair contractual conditions regardless of any exclusionary effect. The question of whether, and if so when, it should impact on exploitative conduct is likely to become more topical as 5G technology develops and standards relating to the Internet of Things are adopted.Footnote 81
In the European Union, for example, Article 102 prohibits exploitative practices, including unfair prices, unfair trading conditions, and the provision of substandard products or services (Article 102(a);Footnote 82 and Article 102(b) prohibits the limitation of production, markets, or technical development to the prejudice of consumers.Footnote 83 It may therefore constitute an abuse for a dominant SEP holder to charge a price that has “no reasonable relation to the economic value of the product supplied”Footnote 84 or to impose “directly or indirectly … unfair trading conditions,”Footnote 85 whether or not it has made a FRAND commitment. In Rambus,Footnote 86 the Commission accepted commitments from Rambus, a patentee that had not made a FRAND commitment, but which it nonetheless accused of charging excessive royalties for the use of patented technology relating to dynamic random access memory (DRAM).Footnote 87 The Commission took the view that these royalties could not have been claimed if Rambus had not intentionally deceived the SSO, Joint Electron Device Engineering Council (JEDEC), and its members, by not disclosing the existence of patents and patent applications relating to technology relevant to the adopted standardFootnote 88 (because had it disclosed the existence of the patents and patent applications, another standard would probably have been adopted and Rambus’s technologies would not have been essential to the standard).Footnote 89 Although the Commission did not state, in the commitments decision, its legal basis for believing that the conduct in question was abusive, it seems clear that a core concern was that the conduct was exploitative. Rambus’s unilateral conduct in allegedly deceiving the SSO and its members, which could have excluded competing technologies from the standard, could not have infringed Article 102 because Rambus was not, at that point, alleged to be dominant (and EU law does not, unlike U.S. law, prevent attempts to monopolize or dominate a market). Rambus only became dominant following the alleged exclusion and the adoption of the standard. To bring the proceedings to an end, Rambus committed to offer licenses to DRAM manufacturers and manufacturers of memory controller products at royalties not exceeding a stipulated cap for a period of five years. Rambus also committed not to seek further royalties for the licensed patents from the licensee’s customers.Footnote 90
In Unwired Planet,Footnote 91 the English High Court also had to consider whether a breach of a FRAND commitment by an NPE could constitute an exploitative abuse contrary to Article 102. In considering this issue, Birss J distinguished three scenarios: a price advanced in negotiation, a price demanded by a vendor backed by a refusal to supply at any other price, and a price agreed upon and paid.Footnote 92 In relation to a price advanced in negotiations, the judge considered that it was normal that the prospective licensor would start from a position that is higher than FRAND. Simply offering a non-FRAND royalty could not therefore constitute an abuse; it only would be if the offered rate was so high that it would disrupt or prejudice the negotiations.Footnote 93 This did not mean, of course, that the actual imposition of such rates in the agreed license or a refusal to license other than at those rates could not be an abuse of dominance, especially if obtained under the threat of an injunction. Birss J considered, however, that a royalty rate would not be excessive unless it substantially exceeded the FRAND rate; in other words, a FRAND royalty could not be an abusive one and a royalty in excess of FRAND would not necessarily be abusive.Footnote 94
The Commission Communication on SEPs sets out some high-level principles for the valuation of SEPs and the assessment of FRAND licensing terms:Footnote 95
a. Licensing terms need to bear a clear relationship to the economic value of the patented technology.Footnote 96 Such a value should not include a premium resulting from the decision to include the technology in the standard.
b. Determining a FRAND value should require “taking into account the present value added of the patented technology.” The present value added of the technology should be irrespective of the market success of the product that is unrelated to the patented technology.
c. FRAND valuation should ensure that SEP holders continue to have incentives to contribute their best available technologies to standards.
d. FRAND valuation should also depend on a reasonable aggregate royalty rate for the standard, to avoid royalty stacking.
What might be considered to be an unfairly high price has also been considered under the Chinese Antimonopoly Law, including by the National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) of the People’s Republic of China in Qualcomm.Footnote 97 In this case it held that Qualcomm had abused its dominant position in the markets for licensing SEPs covering CDMA, WCDMA, and LTE wireless communication, as well as in the market of baseband chips. In particular, the NDRC had concerns about the following conduct in relation to Chinese licensees: (1) refusing to disclose patent lists; (2) charging licensing fees for expired patents included in patent portfolio; (3) requiring a free cross-license of the Chinese licensees’ own relevant patents (so refusing to deduct the value of such cross-licensed patents from its licensing fees); and (4) charging royalties on the basis of the net wholesale price of the device and imposing a relatively high royalty rate on licensees who had been forced to accept Qualcomm’s packaged licensing of non-SEPs. The NDRC found that the combination of these different strands of conduct resulted in excessively high, and abusive, royalties and abusive terms. If a potential licensee did not agree to them, Qualcomm would simply refuse to supply baseband chips to it. The NDRC levied a fine of RMB 6 billionFootnote 98 and imposed a number of behavioral remedies on Qualcomm. In particular, following the proceedings, Qualcomm agreed to charge royalties for 3G and 4G Chinese SEPs for branded smartphones sold for use in China of 5 percent for 3G devices and 3.5 percent for 4G phones on a royalty base of 65 percent of the net selling price of the smartphone; to provide patent lists when entering into a license with Chinese licensees and not to charge licensing fees for expired patents; not to request a free cross-license from Chinese licensees; not to request that Chinese licensees enter into a patent-license agreement including unreasonable conditions when selling baseband chips; and not to condition the supply of baseband chips to Chinese licensees on the obligation not to challenge such patent-license agreement.Footnote 99
Similarly, in Huawei Technologies Co Ltd v. InterDigital Group, the Shenzhen Intermediate People’s Court found that InterDigital had abused its dominant position in certain markets concerning 3G wireless communications technology both in the People’s Republic of China and in the United States by engaging in excessive and discriminatory abuses – by requiring Huawei to pay much higher royalties than those charged by InterDigital to Apple and Samsung and by forcing Huawei to give InterDigital a license to all Huawei’s patents. It also held that it had abused its dominant position by tying SEPS to non-SEPS and imposing unreasonable licensing conditions on Huawei. The fact that InterDigital had made a FRAND commitment appeared central to the ruling of the Court that InterDigital had to adhere to principles of fairness, reasonableness, and nondiscrimination when negotiating, entering into, and performing a license agreement relating to its SEPs.Footnote 100
In proceedings against Ericsson, the Competition Commission of India set out its preliminary view that Ericsson’s practice of charging a royalty based on the value of the end product produced by the implementer is excessive, discriminatory, and contrary to FRAND terms. Following protracted litigation over the jurisdiction of the CCI in this case, the proceedings have still not been finalized.Footnote 101
2 Tying, Bundling, and Price Discrimination
A number of other questions have also arisen in relation to contract, patent, and antitrust law in the sphere of SEPs and complex products. These include whether the following practices of a patentee might infringe a FRAND commitment or competition law (and whether the FRAND commitment is coextensive with, or distinct from, the competition law obligation): a decision by a SEP holder to require a licensee to take a global license, where the licensee is interested only in a license of more limited scope, and/or to take a license of both SEPs and non-SEPs, where the licensee is interested only in a license of SEPs; a decision to calculate licensing rates not by reference to the smallest saleable unit but to a percentage of net sales of the final product; a decision by a SEP holder to enforce its patents against entities at different levels of the vertical/production chain (e.g., against chipmakers, mobile phone manufacturersFootnote 102 and/or mobile phone network operators) and/or to charge different royalty rates to licensees at different levels of the chain;Footnote 103 or a decision by a SEP holder to license only mobile phone manufacturers but not chipmakers. Such practices could, in principle, be appraised as forms of excessive pricing tying,Footnote 104 bundling,Footnote 105 or price discrimination, which can infringe competition rules in some circumstances. Indeed, many jurisdictions have specific rules that target both tying/bundlingFootnote 106 and price discrimination. In some, price discrimination laws may go beyond the aim of preventing exploitation of market power or the foreclosure of competitors and may be aimed at preventing market distortion, whether at the upstream or downstream level, for example by putting one buyer at a disadvantage vis-à-vis another.Footnote 107
A number of these issues have arisen in a protracted battle between Apple and Qualcomm being played out in courts and competition agencies across the globe (in particular, before the English High Court,Footnote 108 as well as in the United States, Germany,Footnote 109 Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and China).
a) Qualcomm
It has already been seen that the complaints against Qualcomm have alleged that it has engaged in a number of interrelated, anticompetitive exploitative and exclusionary licensing practices. Some complaints have alleged that Qualcomm has withheld baseband processors unless a customer accepts a license of its SEPs on Qualcomm’s preferred terms (“no license-no chips” – resulting in non-FRAND licensing terms being extracted), a refusal to license SEPs to competing baseband processor manufacturers, and the bundling of SEPs and non-SEPs. In China, the NDRC in QualcommFootnote 110 supported the principle that a SEP holder is not permitted to bundle SEPs and non-SEPs in the same license.
b) Unwired Planet
In Unwired Planet, Birss J also had to deal with claims of unlawful tying and discrimination. In so doing he held that an offer to grant a worldwide portfolio license, a common industry practice with potential efficiency benefits, instead of a license limited to the United Kingdom, was FRAND and did not automatically infringe Article 102; a worldwide license was not inherently likely to distort competition.Footnote 111 It might infringe Article 102, however, if three conditions were fulfilled:Footnote 112
2. The customer was coerced to obtain the tied product together with the tying product.
3. The tying must have an anticompetitive foreclosure effect; excluding equally efficient competitors and resulting in the acquisition, maintenance, or strengthening of market power on an affected market (the tying market, the tied market, or a related emerging market).
In relation to the bundling of SEPs and non-SEPs, however, Birss J was concerned that such conduct might foreclose competition for non-SEP technologies.Footnote 113 In addition, he held that the nondiscrimination limb of the ETSI FRAND undertaking meant that “a benchmark FRAND rate should be derived which is applicable to all licensees seeking the same kind of licence.”Footnote 114 In so doing he indicated that the FRAND obligation may differ from the competition law one. In particular, the FRAND requirement may if anything be broader, applying even if the SEP holder is not dominantFootnote 115 and even if the discrimination does not cause a distortion of competition between licensees.
c) Multilevel Licensing and Level Discrimination
The teaching of a SEP may be utilized by the manufacturer of a product (e.g., a chip) that is incorporated into another product (e.g. a mobile phone), which is then sold by a provider of a service (e.g., a mobile network provider) to a final consumer.Footnote 116 The doctrine of patent exhaustion prohibits a SEP holder from demanding a license from each supplier down the chain. Nonetheless, the following questions have arisen, particularly in cases before the German courts:
(a) Which level of the chain should the patent license be granted – in particular, can the patentee choose the licensing point and/or can an implementer (e.g., an end-product manufacturer) refuse to take a license on the basis that the patentee should have licensed the SEP at a different level (e.g., a component manufacturer)?
(b) Can the level of licensing affect the level of the royalty to be paid? For example, might licensing further down the chain allow the SEP holder to extract higher licensing fees, because the royalty is calculated on the basis of a percentage of the (higher) value of the product or service sold by the licensee, or would that infringe the principle of fair and nondiscriminatory licensing required both by a FRAND commitment and some competition law systems?Footnote 117
The general approach by the European Commission in the Guidelines on horizontal cooperation agreements and the enforcement practice so far arguably suggest that level discrimination may be problematic and that generally participants wishing to have their patent rights included in a standard should provide an irrevocable commitment to offer to license their essential patents to all (and any) third parties on FRAND terms.Footnote 118 The Commission has thus indicated concern that some suits arising in Germany may be designed to allow SEP holders to circumvent the obligations imposed on them by the CJEU’s ruling in Huawei and has stated that it is monitoring the cases carefully. In the cases arising before the German courts, some SEP owners have commenced injunction proceedings not against phone manufacturers but against mobile network operators (which sell phones), alleging infringement of SEPs. The German courts have, to date, suggested that although in principle every market participant should be entitled to take a FRAND license, a patentee is free to choose which implementer in the chain it wishes to sue for infringement, unless it appears to be part of an undue strategy to extract non-FRAND licensing terms.Footnote 119 If there is a concern with level discrimination, however, such a concern would not result from the prohibition of discrimination by dominant undertakings under Article 102(c) TFEU. As the Commission Communication on SEPs points out, a SEP holder may not discriminate between licensees who are “similarly situated.”Footnote 120 A final service provider or manufacturer is not, however, “similarly situated” to a component manufacturer. Level discrimination may, nevertheless, be problematic if the FRAND commitment is broadly framed as a commitment to license any third party and if component manufacturers were unable to manufacture components without a license. If such conditions occur, it is arguable that the broad tenet, if not the letter, of the Huawei judgment would require the SEP holder to grant a FRAND license to component manufacturers.Footnote 121 The issue is, however, still open.
A further question is whether a SEP holder that engages in multilevel licensing infringes discrimination provisions, if it discriminates between users on the basis of the utility of the patented technology to the licensee.Footnote 122 “Licensing only at the end-user product level and multi-level licensing are not rare, but there is a paucity of judicial authority as to how those strategies should be viewed under FRAND.”Footnote 123 As explained above, the Commission Communication on SEPs considers that a SEP holder may treat differently licensees who are not “similarly situated.”
3 Patent Pools
An important question in the sphere of complex products could be whether a technology or patent pool, an arrangement whereby two or more entities assemble a package of technology that is licensed both to contributors to the pool and third parties, might be a feasible mechanism for eradicating some of the more difficult problems that arise from individual licensing negotiations between SEP owners and implementers. Technology pools have often been used to support a de jure or de facto industry standard and may provide a convenient way for facilitating dissemination of technology through one-stop licensing of pooled technologies and reducing transaction costs and limiting cumulative royalties. In the mobile communications field, however, they have not been successfully used to date, perhaps because the largest SEP holders think they can extract better licensing terms outside of the pool.
Competition law systems generally recognize that technology pools may be procompetitive but are also concerned about the competitive risks that might arise from the licensing of substitute technologies (creating a risk of price-fixing or market-sharing) or as a result of a reduction of innovation from foreclosing alternative, competing technologies.Footnote 124 In assessing the compatibility of such arrangements with competition law rules therefore account is frequently taken of issues such as: the transparency of the pool creation process; the selection and nature of the pooled technologies; whether the technologies are complementary or substitutes, essential or nonessential; the institutional framework of the pool; the market position of the pool and whether it can foreclose third party technologies or limit the creation of alternative pools;Footnote 125 as well as the licensing terms. In the European Union, for example, the Technology Transfer Guidelines state that “royalties and other licensing terms should be non-excessive and non-discriminatory and licences should be non-exclusive. These requirements are necessary to ensure that the pool is open and does not lead to foreclosure and other anti-competitive effects on down-stream markets.”Footnote 126 The Commission has also, with the objective of encouraging the conclusion of procompetitive pools, set out a safe harbor for the creation of certain technology pools and subsequent licensing of the technology.Footnote 127 In particular, the Commission takes the view that the creation and operation of the pool, including the licensing out, generally falls outside Article 101(1) of the Treaty, irrespective of the market position of the parties, if all the following conditions are fulfilled:
a) participation in the pool creation process is open to all interested technology rights owners;
b) sufficient safeguards are adopted to ensure that only essential technologies (which therefore necessarily are also complements) are pooled;
c) sufficient safeguards are adopted to ensure that exchange of sensitive information (such as pricing and output data) is restricted to what is necessary for the creation and operation of the pool;
d) the pooled technologies are licensed into the pool on a nonexclusive basis;
e) the pooled technologies are licensed out to all potential licensees on FRAND terms;
f) the parties contributing technology to the pool and the licensees are free to challenge the validity and the essentiality of the pooled technologies; and
g) the parties contributing technology to the pool and the licensee remain free to develop competing products and technology.Footnote 128
The Commission Communication on SEPs recognizes that patent pools and other licensing platforms may be procompetitive but does not go beyond a mere statement of principle, which could already be derived from general principles of EU competition law.Footnote 129
4 Splitting Patent Portfolios: Sales of SEPs to PAEs in Return for a Share of Future Royalties
Apart from the difficulties involved in identifying competition-compliant FRAND licensing terms, further problems have arisen when owners of SEPs have sought to monetize their patent portfolio and increase revenue from it (so increasing their competitors’ costs), by splitting itFootnote 130 and selling part of the portfolio to a PAE that does not itself produce standardized equipment.Footnote 131
In some such transfers the transaction has been structured not as a genuine clean sale of patents for a purchase price, but as one under which the PAE is essentially acting as a licensing (and litigation service) provider to the vendor whereby the PAE is obliged to pay a percentage of future royalties it obtains to the vendor (described by some as “privateering”).Footnote 132 Instead of the vendor licensing its entire portfolio, therefore, it splits the portfolio, licensing the SEPs it retains and gaining a percentage of the royalties obtained by the NPE in respect of the SEPs transferred; the NPE and former patentee thus share the royalty income. This was the scenario that existed in relation to litigation in England involving Unwired Planet, an NPEFootnote 133 that acquired 2,400 wireless patents from Ericsson and sued Huawei, Google, and Samsung for infringement of six of the patents (five of which were claimed to be SEPs).Footnote 134 The alleged infringers in these cases raised defenses and counterclaims based on breaches of competition law. In particular, they argued that the master sales agreement (MSA) by which Unwired Patent acquired patents from Ericsson and under which Ericsson received a share of the royalties recovered by Unwired Planet, infringed Article 101 TFEU on the grounds that it was simply a device for increasing income over and beyond FRAND terms, thus rendering the transfer of the patents null and void. A further argument concerned the question of whether, if a valid transfer had taken place, Unwired Planet’s license offers were FRAND and/or infringed Art 102 and thus whether they had abused their dominant position by bringing injunction proceedings; key battlegrounds centered around the royalty rate offered and the proper scope of any license.
The question of whether the MSA infringed Article 101 was not determined in the English proceedings.Footnote 135 Although Birss J refused an attempt by Ericsson to strike out this aspect of the action, holding that it was a properly arguable point that ought to go to trial, this aspect of the case was settled and a term in the MSA, which arguably put a floor on the royalty rate (the Applicable Royalty Rate) that Unwired Planet could offer, was removed. In the German proceedings,Footnote 136 in contrast, the Düsseldorf Regional Court rejected the argument that the assignment of the patents was invalid under Art 101 or 102 and that the purpose of the assignment was to establish excessive pricing beyond FRAND. The Court in particular rejected the argument that this was by its very nature anticompetitive and that the object of the assignment was to establish excessive pricing in the market, in particular pricing that exceeds the FRAND benchmark. It did not agree that it was illegitimate for a SEP proprietor to seek to acquire a better position in the negotiation process by splitting up its SEP portfolio, or that the NPEFootnote 137 was obliged to continue the licensing practice of the former SEP owner; the only requirement was that its licensing should be FRAND. The Court thus held that targeting a fair remuneration for a patent portfolio was a legitimate and legal objective.
5 Patent Acquisitions
When conducting merger review, competition agencies have in some cases taken into account the impact the merger will have on the incentives of the merging firms to engage in anticompetitive behavior post-merger, including through the exploitation of SEPs.
For example, when reviewing Google’s acquisition of Motorola and the acquisition by Apple, Microsoft, and Research in Motion (part of the Rockstar consortium) of Nortel and Apple’s acquisition of certain Novell patents, the antitrust division of the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) considered the potential ability and incentives of the acquiring firms to use their patents, especially the SEPs that Nortel and Motorola had committed to license, to raise rivals’ costs, to hold up rivals,Footnote 138 and to foreclose and substantially lessen competition. During the course of the investigation, several of the competitors, including Apple and Microsoft, made FRAND licensing commitments and committed not to seek injunctions in disputes involving SEPS, lessening the DOJ’s concerns about the potential anticompetitive use of SEPs. In the end, the DOJ concluded that the transactions were not likely substantially to lessen competition for wireless devices or change significantly existing market dynamics so did not challenge the merger. The DOJ made it clear, however, that it was concerned about the inappropriate use of SEPs, particularly by Google, post-merger and that it would continue to monitor their use to ensure that competition and innovation were unfettered.
During the course of this investigation the U.S. agency worked closely with other competition agencies, including in Australia, Canada, Israel, and Korea, and especially the European Commission. The Commission was also concerned by the fact that Google’s open-source Android OS, one of the most popular mobile operating systems (OS), and a number of Motorola’s SEPs were key inputs in smart mobile devices. However, it cleared the merger unconditionally in Phase I proceedings.Footnote 139 With regard to the SEPs, the Commission did not consider that the merger would significantly change the current position and was also influenced by Google’s “legally binding” and “irrevocable” letter to standard-setting organizations to honor Motorola’s pre-existing commitment to license them on FRAND terms. Further, it did not consider that Google would have the incentive to prevent Motorola’s competitors from using its OS as that would stifle the spread of its other services. In China, the merger was approved only subject to conditions.Footnote 140
6.4 Antitrust Remedies
Most competition law systems rely on a mixture of public and private enforcement in civil (or exceptionally criminal) proceedings to protect society’s interest in the efficient working of markets and to ensure that victims can protect themselves from violations and receive compensation where necessary. A number rely (or have initially at least relied) heavily on public enforcement agencies to bring antitrust cases that define policy and prevent, deter, and punish serious violations of the law. Private litigation is now developing in many jurisdictions, and in the United States, the preponderance of antitrust enforcement occurs through private actions.
Remedies available for violations of antitrust and competition law broadly include monetary, behavioral, and injunctive remedies.Footnote 141 When actions are brought by enforcement agencies, monetary remedies typically take the form of penalties and fines intended to deter the particular harm in question and to punish the liable party. In private actions, monetary damages are typically compensatory, though in some jurisdictions, particularly in the United States, enhanced monetary awards (treble damages and attorneys’ fees, this latter element as an exception to the general rule of non-recoverability of legal costs in that jurisdiction) may be available.Footnote 142
In addition to compensatory damages, both private parties and enforcement agencies may seek behavioral remedies that are intended to deter, halt, and correct violations.Footnote 143 Injunctive relief in antitrust cases generally seeks to remedy a harm caused by anticompetitive conduct and to prevent its recurrence. Thus, in the case of price fixing between competitors, remedial measures may simply prohibit further price fixing. In monopolization or dominance cases, a remedial order may prohibit a dominant firm from carrying on a particular business within certain markets or, exceptionally, require a firm to divest certain business units or subsidiaries. The range of remedies in antitrust cases is thus quite broad, including cease and desist orders (for example, prohibiting the seeking of an injunction or the charging of exploitative royalties), affirmative obligations (e.g., an obligation to license or to license on competition compliant terms), structural remedies (such as structural separation of business units), and other sanctions. Such remedies may impact, or override, rights and remedies conferred by patent law by, for example, preventing a patent owner from seeking an injunction (through a cease and desist order), ordering a compulsory license, nullifying the sale of patent rights, or interfering with licensing arrangements or terms. They may also subsequently require close scrutiny or monitoring for compliance. In general, the scope of antitrust injunctive relief sought by enforcement agencies can be as broad as necessary “to bring about the dissolution or suppression of” the illegal conduct.Footnote 144 As such, these remedies, which must account for effects on the public and the marketplace, are considered to be more sweeping forms of relief than injunctive relief between private litigants.Footnote 145
A decision-maker might be reluctant to intervene to prohibit certain conduct under competition law – for example, a refusal to license or the seeking of an injunction by a patentee – if it believes that a simple cease and desist order, prohibiting the unlawful conduct identified, and its recurrence, would be insufficient to ensure that the infringement is brought to an end. If an effective remedy requires more, the court or agency must undertake both a careful consideration of the appropriate terms of dealing (especially pricing) as well as the realistic prospects for monitoring of that behavior in the future. In the United States, for example, the Supreme Court has on some occasions expressed reluctance to find that a refusal to deal or a margin squeeze constitutes a substantive antitrust violation in circumstances where such a violation would require the courts to act as central planners, involved in the construction of “fair” access terms or the setting of “fair” prices or spreads between prices, a task to which the Supreme Court felt the courts were ill-suited.Footnote 146 In the European Union, the difficulty of ensuring the effectiveness of the antitrust intervention has also proved to be real. In the Microsoft case,Footnote 147 for example, the Commission and Microsoft, following the Commission’s initial fining of Microsoft for its failure to supply interoperability information, wrangled for several years over the appropriate terms for supplying the interoperability information; eventually the Commission fined Microsoft a second time for its failure to comply.Footnote 148
An important point in relation to remedies is that in many jurisdictions, mechanisms also exist to bring antitrust proceedings to an end by consent. These may allow for remedies to be agreed to more flexibly between an antitrust agency and investigated firms. For example, in the European Union the Commission has power to adopt decisions whereby, without a finding of infringement, commitments given by undertaking as to their future behavior are made binding upon them.Footnote 149 This procedure has been used quite frequently in dominance cases, and, arguably, has sometimes resulted in firms committing to behavioral or structural obligations that go beyond that which could have been imposed by the Commission in a final decision. Such commitments may involve a monitoring trustee mechanism to ensure their implementation. The commitments procedure was used by the Commission, in both Rambus and Samsung, to develop its use of Article 102 to SEPs, prior to its adoption of an infringement decision in Motorola.Footnote 150
In the United States, both the DOJ and the FTC can also enter into consent decrees. The procedures differ, but if the DOJ and the defendant agree on the terms of a desired order prior to or during the course of litigation, they may stipulate the terms of a “consent decree,” which will then be submitted to the court for approval and entry into the record. Though not fully adjudicated, a consent decree has the legal force of an adjudicated decision, enforceable upon pain of contempt.Footnote 151
This procedure has also been relied upon quite frequently by the U.S. authorities in enforcement actions involving the anticompetitive licensing or exploitation of patents, particularly (in recent years) within the context of technical standard-setting. Thus, between World War II and the 1970s, the most aggressive period of U.S. antitrust enforcement,Footnote 152 U.S. courts issued more than one hundred antitrust decrees ordering patentees found to have engaged in anticompetitive conduct to license their patents on terms that were fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory.Footnote 153 Even in the more tempered modern era of antitrust enforcement, both the FTC and DOJ have utilized detailed behavioral remedies to address instances of antitrust violations involving patents, particularly in the area of standard-setting.Footnote 154 The first of these to gain significant attention was the FTC’s 1996 consent decree with Dell Computer, in which Dell agreed to forfeit the enforcement of a patent that it improperly failed to disclose to a standard-setting organization, thereby exploiting an unfair method of competition in violation of Section 5 of the FTC Act.Footnote 155 In a case involving similar allegations, Unocal entered into an agreement with the FTC not to enforce a patent covering a standard for reduced gasoline emissions after it failed to disclose the patent to the relevant standards body.Footnote 156
A different factual pattern was alleged in the FTC’s action against Negotiated Data Solutions (N-Data) LLC. In that case, N-Data acquired a patent with knowledge of a prior patentee’s commitment to license the patent to implementers of a technical standard at a flat rate of $1,000. When N-Data announced that it did not intend to honor that prior commitment, the FTC brought an action alleging violation of Section 5 of the FTC Act. N-Data settled the matter by agreeing to honor the prior patentee’s royalty commitment.Footnote 157
Finally, in 2013 the FTC settled two matters in which patentees were alleged to have violated Section 5 of the FTC Act by seeking injunctive relief against unlicensed implementers of a technical standard as to which they had made FRAND commitments.Footnote 158 In settling these cases, each of the patentees agreed not to seek an injunction to prevent the infringement of a FRAND-committed standards-essential patent by a willing licensee unless and until the patentee engaged in a series of good- faith attempts to reach agreement with the infringer.Footnote 159
These cases, taken together, demonstrate that the remedial orders fashioned by the U.S. antitrust agencies can be flexible mechanisms that are tailored to address specific forms of anticompetitive conduct. Remedies such as these arguably offer significantly more flexibility to improve competitive conditions than monetary damages or simple cease and desist orders such as those issued in private antitrust litigation.
6.5 Conclusions
Although competition and patent law pursue complementary goals, this chapter demonstrates that, in the sphere of complex products, tensions have arisen between the two systems, especially in situations where market power acquired by SEP owners as a result of a standardization process appears to have been used to exclude competition, hold up innovation, or exploit that market power to the detriment of consumers. In certain circumstances antitrust laws in some jurisdictions have been used to scrutinize mechanisms used by SEP holders to monetize their SEP portfolios – whether through the seeking of an injunction against an implementer, licensing arrangements, or through the sale of a portion of the patent portfolio. Its powerful mechanisms – formal and informal (e.g., through settlement processes) – to remedy infringements of its rules have also been used.
Section 6.2.1 discussed cases in which competition law has come directly into conflict with the patent system in some jurisdictions, by intervening to prevent a patentee from obtaining an injunction – its patent remedy of choice. This has been the case where the seeking of such an injunction has been found to be liable to hold up a willing licensee and impact on competition and innovation downstream and/or to compromise the standardization process, in circumstances where the SEP holder had committed to monetize its patent through FRAND licensing. These cases have, however, unleashed a number of other complex matters for resolution, including the scope of the obligations on the patentee and implementer and what each must do, respectively, to assert or avert injunctive relief. In the European Union, many of these questions have been working their way through the courts of Europe’s biggest market, Germany. Solutions to these issues are crucial if further disputes are not to break out between SEP holders and potential licensees, especially as 5G technology is developed, together with the Internet of Things.
These cases, and FRAND commitments given during a standard-setting procedure, have also brought to the forefront the question of when licensing complies both with a FRAND commitment and competition law. These issues are crucial to the questions of what patent damages for past infringement should look like and what a competition-compliant FRAND license should look like. Although until recently few courts outside of the United States have tackled these matters, some cases are emerging across the globe that deal with the validity of global or portfolio licenses and the question of whether licensing rates are “fair” or “discriminatory” in both FRAND and competition law terms (to the extent that they differ) or otherwise infringe antitrust law. Although it still remains unclear whether competition law makes more onerous demands on patent holders than FRAND, some competition enforcers have indicated that they have some concerns about “exploitative” behavior of SEP holders and that they might be willing to intervene to control behavior, balancing the rewards of innovation with the interests of consumers.
The questions of whether, and if so when, dividing or selling a SEP portfolio violates antitrust law and whether the principle of nondiscrimination requires a purchaser of a patent portfolio – especially where the purchaser is an NPE – to adopt the same approach to licensing as the vendor, are also important ones requiring resolution.
Balancing the interests of SEP holders and implementers is proving to be an extremely difficult task that is eluding SDOs and policymakersFootnote 160 and creating complexity for courts charged with resolving the patent disputes arising. In some cases competition agencies are also being asked to help solve the problems occurring and to protect the competitive process from distortion by a multitude of SEP holders with significant market power. Although traditionally competition decision-makers have been reluctant to act as regulators, controlling the pricing and terms of dealing, they are increasingly drawn into these matters in the sphere of patents and the debate as to how the competing interests are to be balanced. This chapter illustrates that a number of difficult issues at the interface of patent and antitrust law remain to be resolved in the sphere of complex products. Given the central role of standardization to 5G and the Internet of Things it is crucial that solutions are found to these problems.
Accordingly, we propose further research on the following topics:
the objectives of competition and patent law respectively and whether, and if so how, trade-offs between such objectives may be achieved or conflicts managed and resolved;
the steps that SEP holders must comply with to ensure that their seeking of an injunction does not infringe competition law, as well as the steps that implementers must take to allow them to lawfully resist an injunction;
the extent to which competition law can impose additional constraints on SEP licensing terms beyond those demanded by a FRAND commitment, in particular whether it impacts on the scope and contours of the obligations of a patentee and an implementer when negotiating a FRAND license of the patentee’s FRAND-committed patents and the consequences of breach of such obligations;
whether competition agencies can do more to encourage the use of procompetitive patent pools or other licensing platforms to address licensing challenges and as a model for licensing complex product patents;
the extent to which level discrimination, multilevel licensing, and the transfer of SEPs to PAEs may violate antitrust laws; and
whether, and if so when, the antitrust system and the portfolio or antitrust remedies offer greater flexibility to deal with some of the patent issues arising in the sphere of complex products.