I. Introduction
The current UK Government is committed to tackling unregulated and unaffordable ground rents in existing leases.Footnote 1 Parliamentarians have referred to the “abusive practices”Footnote 2 of “rip-off” escalating ground rents as the “PPI of the house building industry”.Footnote 3 It is a scandal that involves the creation of a new asset class “as ground rents rise and rise, and properties are … treated as a marketable commodity over the heads of the owner-occupiers”.Footnote 4 As Secretary of State for Levelling Up, Housing and Communities in the previous Conservative Government, Michael Gove made known his preference for a ground rent cap set at a peppercorn. The legislative amendment anticipated was for a £250 cap being phased out to a peppercorn over a 20-year period,Footnote 5 but the general election in July 2024 was called before the legislative plans were laid. We await proposals from the Labour Government elected in 2024. This article steps back from the reform plans and examines whether escalating ground rents in residential long leases are in any event legally enforceable.
What then is an escalating ground rent, and what is the problem? When a long residential lease is bought for a premium, there will also be a rent payable. This is the ground rent, but despite the nomenclature it is not a rent for the ground itself and is therefore quite different from a “site rent” payable under a building leaseFootnote 6 or a pitch fee used, for example, in caravan parks.Footnote 7 There are historical reasons for ground rents,Footnote 8 but these rents were nominal, sometimes a peppercorn.Footnote 9 Since the early 2000s the use of ground rents has changed significantly. “Modern long leases”Footnote 10 typically have higher initial ground rents (often in the low hundreds) and may also provide for the rent to increase at regular intervals. The most prevalent type of escalating clause is adjustment at stated intervals by reference to the Retail Prices Index (RPI). Others may provide for the rent to double at intervals. Referring to one example, Justin Madders M.P. said: “£350 a year for ground rent does not sound too bad, but in 50 years’ time it will be over £11,000, … and in 200 years’ time … it will be a staggering £367 million a year.”Footnote 11 The move to escalating clauses may simply be because developers recognised, and then exploited, the opportunity to create a significant new revenue stream, itself a tradable asset, but it has also been suggested that changes to Stamp Duty introduced by the Finance Act 2003 provided the opportunity to adopt this model without the cost to leaseholders being spotted.Footnote 12
Escalating ground rents affect the housing market: many lenders have policies that prevent lending where they are above a certain level (often £250 or 0.1 per cent of the freehold value) and property agents state that a leasehold property with an escalating ground rent will struggle to sell.Footnote 13 A high ground rent also significantly increases the purchase price for leaseholders seeking to enfranchise or extend their lease, sometimes making it prohibitively expensive.Footnote 14 For leaseholders the rising cost of rent, the inability to sell, and higher enfranchisement costs have negative impacts on well-being, mental health and the ability to make life decisions about moving and starting a family.Footnote 15
Even if reform stops future escalations, the legal arguments discussed here remain significant. It is argued that escalating ground rents may be unenforceable under section 62 of the Consumer Rights Act 2015 (CRA 2015) and may also be struck down under the doctrines of non-derogation from grant and repugnancy. This has various implications. First, and obviously, leaseholders do not have to pay. This may also mean that landlords are liable to refund rents already received. Additionally, it considerably weakens the claims of lobbyists that any reform by capping (or removing) ground rents would be an unjustified interference with a landlord’s human rights. The analysis also provides a case study on the application of section 62 to long-term contracts which are regularly assigned. There is very little discussion or authority on this. In its investigation into event fees in retirement properties – fees payable on certain events such as sale – the Law Commission noted the challenges of applying the CRA 2015 to residential leases.Footnote 16
Before examining the relevant law, Section II explains how escalating ground rents have been tackled to date. The meat of the argument is in Section III which examines the application of section 62 to escalating ground rent clauses. Section 62 provides that unfair terms in consumer contracts are not binding on a consumer, but some contract terms are excluded from an assessment for fairness. Section III(A) considers these exemptions but argues that they do not preclude an evaluation of the fairness of ground rent terms. Section III(B) considers how the fairness test applies to escalating ground rents clauses and concludes that many are likely to be found unfair. This benefits not only the original consumer leaseholder but also later owners as shown in Section III(C). Section III(D) provides a recap of how section 62 applies to escalating ground rents, and notes that the arguments made may go further and also apply to non-nominal initial rents. Section IV discusses an alternative argument that (some) ground rents may not be enforceable because of the separate, but closely related, concepts of derogation from grant and repugnancy. The following Section V then discusses the practical implications in relation to payment and refunds (Section V(A)) and what this means for the human rights objections to reform (Section V(B)). A conclusion follows.
II. Tackling Ground Rents
Ground rent investment became big business following the introduction of modern long leases. Escalating rents are seen as providing secure inflation-linked income with a low credit risk. Media stories report ground rent investors hoovering up portfolios from developers, with the developers sometimes retaining management of the housing.Footnote 17 A survey of institutional investors found that the value of residential ground rents held by 10 respondents in 2012 was £139 million; only three years later in 2015 the value of investments held by eight respondents was £1.9 billion.Footnote 18
Concern about onerous ground rents was first raised in Parliament in 2016,Footnote 19 noting an outcry in a number of media reports that 10-year “doublers” can make resale difficult.Footnote 20 In 2017 the National Leasehold Campaign (NLC) was founded and its campaigning work built on that of the Leasehold Knowledge Partnership. Also in 2017, the Government consulted on “restricting ground rents on new leases to a ‘peppercorn’” and “how to tackle existing onerous ground rents”.Footnote 21 The first goal, removing ground rents on (most) new leases became law in 2022 with the Leasehold Reform (Ground Rent) Act 2022.
Following calls from campaigning groups such as the Leasehold Knowledge Partnership and the NLC, the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) in 2019 – with seeming reluctance – launched an investigation into the potential mis-selling of leasehold homes and the potential use of unfair terms.Footnote 22 The early CMA focus was on doublers as “they posed the most significant problems for consumers” and were seen as “egregious”. In June 2019, the CMA secured voluntary pledges from more than 60 freeholders and developers to replace clauses that double more frequently than every 20 years with clauses that link escalation to RPI.Footnote 23 The 2020 report from the CMA investigation found evidence of mis-selling by developers as well as concern about the use of escalating ground rent terms.Footnote 24 This also, for the first time, expressed concern about RPI linked increases as well as doublers. As the CMA considered that the mis-selling and ground rent terms could break consumer protection law,Footnote 25 it used its powers under the Enterprise Act 2002 to secure undertakings from several large developers to remove ground rent clauses that double more frequently than every 20 years.Footnote 26 Some undertakings also include a commitment to refund payments received. Similar undertakings have been obtained from 26 landlords who purchased from these developers, with the original developer making a financial contribution to the landlord for the cost of removing these leasehold clauses. Although the doublers were considered more egregious, RPI rises since then mean that indexed clauses may now be worse than 20 year doublers.Footnote 27
A further government consultation, specifically on ground rents, was launched in December 2023. This outlined five options for reform: from capping ground rents at a peppercorn, through to freezing ground rent at current levels. The impact assessment estimated that a reduction to peppercorn would mean over £5 billion in lost ground rent in the first 10 years and more than a £27 billion devaluation in asset value.Footnote 28 Unsurprisingly, investors have lobbied hard and claimed that this would be unfair and a breach of their human rights. Of course, capping should not be a surprise to them; at least since 2016 investors should have been aware that action was likely. Any investments purchased since then were a risk.
The Government’s claim in the consultation that ground rent is “something for nothing”Footnote 29 is supported by the CMA’s response. It states that they found no convincing justification for ground rent and that they had seen no persuasive evidence that it is commercially necessary or that consumers receive anything in return.Footnote 30 Nor was there evidence to support claims that the premium payable was significantly reduced to reflect ground rent.Footnote 31 The government response to the ground rent consultation was not published and the talk of a £250 cap (coupled with a phasing out to peppercorn) was no more than a rumour.
Before discussing the consumer protection legislation, the significance of a £250 cap should be explained. If the ground rent exceeds £250 per year (or £1,000 per year in Greater London), a leaseholder living in the property as his principal home will be an assured tenant within the Housing Act 1988. This means that the lease can be ended by court order on the mandatory grounds in Part 1 of Schedule 2 to the 1988 Act, including Ground 8 which applies if two months’ rent is unpaid. Unlike forfeiture, there is no possibility of relief or of the court ordering sale in preference and it is not possible to argue that the long leasehold interest persists even if the assured tenancy is ended.Footnote 32 The outcome will be an unjust windfall for the landlord.Footnote 33 In practice, the lease is unlikely to be lost if there is an outstanding mortgage as the lender will step in, but the “Housing Act trap” is anecdotally known to cause problems. Legislation is now proposed that will remove this trap by excluding leases of seven years or more from the assured tenancy system.Footnote 34
As well as noting concerns about the financial impact of escalating ground rents the CMA found that many clauses were “obscure and hard to understand”. In addition, there were “very serious allegations of mis-selling”, which included a failure to disclose escalating ground rent provisions to purchasers and a failure to explain the Housing Act trap. This mix of procedural and substantive concerns is important in relation to the legislation concerned with unfair terms, discussed next.
III. Ground Rent Clauses as Unfair Terms
Section 62 of the CRA 2015 applies to leases entered into on or after 1 October 2015 between a “trader” (which would include landlords running a business) and a consumer.Footnote 35 Subsection (1) states: “An unfair term of a consumer contract is not binding on the consumer.”Footnote 36 Similar provisions, the Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Regulations 1999, apply to leases entered between 1 October 1999 and 1 October 2015.Footnote 37
Although there is no doubt that Part 2 of the CRA 2015 applies to long leases,Footnote 38 the wording is ill suited to them. It is crucial to remember that its origin is in a European Directive, the Council Directive 93/13/EEC on unfair terms in consumer contracts (UTD), which is intended to offer a high level of consumer protection.Footnote 39 This means that the application of the 2015 Act (and earlier Regulations) must therefore be guided by European law, even post-Brexit: case law before the end of 2020 remains binding, and the UK courts may have regard to later cases where relevant.Footnote 40
A. Are Ground Rent Terms Excluded from Assessment for Fairness?
Under section 64 some contract terms are excluded from the section 62 assessment for fairness. This will be the case if the term meets two conditions. Condition 1 is that the term either (a) “specifies the main subject matter of the contract” or (b) involves “the assessment … of the appropriateness of the price payable under the contract by comparison with the … services supplied under it”.Footnote 41 As a term relating to price may come within either (a) or (b), both need to be considered in the context of ground rent clauses. Condition 2 is that the term is excluded only if it is “transparent and prominent”. Unless both conditions are met the term must be assessed for fairness.
European case law makes clear that, in relation to Condition 1, exclusion should be strictly interpreted given the consumer protection goal of the UTD.Footnote 42 Further, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) has clearly stated that “exclusion cannot apply to a term relating to a mechanism for amending the prices of the services provided to the consumer”.Footnote 43 In relation to escalating ground rent clauses there is, therefore, no doubt that they should be assessed for fairness. Squaring this with the wording in Condition 1(a) and (b) is, however, not entirely straightforward.
1. Condition 1(a) – the term specifies the main subject matter of the contract
The test is whether the term lays down “the essential obligations of the contract and, as such, characterise it”.Footnote 44 As it is for the national court to determine whether a term does this, there is little guidance as to how it would be applied in particular contexts. There are several European cases involving credit agreements, but nothing closely analogous to the English long lease. When lobbying against reform, landlords have pointed to the importance of ground rents to their investment models and how this impacts the leasehold market, but economic significance is not relevant to whether it defines the main subject matter.Footnote 45 Absent authority we are left with the open question: what are the essential obligations of a contract for the sale of a residential lease? The answer suggested is that it involves the grant of a leasehold estate in return for a premium.Footnote 46 Ground rent does not characterise the contract. This is consistent with the view taken by the Office of Fair Trading (OFT) in its investigation of event fees.Footnote 47 The numerous other obligations in leases undertaken by landlords and leaseholders, including the escalating rent provisions, are ancillary.
2. Condition 1(b) – the appropriateness of the price by comparison with the services supplied
Recital 19 in the UTD refers to this as the “quality/price ratio”, but it is surprisingly complex to apply. Does “price” refer to only the capital sum paid or is it the premium plus the initial ground rent (or even the premium plus the initial and escalating ground rents)? In Office of Fair Trading v Abbey National Plc and others the Supreme Court approached “price or remuneration” (a case under the 1999 Regulations) globally and held that terms relating to contingently payable sums (bank charges) were within this and therefore excluded from review.Footnote 48 This global approach suggests that both the “appropriateness” of the premium and the ground rent could be excluded. Unsurprisingly, landlords argue that ground rents are part of the price: “In the absence of a ground rent, the upfront premium sought to be achieved by the developer would be set at a higher level than the upfront premium for an identical property with a ground rent.”Footnote 49 As the CMA found, however, there is no persuasive evidence to support this.Footnote 50
But even if ground rents are treated as part of the “price”, it is still necessary to look at the other wording in 1(b), the idea of comparing the price with a “service”. Here European case law has taken a narrower approach than the Supreme Court in Abbey National. In particular, it was emphasised in Kásler v OTP Jelzálogbank Zrt. that there must be an element of exchange for a particular service (the price for a service), albeit that the nature of the services in exchange may be understood from the contract as a whole.Footnote 51 Thus, in Matei v SC Volksbank România S.A., it was noted that if an alteration in interest rates is not “against any consideration that may have been supplied in exchange” this may mean that it can be assessed for fairness; likewise with the risk charge in Matei where it was suggested “that the lender does not provide any actual service which could constitute consideration for that charge”.Footnote 52 Is there any service in exchange for a ground rent? The Residential Freehold Association claims that ground rent is part of the consideration for the “property”.Footnote 53 Even if this claim is correct (which is not accepted), the “property” exchanged is a leasehold estate and not a service. Although service is not defined in the CRA 2015, the Court of Appeal has held that, even when the landlord is undertaking to insure, it is “unrealistic to describe the arrangement as ‘the supply of services’”.Footnote 54 Of course, services are provided by the landlord more generally, but these are contracted for in exchange for a service charge, not ground rent. The Residential Freehold Association also states that ground rent provides “the benefit of access to a freeholder”.Footnote 55 This again is not a service, nor is it provided in exchange for the ground rent. The reality is, as is well known, that nothing is given in return and there is no element of exchange as required by Kásler. As the CMA reported, “ground rent is simply an income stream”Footnote 56 or, as per the government consultation, “something for nothing”.Footnote 57 Therefore, escalating rent clauses are not excluded from review.
There are further arguments that show that escalating clauses are not excluded. Justification for excluding the “adequacy” (UTD) or “appropriateness” (CRA) of the price is that there is no objective legal scale or criterion that can provide a framework for and guide a review of that balance.Footnote 58 Whether the amount of the price itself is adequate cannot therefore be tested for fairness and is a matter for party autonomy, but price variation clauses are different. Numerous European cases indicate that terms relating to the consideration owed or affecting the actual price payable can be reviewed.Footnote 59 The fact that the law is so clear on this also strengthens the argument that escalating clauses should not be seen as the “main subject matter of the contract” under Condition 1(a).
3. Transparency and prominence
The argument above means that escalating ground rents terms should be assessed for fairness as they do not meet Condition 1(a) or (b). Many are unlikely to meet Condition 2 either: the term will be excluded only if it is transparent and prominent.
Transparency requires the term to be written in plain and intelligible language (section 64(3) of the CRA 2015). Although some escalating clauses are in plain and intelligible language,Footnote 60 many will fail these formal transparency requirements as they are grammatically complex. The CMA says that “lease provisions imposing ground rent and providing for its escalation can be obscure and hard to understand”.Footnote 61 Further, transparency is not only about “formal transparency”, that is whether terms are “formally and grammatically intelligible”, but “substantive transparency” is also required.Footnote 62 For a term to be transparent the “average consumer, who is reasonably well informed and reasonably observant and circumspect, would … be able to assess the potentially significant economic consequences for him”.Footnote 63 Further, it is the seller who has the burden of proving that the information supplied to the consumer enables them to “evaluate the risk of potentially significant adverse economic consequences of contractual terms on his or her financial obligations”.Footnote 64 But the CMA found widespread evidence of mis-selling of leasehold homes, giving examples of purchasers not being told that rents would increase.Footnote 65
For the term to be “prominent”, it must be “brought to the consumer’s attention in such a way that the average consumer would be aware of the term”. Interestingly, since 19 June 2006 the Land Registration Rules 2003 have required leases to contain a standard set of clauses that must appear at the front of leases but, although premium is stated there, the rent is not. The escalating clauses are usually hidden several pages into leases; and often even the initial ground rent is not easy to find.
It may be that many escalating clauses do not meet the requirement to be transparent and prominent, but some will. However, given the earlier argument that Condition 1 is not met, they are in any event subject to an assessment for fairness. The next Subsection (B) explains how fairness is assessed in relation to ground rent clauses.
B. Are Ground Rent Clauses Fair?
Consumer protection in the UTD is based around the concepts of “good faith, balance and transparency”.Footnote 66 According to section 62(4): “A term is unfair if, contrary to the requirement of good faith, it causes a significant imbalance in the parties’ rights and obligations under the contract to the detriment of the consumer.” This incorporates both procedural and substantive concerns,Footnote 67 recognising that the “system of protection introduced by [the Directive] is based on the idea that the consumer is in a weak position vis-à-vis the seller or supplier, as regards both his bargaining power and his level of knowledge”.Footnote 68
The procedural dimension supports consumer protection as it pays attention to whether the trader has dealt fairly and equitably with the consumer, taking account of their legitimate interests.Footnote 69 Further, the concept of transparency – both formal and substantive – is built into the fairness test (as well as being considered at the earlier stage of determining whether a term is excluded from review).Footnote 70 As Sergio Cámara Lapuente explains, the transparency requirement has become a “rule that demands (positive) duties of active information”.Footnote 71 An emphasis is placed on how the trader behaved towards the consumer at the pre-contractual stage given that on the “basis of that information … the consumer decides whether he or she wishes to be bound by the terms”Footnote 72 and the trader should not take advantage of the consumer’s weak bargaining position.Footnote 73 The question must be asked whether the seller “could reasonably assume that the consumer would have agreed to such a term in individual contract negotiations”.Footnote 74 As noted earlier, substantive transparency means that particular attention is paid to whether the consumer comprehends the economic impact of the term; it is unlikely that the average leaseholder (and this author) will understand the economic significance of many escalating clauses.Footnote 75
There has clearly been a widespread failure on the part of developers in relation to transparency demands, especially given how poorly pre-contractual information has been presented and explained to leaseholders. It is now common knowledge that there was a great deal of mis-selling and the CMA received evidence of developers failing to explain the existence and operation of ground rents to purchasers. The sales pitch is pivotal when it comes to consumer choice and decision-making; in other contexts, the courts have taken account of pre-commitment telesales pitches in the assessment of fairness.Footnote 76 Purchasers therefore need to be informed about ground rents, and their economic impact, at the outset of the process: it is too late for purchasers to discover them once they are emotionally committed to the purchase and may well have started incurring expenses. In her evidence to the Leasehold and Freehold Reform Bill Committee, one of the founders of the NLC explained that she had not even been told that the house she was buying was leasehold until late into her commitment journey.Footnote 77 Further, a survey by the NLC carried out in 2019 revealed that leaseholders had experienced poor conveyancing services.Footnote 78 Empirical research into the sale and use of leasehold in Wales by Helen Carr and others reinforces the findings of the CMA in relation to misleading sales practices and paints a picture of a dysfunctional market “within which consumer confidence has been utterly undermined”, noting that this complicates the use of “traditional consumer mechanisms such as information requirements or unfair terms regulation”.Footnote 79
Nor will a term be treated as fair simply because the leaseholder has been advised by their own solicitor.Footnote 80 In Evans v Cherry Tree Finance Ltd. a mortgage term was held to be unfair even though the consumer had been advised by a solicitor.Footnote 81 Questions have also been raised about the independence of some conveyancers acting for purchasers given their close relationships with developers.Footnote 82
As transparency is highly relevant, the lack of transparency is a strong indication of unfairness,Footnote 83 but it is only one of the elements.Footnote 84 The other core component is a “significant imbalance”. This will be found if the term tilts an obligation significantly in favour of the supplier by imposing a disadvantageous burden on the consumer.Footnote 85 Where the term relates to a payment the substantive component is concerned with proportionality between the price and the service. So, there may be a significant imbalance if a fee does not correspond to services provided and costs incurred,Footnote 86 or the payment is disproportionate.Footnote 87 The fact that ground rents are “something for nothing” must therefore mean that the term causes significant imbalance. Further, although the case law interweaves transparency and significant imbalance, there is some support for saying that significant imbalance alone may be sufficient to find a term unfair. Thus, in Sebestyén v Zsolt Csaba Kővári and Others, the ECJ said that: “even assuming that the general information the consumer receives before concluding a contract satisfies the requirement under Article 5 that it be plain and intelligible, that fact alone cannot rule out the unfairness of a clause such as that at issue in the main proceedings.”Footnote 88
There have been particular concerns about price variation clauses and several European cases state that to be fair the term must set out the reason for, and the method of, the variation, as well as giving the consumer a right to terminate the contract.Footnote 89 They are not, however, analogous to escalating rent clauses. For one thing, it is hard to envisage other contracts with anything approaching the same duration. Even in mortgage cases the duration will be much less; as, for example, in Matei where there were loan agreements of five and 25 years. Additionally, the alterations provisions operate differently. For example, in the leading case of Nemzeti Fogyasztóvédelmi Hatóság v Invitel Távközlési Zrt. the term provided that a phone network operator could charge additional fees for subscribers who pay by money order, without specifying how they would be calculated. In contrast, escalating rent clauses do explain how the reviewed rents are calculated (albeit without an explanation of why the rent is being reviewed and the method is seldom in clear language). But this may not be sufficient to satisfy the concerns in the Invitel line of cases. Both the CRA 2015 and the UTD contain an annex with a list of terms that may be regarded as unfair. Although the annex lists as potentially unfair a term that permits a trader to increase the price without giving the consumer the right to cancel if the final price is too high, this does not apply to a “price-indexation clause … if the method by which the prices vary is explicitly described”.Footnote 90 Of course, doubling rent clauses are not indexed, but (provided there is formal transparency) the method is clear. With RPI linked clauses, the requirement for an “explicit description” of how indexation works is demanding. In Gómez del Moral Guasch v Bankia S.A., it was said that the need for transparency requires that the average consumer can understand the methods used in indexing, including that the information that goes into the calculation and the provision of data relating to past fluctuations.Footnote 91 The CMA update report expresses concern about RPI clauses: homeowners may well not understand how an RPI increase is calculated (a problem that may be compounded by the drafting), quantum is uncertain and it is unclear why RPI is a suitable index as ground rents do not have “much if anything to do with the value of property or land”.Footnote 92
It is also evident that many (perhaps most) conveyancers did not themselves understand the economic significance of escalating clauses until they received recent attention. In Arrassey Properties Ltd. v Nelsons Solicitors, a negligence claim was brought against solicitors acting for a leasehold purchase in 2006.Footnote 93 The relevant provisions provided for 10-year reviews to the greater of either a 150 per cent increase or RPI linked increase. The Law Society’s Conveyancing Handbook at that time simply said: “In long residential leases, fixed increment reviews every 25 to 30 years are more usual” and there was no requirement to explain the exponential effect of the clauses or advice on the risks over time.Footnote 94 The solicitor said that he did not consider the provision to be unusual and was held not to be negligent because (then) a “reasonably prudent solicitor” was not required to do more. One also suspects the solicitor had little comprehension of the economic impact of the clause.
The practices adopted by developers selling modern leases will often fail the transparency requirements; in itself this raises a strong indication of unfairness. But the fact that nothing is given in return for the ground rent means that it is disproportionate, causing a significant imbalance. Together this means that escalating rent clauses are likely to be unfair and not binding on consumers.
The application of the CRA 2015 to leases does, however, require consideration of two further issues: the assignment issue and the temporal dimension, which are discussed next.
C. Particular Challenges with Leases: Assignment and Length
Modern long leases are granted for decades or centuries which means that there will be multiple sales during the term. To ensure that consumer protection is effective, it has been held that there is no limitation period that applies to challenging the fairness of a contractual term.Footnote 95 However, both the assignment issue and the temporal dimension give rise to difficult legal issues when applying the CRA 2015. In outline, the challenges are:
-
(1) Although there is a contract between the original parties, there is no contractual relationship between an assignee and the other party to the lease. Does the CRA 2015 therefore cease to apply?
-
(2) Under section 62(5) whether a term is fair is to be determined by “reference to all the circumstances existing when the term was agreed”. Given the effluxion of time this may be difficult to recall or evidence, even for the original parties to the lease. When the lease has been assigned, it is unlikely that the successor leaseholder will have information about the earlier bargaining process (which goes to good faith and transparency). What does this mean for leaseholder protection?
For ease these questions are discussed under separate headings, but the issues are interlinked.
1. The assignment issue
In its investigation of event fees the Law Commission recognised the difficulties, remarking that the lease ceases to be a contract on assignment. This lies behind the plan for the Thirteenth Programme of Law Reform to consider: “whether, each time a lease is assigned, this should be seen as creating a new contract between the landlord and leaseholder for the purposes of unfair terms law.”Footnote 96 Pending this, which would require legislative action, their tentative argument was that a European understanding of contract should be adopted and “under European principles, a lease would be regarded as constituting a contractual relationship between the landlord and any subsequent tenants” as the assignee may “step into the contractual relationship”.Footnote 97 But even without this approach, it can be argued that the CRA 2015 continues to be relevant post-assignment. Prior to the Law Commission’s work, the OFT had itself investigated retirement home transfer fees and accepted (without detailed explanation) that the consumer protection legislation applies post-assignment where the assignee is a consumer.Footnote 98
It is strange to say, as the Law Commission does, that the contract ceases to exist. Admittedly the status post-assignment is peculiar but there is nothing to suggest that the original contract does not continue between the original parties. Indeed, the major reform to privity in the Landlord and Tenant (Covenants) Act 1995 was only necessary because the original lease parties continued to be contractually liable post-assignment. Hence the 1995 Act introduced changes that on assignment release the original tenant from liability on the covenants and provide a route for the original landlord to be released.Footnote 99 Further, I argue that it is this legislation that explains why the CRA 2015 continues to have teeth post-assignment. Although the successor leaseholder is not a contracting party, section 3(1) of the 1995 Act provides that the assignee is bound by the leasehold covenants. However, by section 3(2) this does not apply to tenant covenants that “immediately before the assignment … did not bind the assignor”. Conveniently, this mirrors the wording in section 62 which provides that an unfair term is not “binding” on a consumer. This means that, if the original leaseholder was not bound by an unfair ground rent term, nor will the assignee be, and this does not depend on the status of the assignee.
Case law, commentary and regulatory action all add support to the CRA 2015 applying post-assignment. In Roundlistic Ltd. v Jones and another the Court of Appeal assessed a leasehold term for fairness under the 1999 Regulations even though the lease had been assigned.Footnote 100 Admittedly, the authority of this case may be weakened because there does not appear to have been any discussion of the assignment issue. The leading contract text, Chitty on Contracts, also argues that an assignee leaseholder is protected by section 62 if the original leaseholder was.Footnote 101 In support of the argument from principle, Chitty on Contracts also relies on Ryanair DAC v Delay Fix which illustrates that, if a clause in a contract between a (consumer) passenger and an airline is unfair, the airline cannot enforce it against a collection agency which is the successor to the consumer’s rights and obligations.Footnote 102
The undertakings secured by the CMA not to enforce clauses doubling more frequently than every 20 years benefit assignees as well as original leaseholders, irrespective of whether the original leaseholder was a consumer (unlike the argument above based on the 1995 Act). At least one freeholder has, however, limited its undertaking to repay escalated rents to leaseholders who are not subletting or who own fewer than three residential properties for letting (referred to as Category One Leaseholders).Footnote 103 This narrowing of the scope of the undertaking presumably reflects negotiations between that landlord and the CMA that sought to distinguish between consumer and non-consumer leaseholders. And, akin to my 1995 Act argument above, the distinction flows through to successor leaseholders: they benefit only if they took the assignment from a Category One Leaseholder.
These various arguments all point to an assignee from an original consumer leaseholder being protected by the CRA 2015. With the exception of the Law Commission’s argument about the adoption of the Euro-model of contracting, however, it would seem that an assignee consumer does not benefit if the original leaseholder was not a consumer but, for example, an investor. If correct, this appears to be a serious lacuna in the consumer protection.
2. The temporal dimension
The fairness test requires consideration of the circumstances at the time the term was agreed (section 62(5)), but the longevity of leases means that this may be difficult in practice. The evidential problems that may arise when terms are challenged many years after the contract was entered, and particularly post-assignment, do not appear to have been addressed in case law.Footnote 104 At face value, section 62(5) may therefore be problematic if there are no records of what happened when the lease was granted.
However, it is argued here that to adopt a strict approach would be inconsistent with the high level of consumer protection or the principle of effet utile (effectiveness) used by the ECJ to give effective protection to individual rights in the interpretation of directives.Footnote 105 The purpose of requiring consideration of circumstances at the time of agreement is, presumably, to discover whether the consumer has been dealt with fairly and equitably, and in particular whether the seller can prove that “its pre-contractual and contractual obligations, relating in particular to the requirement of transparency” have been fulfilled.Footnote 106 If there are no records this may disadvantage the seller, but the overall aim is to promote consumer protection. Even if the reversion has been assigned, this again should make no difference: the status of the rent clauses as binding/non-binding is set at the time of contracting.
In the absence of specific information, it is suggested that regard should be had to the standardised practices that were used for the sale of modern long leases. This is what happens in collective actions where the ECJ has regard, in relation to the types of contract concerned in the collective action, to standard contractual and pre-contractual practices, drafting, the position of terms within a contract and advertising that was employed.Footnote 107 Of course it is now common knowledge that developers had poor practices: the CMA repeatedly received “very serious allegations” of mis-selling “about the conduct of developers and their sales staff in the process leading to the reservation agreement”.Footnote 108
D. Summary of Section III
Several judgment calls have to be made when applying section 62 to ground rent clauses but there are strong reasons for arguing that they are not excluded from an assessment for fairness. They don’t specify the main subject matter, nor is a service given in return. Many will also not be transparent or prominent. This means that escalating clauses should be assessed for fairness. Given the widespread mis-selling of modern long leases, landlords may struggle to prove that there was sufficient pre-contractual information to demonstrate that the leaseholder was dealt with fairly and equitably. There will also be a significant imbalance as there is no proportionality between a price and a service: ground rents, as “something for nothing”, are disproportionate. Escalating clauses, particularly RPI clauses, may also fail to meet the concerns of substantive transparency as the average leaseholder will not understand the economic impact. Some residential leases will be outside the scope of the CRA 2015 if the original leaseholder was not a consumer, and temporal distance from the date of contracting may also add complications, but for the majority the requirement to pay an escalating rent will not be enforceable.
Although not the focus of this article, the argument may extend even to initial ground rents. Analysis of the CRA 2015 points towards all non-nominal ground rent clauses being potentially unfair. It may be that the transparency test will draw some lines between initial and escalating rents: the wording will be more straightforward to comprehend and sales agents may be more likely to mention an initial ground rent than the escalating provisions, but this is speculative and anecdotal evidence suggests that this was often not the case. The significant imbalance does, however, appear problematic for both: the absence of any service in return for the payment applies equally to escalating and initial rents.
Apart from section 62, there is an alternative argument that may strike down rent clauses. This is discussed next.
IV. Derogation from Grant, and Repugnancy
The Housing Act trap (discussed above) provides alternative grounds for claiming that ground rent provisions are unenforceable if the rent is above the low-rent threshold, either initially or through the implementation of escalating rent clauses. The arguments are based on the separate, but closely related, concepts of derogation from grant (DFG),Footnote 109 and repugnancy. The kernel of the argument in both cases draws on the idea that, as the landlord has sold a fixed long-term lease which can only be ended by mutual consent or in accordance with the lease (forfeiture), it is inconsistent to include provisions that convert the long lease into an assured tenancy where the statutory grounds of possession can be used rather than forfeiture.Footnote 110
The covenant not to derogate from grant is based on the “bedrock of basic fair dealing”Footnote 111 or “rule of common honesty”Footnote 112 that “a grantor having given a thing with one hand is not to take away the means of enjoying it with the other”.Footnote 113
Repugnancy is based on a principle of construction by which courts may strike down contractual terms where one term “contradict[s] another term or [is] in conflict with it, such that effect cannot fairly be given to both clauses” or they “cannot sensibly be read together”.Footnote 114 This principle also applies where words and clauses “are inconsistent with what one assumes to be the main purpose of the contract”.Footnote 115
The first step with both is to ask what the “main purpose” of the contract is (repugnancy)Footnote 116 or the “irreducible minimum implicit in the grant” (DFG).Footnote 117 It will be clear that a long lease is intended; this is the main purpose and core of the contract.
An initial rent that invokes the Housing Act trap is likely to lead to repugnancy as the rent provisions are inconsistent with “the interest created by the contract”,Footnote 118 a long lease. The doctrine of DFG appears, however, only to address situations in which there is a post-grant act or omission.Footnote 119 Whether a rent review that triggers the Housing Act trap would involve derogation is unclear. The puzzle turns on whether the grant is the entire bundle of rights and obligations in the lease, in which case there is no derogation as the landlord’s exercise of the review clause is in accordance with the terms of the lease,Footnote 120 or whether the grant is the “minimum irreducible core” (possession for the long fixed term, as against the whole bundle of rights) so that a rent increase converting the long lease into an assured tenancy would be a derogation. Again, the idea of repugnancy may be a better fit as the operation of the review clause is inconsistent with the main purpose of the contract.
The Housing Act trap is likely to be removed when the Renters’ Rights Bill receives Royal Assent.Footnote 121 But if repugnancy and DFG turn on the situation at the outset of the contract, it is hard to see that legislative reform changes this argument.
V. Further Practical Implications
A. Refund of Escalated Rent Payments
The foregoing argument has significant implications where leaseholders have made payments under escalating clauses which are unfair. European case law is clear that where a term is found to be unfair it “must be regarded, in principle, as never having existed, so that it cannot have any effect on the consumer”.Footnote 122 It follows from this that, subject to limitation periods, the consumer should be refunded:
[a finding of unfairness] must, in principle, have the consequence of restoring the consumer to the legal and factual situation that he would have been in if that term had not existed. It follows that the obligation for the national court to exclude an unfair contract term imposing the payment of amounts that prove not to be due entails, in principle, a corresponding restitutory [sic] effect in respect of those same amounts.Footnote 123
The question is whether this outcome can be achieved applying the current English law in relation to unjust enrichment.
Although the correct approach to cases of payment not due is contested in the literature, it is clear that as matter of principle leaseholders who have paid ground rent under a term held to be unfair should be able to recover. The first argument a consumer could rely on to obtain restitution is that the payment was mistaken. The second approach relies on the absence of basis for the payment or lack of entitlement for the payment. An alternative ground would be to realise the policy behind the CRA 2015.
Under the first approach, the consumer would argue that the rent payment was made in the mistaken belief that it was contractually due under the lease. As statute says the contractual term explaining the payment is not binding, the consumer acted on a mistaken belief and the landlord’s receiptFootnote 124 of the payment is therefore unjust. This approach has previously been applied for payments made under an unfair term.Footnote 125 There is a potential complication which is that the consumer may have doubts about the law, perhaps wondering if the clause was unfair. However, slight doubts are not inconsistent with mistake. Lord Hoffmann said that the real question is whether the payer “took the risk that he might be wrong”.Footnote 126 In any event, given that the only public conversation about these provisions is the indirect references in the CMA work, consumers will not have had grounds to doubt the payability of escalating ground rents. Indeed, the focus on the need for legislative solutions suggests the very opposite.
Under the second approach, the consumer would argue that, because the clause that is unfair is not binding, there is no basis for, or entitlement to, the payment. This civilian approach has sometimes been adopted by English courts, most notably per Hobhouse J. in Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale v Islington London Borough Council,Footnote 127 where he held that: “The right to restitution arises from the fact that the payment made by the plaintiff to the defendant was made under a purported contract which, unknown to the plaintiff and the defendant, was ultra vires the defendant and wholly void.”Footnote 128 Although this approach has not found favour with English courts,Footnote 129 a consumer could succeed if such an approach were to be adopted. Following section 62(1), the effect of a finding of unfairness is that the term is not binding on the consumer. As Gutiérrez Naranjo and Others says, this means that for the consumer it must be as if the “unfair term had not existed”Footnote 130 (as opposed to merely being unenforceable). Payments made by consumers when no obligation to pay ground rent ever existed would thus be recoverable.
An alternative to relying on mistake of law as an unjust factor is to say that restitution here would be based on policy-motivated unjust enrichment. Andrew Burrows gives a list of unjust factors within the umbrella of “policy-motivated restitution” but none capture this particular context.Footnote 131 However, as the category of unjust factors is not closed,Footnote 132 the argument could be made that the policy of the CRA 2015 would be frustrated if payments made under non-binding consumer terms could not be recovered.Footnote 133
The CMA appear to have proceeded on the basis that restitution should, indeed, follow if the terms are unfair under consumer protection legislation. Some of the undertakings secured include agreements from current landlords to repay leaseholders (and former leaseholders) the difference between the initial ground rent and rents paid to them under a doubling ground rent clause.Footnote 134
As reversionary interests change hands, it may be that rent has been paid not only to the current landlord (for recent payments) but also former landlords. In restitution the claim must be against the person “enriched” by the payment. The CMA appears, however, to take a different point of view. Its response to the government consultation argued that the original developer (presumably as original landlord) should “compensate freeholders … given that developers had created and then sold freeholds with the benefit of unlawful terms”.Footnote 135 Further it suggested that, if the Government considers that less than 20-year doubling clauses are egregious, it could legislate to require repayment and also that the burden of this “reimbursement could be shared between those who have received the ground rent and those who have profited from the sale of freeholds”.Footnote 136 What this means is that even if, for example, doubling rents have been paid only to a later landlord, the original developer landlord should bear some financial responsibility for the repayment to leaseholders. This approach of “following the money” into capital receipts from sale is a policy argument that goes beyond what is required under the law of unjust enrichment.
There is a further issue to consider: limitation periods. The reasons for limitation periods are policy based; a defendant should not have the threat of being sued hanging over them forever and claimants should have an incentive to bring claims as soon as possible, but limitation periods must not “restrict or reduce the access left to the individual in such a way or to such an extent that the very essence of the right is impaired”.Footnote 137 In Naranjo it was noted, in the context of holding that restitutionary remedies should be provided where terms are unfair, that it is compatible with EU law to lay down reasonable time limits for bringing legal proceedings.Footnote 138
In English law, claims in unjust enrichment must be brought within six years,Footnote 139 but when does the time start to run? The usual position is that this is when the payment is made (the landlord is enriched). Where, however, the claim is based on a mistake, time does not start to run until the mistake is discovered or could with reasonable diligence be discovered,Footnote 140 and this has been held to apply to mistakes of law as well as to mistakes of fact.Footnote 141 As Lord Hoffmann notes, this “tilt[s] the balance … against the public interest in the security of transactions”Footnote 142 but in our context it opens the possibility of restitutionary claims many years after the rent payment has been made. The mistake will be “reasonably discoverable” when they could “with reasonable diligence discover [their] mistake in the sense of recognising that a worthwhile claim arises”, which is likely to be when they feel ready to take advice and begin the process of making a claim.Footnote 143 Identifying whether the discoverability threshold has been passed will, as the minority feared in Test Claimants, be evidentially difficult in practice.Footnote 144 As consumers are not legal experts, this may well not be until the potential for claim becomes very well known in the public sphere,Footnote 145 turning on the state of “inherently vague and intangible” professional opinion over a very long period.Footnote 146
B. Undermining Human Rights ConcernsFootnote 147
If escalating rents are not binding on consumers, this weakens the claims of lobbyists using human rights concerns to argue against legislative reform. Unsurprisingly, given the huge economic impact of reform, landlords (particularly institutional landlords with large ground rent portfolios) have claimed that intervention would be incompatible with the right to peaceful enjoyment of possessions in Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 to the European Convention on Human Rights (A1P1).
A1P1 is given effect in the UK through the Human Rights Act 1988 and sets out that natural or legal persons are entitled to the peaceful enjoyment of possessions. As the Supreme Court noted in Salvesen v Riddell, “landlords, however unpopular, are as much entitled to the protection of the Convention rights as anyone else”.Footnote 148
The application of A1P1 involves several stages.
First, is there a possession? Both the landlord’s reversion and an (enforceable) right to future income (rent) are, as objects of economic value,Footnote 149 possessions.Footnote 150
Next, has there been an interference with that possession (and if so, how)? If the arguments above about the CRA 2015 are correct, the extent of the interference will be limited where ground rent clauses are unfair. Although there will still be bite in relation to the initial ground rents (unless, under the argument floated in Section III(D), they may also be found unfair), there is only an illusory interference if escalating clauses are capped and the terms were unfair and never binding in the first place.
It is also necessary to ask if any interference is lawful and in the public interest. The wide margin of appreciation, often referred to as deference or weight in the domestic context, means that any challenge to the lawfulness or public interest of any interference with existing ground rents would have only limited prospects of success.
A key question in relation to A1P1 challenges will be whether the interference is proportionate. The question of incompatibility will depend both on the particular legislative measure (which could take the radical form of reducing ground rents to a peppercorn or introducing some form of capping)Footnote 151 and its application to the specific facts of any challenge.Footnote 152 Compatibility with A1P1 is nuanced and complex. Especially important is whether the intervention achieves a “fair balance” between the rights of the landlord and the interests of the community. Relevant to this, but not determinative, will be the amount that the cap is set at (a peppercorn cap is very different to one set at current rent levels) and whether there is any form of compensation to landlords. Even in the absence of compensation (as is likely), and notwithstanding the previous Government’s impact assessment showing every possible cap producing an economic impact in the billions, capping can still be compatible with human rights. In The Karibu Foundation v Norway, the European Court of Human Rights found Norwegian legislation that capped rents under lease extensions, without the payment of compensation, compatible with A1P1.Footnote 153 This finding was reached after a careful balancing of the competing interests, consideration of the specific factual context and the position of the parties; and noting the careful legislative background to the measures.
The most important question in a challenge will be whether the interference is proportionate. But the important contribution of this article is that the extent of the interference is significantly reduced if any of the ground rent terms are unfair under consumer protection legislation. This undermines, perhaps fatally, any human rights challenge.
VI. Conclusion
The issues covered in this article cross rocky and uncertain terrain.
Applying section 62 to ground rent clauses is not straightforward and is largely uncharted. Long residential leases are conceptually hybrid, “part contract, part property”,Footnote 154 and as they last for decades or centuries they will change hands on many occasions. This makes for difficult legal questions. What is the main subject matter of the contract? Is the ground rent in return for any “service”? Do only the most egregious ground rent clauses cause “significant imbalance”? There is no contractual relationship between the assignees to the lease and yet the contractual terms continue to bind them: does the CRA 2015 still apply? What if the current leaseholder is not a consumer but the original leaseholder was? How does the transparency test apply if the current leaseholder has no information about the bargaining process at the time of contracting? Answering these questions must be approached bearing in mind the high level of consumer protection underpinning the legislation and that consumers are in a position of weakness vis-à-vis sellers or suppliers, as regards both their bargaining power and their level of knowledge. The answers to these questions given in this article will, undoubtedly, be contested.
A summary of the conclusions reached is as follows. Escalating ground rent clauses are not exempted from the fairness assessment: the main subject matter is the sale of an estate in land in return for a premium, the “appropriateness of the price” exclusion does not apply as there is no service in exchange for the ground rent and European case law makes clear that price variation clauses are subject to review. Evaluating fairness requires consideration of both transparency, formal and substantive, and significant imbalance. Many clauses will fail the transparency test: consumers will not understand the economic significance of escalating clauses and the mis-selling of modern long leases means that many consumers were not made aware of ground rent provisions. As nothing is given in return for ground rent there will always be significant imbalance. The consequence is that escalating ground rent clauses are not binding on consumer leaseholders. This is also true for future leaseholders as they are bound only by terms that were binding on the assignor. In so far as the passage of time makes proof of the circumstances at the time of contracting difficult, this should not impact the application of the tests: the goal is to protect the consumer and it is for the trader to prove that the requirements of transparency were met and, in line with how this is dealt with in collective actions, the court should also be able to look at the standardised selling practices. For those leases within the Housing Act trap there are additional grounds for maintaining that high ground rent provisions are not enforceable through the doctrines of non-DFG and repugnancy.
This article shows that escalating ground rents may be found unfair and therefore not binding on consumer leaseholders and their assignees. The implications are clear. Where terms are found unfair, leaseholders do not have to pay and can recover past payments through restitution. This will have significant economic impact on institutional landlords. Turning these arguments into practical legal remedies for leaseholders would probably require some form of collective action with a willing litigation funderFootnote 155 as individual leaseholders may be unlikely to litigate. Legislative solutions may appear more attractive but it is unclear how strong an appetite the Labour Government has for reducing ground rents to a peppercorn as against imposing a cap and there has been no hint that landlords would be required to refund previously paid onerous rents to leaseholders. The arguments here could, however, have an immediate impact on valuation in enfranchisement claims. In addition, the wind is taken out of the A1P1 sails that have been raised by lobbyists arguing against reform given that the most egregious rent provisions – and therefore the most economically significant – are unenforceable.