Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T18:05:40.594Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Designing profitable joint product–service channels: case study on tablet and eBook markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 August 2019

Namwoo Kang*
Affiliation:
Department of Mechanical Systems Engineering, Sookmyung Women’s University, 100 Cheongpa-ro 47-gil, Yongsan-gu, Seoul, 04310, Republic of Korea
Fred M. Feinberg
Affiliation:
Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, 701 Tappan Street, Ann Arbor, MI, 48109, USA
Panos Y. Papalambros
Affiliation:
Department of Mechanical Engineering, University of Michigan, 2350 Hayward Street, Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA
*
Email address for correspondence: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Consumers’ choice of services and the product platforms that deliver them, such as apps and mobile devices, or eBooks and eReaders, are becoming inextricably interrelated. Market viability demands that product–service combinations be compatible across multiple producers and service channels, and that the producers’ profitability must include both service and product design. Some services may be delivered contractually or physically, through a wider range of products than others. Thus, optimization of producers’ contingent products, services, and channel decisions becomes a combined decision problem. This article examines three common product–service design scenarios: exclusive, non-exclusive asymmetric, and non-exclusive symmetric. An enterprise-wide decision framework has been proposed to optimize integrated services and products for each scenario. Optimization results provide guidelines for strategies that are mutually profitable for partner–competitor firms. The article examines an example of an eBook service and tablet, with market-level information from four firms (Amazon, Apple, Barnes & Noble, and Google) and conjoint-based product–service choice data to illustrate the proposed framework using a scalable sequential optimization algorithm. The results suggest that firms in market equilibrium can markedly differ in the services they seek to provide via other firms’ products and demonstrate the interrelationship among marketing, services, and product design.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
Distributed as Open Access under a CC-BY 4.0 license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/)
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2019

1 Introduction

The integration of services and products enhances both the profitability and sustainability of innovating firms. An oft-cited example concerns the interrelation of digital services delivered via tablets, e.g., from the App Store in an iPad, or through Amazon in a Kindle. The importance of product–service (PS) integration extends well beyond handheld devices (Brady, Davies & Hobday Reference Brady, Davies and Hobday2006; Hudson, Fudge & Rae Reference Hudson, Fudge and Rae2011), with early definitions establishing ‘a marketable set of products and services capable of jointly fulfilling a user’s need’ (Mont Reference Mont2002) to achieve greater economic value than conventional product-oriented businesses (Baines et al. Reference Baines, Lightfoot, Peppard, Johnson, Tiwari, Shehab and Swink2009; Roy & Baxter Reference Roy and Baxter2009). Research on these so-called Product–Service Systems (PSS) has been conducted on the full spectrum of the product/service life cycle, from planning to delivery (Sakao & Lindahl Reference Sakao and Lindahl2009). While jointly designing services, products, and their channels, the role of services may be undervalued: ‘Some of the companies that have made tablets and put them on the market have not been successful, because they made tablets. They did not make services.’ (Jeff Bezos quoted in Hudson et al. (Reference Hudson, Fudge and Rae2011)).

The present article reports research focused on the tablet and eBook markets. The definitions of key terms used are as follows: (1) producers are firms developing and providing both tablets and eBooks, such as Amazon, Barnes & Noble (B&N), Apple, and Google; (2) competitors indicate other producers in the market other than the focal firm; (3) products are tablets such as Kindle, Nook, iPad, and Nexus, which are devices for using services; (4) services indicate online content such as eBooks; (5) service platforms are online markets to buy eBooks, such as Amazon, B&N, iBooks, and Google Play; note that Amazon and B&N use the same name in the producer and service platforms; and (6) product–service channels or simply channels indicate the connections between tablets and eBooks; e.g., if a channel connects Kindle with iBooks, Kindle users can buy eBooks from iBooks.

Product–Service (PS) channels are generally used to transfer, amplify, and control service contests, and they can be explained in various ways and perspectives depending on the context (Sakao & Shimomura Reference Sakao and Shimomura2007). While PS channels can represent compatibility between services and products from the customer’s perspective, they can also represent the cooperation between a competitor’s service and product from the producer’s perspective. Moreover, competitors’ services can complement the firm’s products but are substitutes for the firm’s own services. Furthermore, while competitors’ products are substitutes for the firm’s product, they can complement the firm’s own services. PS channels can also interact with the supply chains, where the product is part of a supply chain and services are provided by the firm but also by its competitors.

In our research, PS channels differ substantially from conventional distribution channels across at least four dimensions. First, rather than being delivered via an intermediary retailer, PS channel services are delivered through products. Second, in a PS channel, producers can be both product and service suppliers; service platforms (e.g., app stores) can include a wide array of external service suppliers (e.g., app developers). Third, rather than focusing on a single customer choice, PS channels are designed around customers making multiple choices sequentially: a typical customer first chooses a product, and then chooses services through that product for the period of product ownership; this differs from a complementary goods market, where a retailer sells a bundle of services and products to a customer just once. Fourth, while the PS channel structure is itself a design decision (hence amenable to optimization), the analyses of traditional channels typically assume a predetermined fixed structure.

To operate and compete successfully in an integrated PS market, producers must examine profitability jointly, that is, with both services and product design(s) serving as their delivery vehicles. Research in profit-maximizing product design methodology has long been a staple of academic marketing, especially via the conjoint approach (Green & Krieger Reference Green and Krieger1991; Moore, Louviere & Verma Reference Moore, Louviere and Verma1999), with ancillary applications to optimal service design (Pullman & Moore Reference Pullman and Moore1999; Easton & Pullman Reference Easton and Pullman2001). Research in the operations management and engineering design fields have extended this approach to multidisciplinary design comprising engineering, manufacturing, and policy (Michalek, Feinberg & Papalambros Reference Michalek, Feinberg and Papalambros2005; Lewis, Chen & Schmidt Reference Lewis, Chen and Schmidt2006; Frischknecht, Whitefoot & Papalambros Reference Frischknecht, Whitefoot and Papalambros2010; Kang Reference Kang2014). Much of the previous research in profit-maximizing design has focused on either the service or the product aspect in isolation. However, some studies have addressed service and product design jointly, mainly in after sales and related services such as scheduled maintenance and repair (Cohen & Whang Reference Cohen and Whang1997), or wait time and reliability in delivery (Verma et al. Reference Verma, Thompson, Moore and Louviere2001). Channels analyzed in prior literature where consumers consider only whether add-on services may be useful after product purchase differ from current market integration conditions, where the choice of services is an integral part of product choice. In Barczak, Griffin & Kahn’s (Reference Barczak, Griffin and Kahn2009) review of drivers of success in new product development, only about one tenth of the firms were primarily service-oriented, while one third were a mixture of services and products. The latter have a complex array of decisions to make regarding the attributes of their products, what services to offer, whether to license those services to other firms or not, and whether to allow other firms’ services on their own devices. The present paper offers a way to organize, formalize, and optimize these interlinked decisions.

Producers must have foresight about service offerings, since they drive primary consumer product choice and affect a firm’s overall profitability. Two issues need to be focused on: (i) compatibility between services and products from the customer’s perspective, and (ii) strategic cooperation among competitors’ services and products. Hence, a broad class of PS markets, characterized by several core assumptions are modeled and analyzed:

  1. (1) Producers supply both services and associated products;

  2. (2) Customers can purchase other producers’ services, if available;

  3. (3) Customers desire multiple services, and purchase a particular product that enables such multiple access (i.e., purchases through a service platform); and

  4. (4) Channel decisions among competitors require contractual agreements.

Despite the variety of decisions across this market set-up, all the assumptions can be addressed via formal optimization with respect to three interrelated quantities: product prices and attributes, service prices and attributes, and the nature of the PS channel itself. The difficulty in directly optimizing the entire system using common tools arises from the PS channel structure being a shared decision variable across competitors.

The aim here is to present an enterprise-driven decision-making framework to design products, services, and especially PS channels at the same time, with application to the tablet–eBook market. The study shows how to leverage game theory techniques to establish and determine market equilibria for various common market structures, and then illustrates the (equilibrium) solution method using real data from tablets and eBook services to calibrate quantities of managerial importance.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes related work in PSS, while Section 3 introduces the associated design profit maximization framework. Section 4 illustrates the proposed method using an application of the tablet and eBook services design example, and the results are discussed. Section 5 offers conclusions, limitations, and directions for future research.

2 Theoretical framework: related prior research

Systems comprising services and products have appeared in prior literature in various disciplines. PSSs were introduced by Goedkoop et al. (Reference Goedkoop, van Halen, te Riele and Rommens1999), who defined them as ‘a marketable set of services and products capable of jointly fulfilling a user’s need.’ This has since been regarded as an emerging research area for integrated PS ecosystems (Mont Reference Mont2002; Baines et al. Reference Baines, Lightfoot, Peppard, Johnson, Tiwari, Shehab and Swink2009; Roy & Baxter Reference Roy and Baxter2009); full reviews of recent literature appear in Beuren, Ferreira & Miguel (Reference Beuren, Ferreira and Miguel2013), and Reim, Parida & Örtqvist (Reference Reim, Parida and Örtqvist2015). Besides the tablet and digital service market example discussed earlier, a frequently used example in this line of research is the case of Rolls-Royce PLC, which supplies total-care package services to airlines, as opposed to merely selling gas turbine engines alone. This business model, often referred to as ‘power by the hour’ (e.g., Smith Reference Smith2013), works by supplying services to maintain and repair engines, collecting data on product performance, and using them to upgrade engine efficiency, while reducing the costs and environmental impact. Sundin & Bras (Reference Sundin and Bras2005) also claim that product remanufacturing in PSS makes the business model more environmentally and economically attractive compared to conventional ones. Baines et al. (Reference Baines, Lightfoot, Steve, Neely, Greenough, Peppard, Roy, Shehab, Braganza, Tiwari, Alcock, Angus, Bastl, Cousens, Irving, Johnson, Kingston, Lockett, Martinez, Michele, Tranfield, Walton and Wilson2007) explained this as a special case of ‘servitization,’ a business model transformation of ‘sale of product’ to ‘sale of use.’ Although the range of extant service integration research is vast, relatively little research is aimed at market-driven profit maximization design approaches for producers to implement this paradigm in a practical manner (Vasantha et al. Reference Vasantha, Roy, Lelah and Brissaud2012), with notable exceptions being financial service ‘products’ (e.g., Thornton & White Reference Thornton and White2001; Lee Reference Lee2002).

In marketing, product design research focusing on profit optimization has a rich history (e.g., Moore et al. Reference Moore, Louviere and Verma1999; Green, Krieger & Wind Reference Green, Krieger and Wind2001). One major input for such methods is the quantification of consumer preferences and choice shares, typically achieved via conjoint-based methods. Since demand can be written as a function of product attributes and price, conjoint methods allow optimization for various metrics such as sales, shares, and profit (given a product cost model, which manufacturers can supply internally).

A similar profit maximization approach (based on the conjoint/choice model) has been applied to service design (Pullman & Moore Reference Pullman and Moore1999; Easton & Pullman Reference Easton and Pullman2001). Service design research generally addresses both operations and marketing for the following reason: although product design methods are applicable to service design, services possess unique characteristics – such as simultaneity of production, consumption, perishability, inability to stockpile, etc. – so that operations management techniques can handle service capacity and demand management (Pullman & Moore Reference Pullman and Moore1999). Service design research considers not only tangible services (i.e., technical features), but also how the service is delivered, such as waiting lines, service delays, scheduling, and congestion in the service facility (Pullman & Moore Reference Pullman and Moore1999; Easton & Pullman Reference Easton and Pullman2001). Several articles have addressed service and product characteristics together, though not in PS channels specifically. For example, Cohen & Whang (Reference Cohen and Whang1997) designed the joint product/service bundle, addressing trade-offs between product profit and after-sales service profit, and Verma et al. (Reference Verma, Thompson, Moore and Louviere2001) addressed product and process attributes as key inputs regarding the ‘operating difficulty’ of meeting customer demand patterns. Kang, Feinberg & Papalambros (Reference Kang, Feinberg and Papalambros2013) proposed an integrated optimization framework to codesign products (e.g., tablets) and services (e.g., eBooks and cloud services) to maximize overall profits.

Real product design decisions cannot be made based only on marketing considerations. The marketer and engineer need to consider the trade-offs between marketable design and feasible design (Michalek et al. Reference Michalek, Feinberg and Papalambros2005, Reference Michalek, Ebbes, Adigüzel, Feinberg and Papalambros2011). Although marketing research does not typically consider design feasibility, engineering design research has begun to adopt profit optimization as an enterprise-driven design objective subject to engineering constraints. This design for market systems (DMS) approach integrates marketing, engineering, manufacturing, operations, and policy considerations into a profit optimization framework (Michalek et al. Reference Michalek, Feinberg and Papalambros2005; Lewis et al. Reference Lewis, Chen and Schmidt2006; Frischknecht et al. Reference Frischknecht, Whitefoot and Papalambros2010; Kang Reference Kang2014).

Profit optimization of multiplayer channels typically follows game theory, with the Nash equilibrium condition that no player can gain by altering his/her decisions (Nash Reference Nash1950, Reference Nash1951). While there are different game theory concepts such as Cournot, Bertrand, and Stackelberg solutions, the appropriate solution concept in our context is the Stackelberg solution because the focal firm producing the product/service moves first and the competitors then decide their products/services. This Stackelberg solution has been widely used for product design optimization under competition in DMS research (Michalek, Papalambros & Skerlos Reference Michalek, Papalambros and Skerlos2004; Shiau & Michalek Reference Shiau and Michalek2009b ; Kang et al. Reference Kang, Ren, Feinberg and Papalambros2016).

Since each channel player’s decision can affect the other channel player’s profits and subsequent actions, it is important to understand the relationships between channel decisions, an observation that goes back to the findings of Jeuland & Shugan (Reference Jeuland and Shugan1983). Sudhir (Reference Sudhir2001) further categorized these relationships according to manufacturer–manufacturer interaction, manufacturer–retailer interaction, the retailer pricing rule, demand functional form, and wholesale price information availability. Sadeghi & Zandieh (Reference Sadeghi and Zandieh2011) developed a two-player non-cooperative game framework for product portfolios while considering customer–engineering interactions, while Cai, Dai & Zhou (Reference Cai, Dai and Zhou2012) addressed the combination of exclusive channel and revenue sharing strategies for complementary goods markets. Some engineering design research (Williams, Azarm & Kannan Reference Williams, Azarm and Kannan2008; Shiau & Michalek Reference Shiau and Michalek2009a ) have begun addressing the distribution channel to optimize product design for suppliers’ profit, subject to enhanced profitability of retailers. Shiau & Michalek (Reference Shiau and Michalek2009a ) focused on product design and the ‘conventional’ distribution channel via a game theory approach. Aribarg & Foutz (Reference Aribarg and Foutz2009) addressed category-based choice modeling for complementary products in a study on cell phones and service plans, but in the context of a single choice of PS bundle, as opposed to sequential choices of products, and multiple services where market-based asymmetries exist.

Overall, as disciplines, marketing, design, and operations have each begun to address the complex task of optimizing subsets of product attribute, service attribute, and channel structure variables. To date, however, channel structure has been either predetermined or closely linked to the nature of the products themselves, for example, through unique service providers. In contrast, the channel structure is here considered as a variable that is interrelated with all other variables and allows asymmetries in service provision and sequential consumer choices. Game theory considerations guide solutions through this high-dimensional space of possible joint product, service, and channel configurations, where multiple services can be offered via each product’s platform.

3 Methodology: proposed model

3.1 PS channel design decisions

For modeling a PS channel, the key trade-offs in PS channel design decisions need discussion. A simple example helps illustrate the interconnectedness of the service and product design optimization problems. When a product is launched, the producer must determine its price, which can be approached with standard techniques (e.g., conjoint and a time-discounted or finite-horizon profit model). For PS channels, the product price setting must consider the demand for associated services, in addition to what might happen if a lower initial product price spurs demand not only for the producer’s own services, but also for the competitors’ services that can be accessed through its device. If the channel is exclusive (the producer’s customers can only access its services on its devices), the lower product price may translate into greater demand for costly services down the road – the inspiration behind the saying ‘give away the razors and get them on the blades’ (Anderson Reference Anderson2009). In a non-exclusive channel, one might give away the razors and see a competitors’ sales surge for the blades, in effect, leading to a double loss. Yet the seemingly simple solution of ensuring no competitor’s services are available makes the core product less versatile, and therefore placed at a disadvantage to more open platforms, a situation reminiscent of the early debates between the Apple (closed) and Microsoft (open) Operating System development platforms. This additional source of consumer freedom in the PS channel renders PS choice and demand far more complex to model. Since the particular PS channel availability is a shared decision variable, firms need to understand how the PS channel decisions affect not only their own service and product demand levels, but also those of competitors’ shared channels.

The PS channel design problem is well exemplified by eBook service and tablet designs, the specific application examined later in this article. For example, Kindle/Amazon Books (Amazon), Nook/B&N (Barnes & Noble), iPad/iBook (Apple), and Nexus/Google Play (Google), supply both eBook services, and associated core tablet products. Assuming that all PS channels were exclusive, Kindle users could avail only Amazon eBooks, and Amazon can supply eBooks only to Kindle users; iPad users are limited to iBook; and iBook can supply iPad users alone. Yet in reality, PS channels are non-exclusive and, importantly, asymmetric: at the time of data collection (see Section 4.1), a Kindle user is limited exclusively to the Amazon eBook market, as Amazon’s App Store lacks an iBook app; yet Amazon supplies eBook services not only to Kindle, but also the iPad (via the Kindle app in Apple’s App store). That is, iPad users can use not only iBooks but also Amazon eBooks, but iBooks supplies eBook services to only the iPad users (Bläsi & Rothlauf Reference Bläsi and Rothlauf2013; Ritala, Golnam & Wegmann Reference Ritala, Golnam and Wegmann2014).

3.1.1 Channels and customer choice

The effect of the PS channel structure on customer choices is clear from the fact that customers choose services from multiple providers, i.e., other than the ones explicitly provided by the manufacturers of their equipment. This effect cuts both ways: the choice of product is influenced by which services will be available while using any particular one. In a non-exclusive channel structure, when choosing a product, customers can consider service quality and price, as well as how many services (i.e., service variety) are available through any particular product. The PS channel thereby affects the product choice and service demand. For example, an Amazon customer who has many Amazon eBooks does not need to buy a Kindle specifically: she or he has other options, such as the iPad Kindle app. Analogously, an iPad user does not need to buy all, or indeed any, eBooks through iBooks, because other iPad-compatible options, like Amazon, are available.

3.1.2 Channels and product design

While PS channels have a clear impact on product choice, their structure also affects producers’ design decisions. When a producer supplies its services to other competitors’ products, it allows users of those products to access its own content. When that content is proprietary, those who chose the producer’s product(s) merely to be able to access their content no longer have to use this choice criterion. For example, many current Apple programs are specific to their own operating system; those wishing to use these programs must purchase them from Apple, and importing the software to other operating systems might therefore lower the product demand for Apple, overall. On the other hand, when a producer allows its product to use other competitors’ services, its product becomes more attractive due to increased service variety; however, it may also cede service demand to competitors. Thus, the decision to ‘open up’ a device to services from others presents a dilemma, involving trade-offs between demand or the share for a product, and for its formerly exclusive services.

3.1.3 Adding and deleting channels

This sharing of the PS channel decision is affected by competitors’ decisions in at least two major ways. The first and most obvious is that the PS channel decision requires acceptance from competitors. Although deleting the channel – i.e., an equipment manufacturer deciding to no longer support content from a specific provider, or a provider electing to no longer serve a particular device – may be decided by each producer individually, adding a channel requires an agreement between two partners, a decision that can hinge on the predicted profit change for both. If adding a channel brings more of a valued quantity (usually, profit, but potentially also sales or share) to both producers, it should be accepted ceteris paribus.

Second and less obvious, the PS channel can entail different levels of ease of use. A producer may offer more advantages to its own PS channel than to a channel with other competitors. For example, in its early days, Apple allowed iPad users to shop for eBooks (from Amazon) through the Kindle app; however, Apple began to require a 30% portion of the revenue from each Amazon book purchase on iOS, perhaps in a bid to protect its own iBook service. Amazon decided not to include a store function in the Kindle app on iOS. Therefore, Kindle app users could no longer shop for Amazon eBooks directly; instead, iPad users needed to follow the more laborious route of shopping for Amazon eBooks from a web-based store outside the app, sync them with the app on the iPad, and then access them. In short, the ease of use of services can vary according to competitors’ PS decisions. Notably, PS channels differ critically from ‘mixed source’ applications (e.g., Casadesus-Masanell & Llanes Reference Casadesus-Masanell and Llanes2011), where the question is one of ‘opening up’ a platform to development by others, while not contractually licensing it for mutual profitability.

To sum up, in order to coordinate PS profitability, producers need to strike a balance between exclusive and non-exclusive PS channels. In particular, they need to anticipate competitors’ potential profit changes to negotiate a mutually beneficial channel decision. For example, a tablet producer can only reasonably propose the support of eBooks from another firm if the arrangement is profitable to that firm. In the modeling approach presented in this article, this insight will be used – for the first time to the best of our knowledge – to impose constraints on possible contractual solutions. One must note that optimal prices and attributes for both services and products depend on the PS channel structures themselves and cannot be optimized in an ‘exogenous’ manner, and then fed into the PS design problem as fixed quantities. That is, producers need to understand the relationships among all these variables, and then optimize them concurrently. Prior work in marketing and management (Jeuland & Shugan Reference Jeuland and Shugan1983; McGuire & Staelin Reference McGuire and Staelin1983; Lee & Staelin Reference Lee and Staelin1997; Sudhir Reference Sudhir2001; Luo, Kannan & Ratchford Reference Luo, Kannan and Ratchford2007; Cai et al. Reference Cai, Dai and Zhou2012), design (Williams et al. Reference Williams, Azarm and Kannan2008; Shiau & Michalek Reference Shiau and Michalek2009a ), and systems (see, e.g., Jun, Ward & Clarkson Reference Jun, Ward and Clarkson2010; Zhang et al. Reference Zhang, Lee, Wu and Choy2016) has addressed distribution channels for maximizing profit, but these are ‘conventional’ channels between suppliers and retailers with a given fixed structure, and not channels selected for joint optimization. Here, a purview of prior works is provided to consider the types of channel structures coming to dominate online commerce and their joint implications for product design and marketing.

3.2 Market setting

This section details the market setting for the integrated PS business model addressed in this study. Figure 1 depicts several representative PS channel structures involving two producers. Service choice examples are also shown according to their PS channel structures.

Figure 1. Examples of market settings.

The key properties of the types of systems depicted in Figure 1:

  1. (1) A producer supplies a service and product together. Producer $A$ supplies product $p_{A}$ and associated service $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ ; producer $B$ supplies product $p_{B}$ and associated service $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ .

  2. (2) A service consists of multiple subservices, e.g., $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ includes $\{s_{Ai}\}=\{s_{A1},s_{A2},s_{A3},s_{A4}\}$ , while $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ includes $\{s_{Bi}\}=\{s_{B1},s_{B2},s_{B3},s_{B4}\}$ . [For example, these could be items in a web store, such as a particular book or app, as long as they are potentially purchasable from different providers.]

  3. (3) Subservices can be unique to a particular provider or similar across providers. In the case of similar services, pairs such as, $(s_{A1},s_{B1}),(s_{A2},s_{B2})$ , $(s_{A3},s_{B3}),(s_{A4},s_{B4})$ may have different prices and qualities while providing functionally equivalent benefits to the user. [Given any set of subservices from A and B – partly overlapping or not – one can always conjoin them to create a key list with matched indices, and this will be done later.]

  4. (4) Because the products are presumed to provide similar core benefits, each customer who buys a product, chooses exactly one, either $p_{A}$ or $p_{B}$ ; customers may elect to choose the ‘outside good’ (i.e., no product at all, that is, waiting), but not more than one. [This will be explicitly incorporated in the forthcoming conjoint simulation.] S/he then chooses a service – either $s_{Ai}$ or $s_{Bi}$ . Elected services correspond to a subset of all available services.

  5. (5) There are three cases, in general, for two producers:

    1. (i) Case 1, exclusive channels: $p_{A}$ users can use subservices from only $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ ; $p_{B}$ users can use subservices from only $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ .

    2. (ii) Case 2, non-exclusive and asymmetric channels: $p_{A}$ users can use subservices from only $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ ; but $p_{B}$ users can use subservices from both $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ and $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ , so that $p_{B}$ users can choose some subservices from pairs such as $(s_{A1},s_{B1})$ , $(s_{A2},s_{B2})$ , $(s_{A3},s_{B3})$ , $(s_{A4},s_{B4})$ . For example, $p_{B}$ users can choose $\{s_{B1},s_{A2},s_{B3}\}$ , that is, two items from their own product manufacturer, $B$ , and one from $A$ .

    3. (iii) Case 3, non-exclusive and symmetric channels: regardless of product choice, customers can choose any subservices.

  6. (6) Adding a channel requires acceptance from competitors, whereas removing a channel can be decided by only one partner (unless contractually disallowed). For example, when producer $A$ wants to add a channel between $p_{A}$ and $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ , or a channel between $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ and $p_{B}$ , acceptance by producer $B$ is required.

The assumption is that a customer chooses a product based on product price, product attributes, and the PS channel; and chooses a service based on service price and attributes. Taking the example of the tablet and eBook service market, $p_{A}$ and $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ can be the Kindle and Amazon market, respectively; $p_{B}$ and $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ can be the iPad and iBooks markets, respectively. That is, $\{s_{A1},s_{A2},s_{A3},\ldots ,s_{AM}\}$ are eBooks in the Amazon market and $\{s_{B1},s_{B2},s_{B3},\ldots ,s_{BM}\}$ are eBooks in the iBooks market. In practice, $M$ , the number of total potential books, can number in millions. Note that $s_{At}$ and $s_{Bt}$ are the same book, where $t=1,2,3,\ldots ,M$ , and can either take on a value of 1, if the book is available, or 0 if it is not. In the service and product market, the book price and shopping methods can be different. Each customer can purchase a different number of eBooks for a different period of product ownership.

3.3 Demand and profit modeling under the PS channel

Services and products are modeled based on the market set-up described above, with a demand model that can be modified for different market settings. This study adopts the latent (to the researcher) consumer utility concept underlying random-utility-based discrete choice models (Green & Krieger Reference Green and Krieger1996), which have come to dominate both theoretical and applied work in the marketing field, as has the Hierarchical Bayes (HB) choice-based conjoint (Rossi & Allenby Reference Rossi and Allenby2003; Gustafsson, Herrmann & Huber Reference Gustafsson, Herrmann and Huber2013) for estimating heterogeneous customer preferences (often referred to as ‘part-worths’ for discrete or discretized attributes).

Product demand modeling follows recent design research using the HB approach (e.g., Michalek et al. Reference Michalek, Ebbes, Adigüzel, Feinberg and Papalambros2011), which itself builds upon decades of research in preference elicitation and measurement (see, for additional detail, Green et al. (Reference Green, Krieger and Wind2001) or Gustafsson et al. (Reference Gustafsson, Herrmann and Huber2013)). The basic process can be summarized as follows: (i) Data are gathered using a choice-based conjoint task; (ii) HB choice model parameters (i.e., individual-level part-worths) for the preference function are estimated; (iii) splines interpolate across (discrete) part-worths, enabling efficient optimization over a continuous design space; (iv) market demand is predicted, based on choice probabilities and potential market size.

The individual-level discrete utility, $v_{ip_{j}}$ , of individual $i$ and product $p_{j}$ takes the usual form with respect to discrete attributes levels, as

(1) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle v_{ip_{j}}=\mathop{\sum }_{k=1}^{K}\mathop{\sum }_{l=1}^{L_{k}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}_{ikl}z_{jkl}, & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $z_{jkl}$ are binary dummy variables indicating if alternative product $j$ possesses attribute $k$ at level $l$ ; $z_{jkl}$ represent product price, product attributes, and service compatibility; $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}_{ikl}$ are the part-worth coefficients of attribute $k$ at level $l$ for individual $i$ .

Service compatibility is determined by the structure of the PS channel decisions made by producers. For example, in Figure 1, there are four PS channel decision variables: potential linkages between $p_{A}$ & $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ , $p_{A}$ & $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ , $p_{B}$ & $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ , and/or $p_{B}$ & $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ . Channel decision variables are binary: 1 indicates that a channel is connected (as depicted by lines in Figure 1), while 0 indicates that it is not. Note that $p_{A}$ & $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ , and $p_{B}$ & $\mathbf{s}_{B}$ should always be connected, since producers will by necessity make their services available using their own product platforms. In this case, customers can avail three levels of service compatibility: $\mathbf{s}_{A},\mathbf{s}_{B}$ , and $(\mathbf{s}_{A},\mathbf{s}_{B})$ , according to their product choice. In our forthcoming empirical example, there will be four producers, and therefore $2^{4}-1=15$ levels of service compatibility, as shown later in Table 2.

The HB choice model estimates the conjoint part-worths via a two-level process. At the ‘upper level,’ we assume individuals’ part-worths, $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}}_{i}$ , follow a multivariate normal distribution, $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}}_{i}\sim N(\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D703}},\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6EC}})$ , where $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D703}}$ indicates a vector of mean individual preference and $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6EC}}$ is their covariance matrix; that is, the former ( $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D703}}$ ) suggests what a ‘typical’ consumer would like, whereas the latter suggests how much variability there is in consumer preference (diagonal elements of $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6EC}}$ ), as well as how preferences for one attribute help predict those for a different attribute (off-diagonal elements of $\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6EC}}$ ). At the ‘lower level,’ choice probabilities have a logit form, which is particularly amenable to gradient and elasticity computation:

(2) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle Pr_{i}(p_{j})=\exp (v_{ip_{j}})/\mathop{\sum }_{j^{\prime }\in \mathbf{J}}\exp (v_{ip_{j^{\prime }}}), & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $Pr_{i}(p_{j})$ is the probability that individual $i$ chooses product option $p_{j}$ from a set of product alternatives $\mathbf{J}$ .

Product demand can be calculated, for various market scenarios, based on heterogeneous customer preference models. Either the total or average demand across participants can be used for optimization (as these contain identical information); the latter is given by:

(3) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle q_{p_{j}}=\frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}Pr_{i}(p_{j}), & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $q_{p_{j}}$ is the product demand of product option $p_{j},\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}$ indicates the potential product market size (i.e., number of users), and $I$ indicates the total number of participants.

Next, service demand is calculated via conditional probability, given product choice and demand. A choice-based conjoint survey can be conducted (as described previously) to gather service preference data; the estimation of service attributes part-worths proceeds analogously to that of products. Note, however, that the setting is somewhat more complex, due to the following reasons: (1) service alternative options depend on product choice; (2) services consist of subservices; and (3) service choices occur on multiple occasions.

The individual-level discrete utility, $v_{is_{h_{t}}}$ , of individual $i$ and service $s_{h_{t}}$ , can be expressed in linear form with respect to discrete attribute levels as

(4) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle v_{is_{h_{t}}}=\mathop{\sum }_{m=1}^{M}\mathop{\sum }_{n=1}^{N_{m}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}_{imn}z_{h_{t}mn}, & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $h$ is a service platform, $t$ indicates subservice, $z_{h_{t}mn}$ are binary dummy variables representing service price, and attributes $m$ at level $n$ , and $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}_{imn}$ are the part-worth coefficients of service attribute $m$ at level $n$ for individual $i$ . Using the HB choice model, $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6FD}_{imn}$ are estimated, and then service choice probabilities can be calculated using the logit-based expression

(5) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle Pr_{i}(s_{h_{t}}|p_{j})=\frac{\exp (v_{is_{h_{t}}})}{\mathop{\sum }_{h^{\prime }\in \mathbf{H}_{p_{j}}}\exp (v_{is_{h_{t}^{\prime }}})}, & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $Pr_{i}(s_{h_{t}}|p_{j})$ is the conditional probability that individual $i$ , after choosing product $p_{j}$ , will then choose service option $s_{h_{t}}$ from the set of service alternatives $\mathbf{H}_{p_{j}}$ of product $p_{j}$ . The service alternatives available to a consumer who has selected a particular product are dictated by the PS channel decision made by its producer. Equations (4) and (5) represent, for simplicity of exposition, single choices of subservices (e.g., one eBook choice). Service demand can be calculated by summing all subservice choices over all products during the product’s life cycle.

As before, the averaged (across consumers) demand value is used for profit optimization:

(6) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle q_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}=\frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\mathop{\sum }_{t\in \mathbf{T}_{i}}\mathop{\sum }_{j^{\prime }\in \mathbf{J}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}Pr_{i}(p_{j^{\prime }})Pr_{i}(s_{h_{t}}|p_{j^{\prime }}), & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $q_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}$ is service demand of service option $\mathbf{s}_{h}$ , $\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}$ indicates the potential product market size, $Pr_{i}(p_{j^{\prime }})$ is choice probability of product $p_{j^{\prime }}$ , $Pr_{i}(s_{h_{t}}|p_{j^{\prime }})$ is conditional probability of service $s_{h_{t}}$ given $p_{j^{\prime }}$ , $\mathbf{J}$ is a set of product alternatives, $\mathbf{T}_{i}$ is a set of service choices of individual $i$ , and $I$ indicates total number of individuals. The set $\mathbf{T}_{i}$ is can be determined by foreknowledge, an additional survey, or inferred from market statistics (e.g., eBook purchase history).

To illustrate, Equations (1) to (6) are applied to Case 2, that is, a non-exclusive and asymmetric channel (as in Figure 1), for two products, $A$ and $B$ :

(7) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle q_{p_{A}}=\frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}\left[\frac{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})}{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})+\exp (v_{ip_{B}})+\exp (v_{ip_{0}})}\right] & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(8) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle q_{p_{B}}=\frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}\left[\frac{\exp (v_{ip_{B}})}{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})+\exp (v_{ip_{B}})+\exp (v_{ip_{0}})}\right] & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(9) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle q_{\mathbf{s}_{A}} & = & \displaystyle \frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\quad \mathop{\sum }_{t\in \mathbf{T}_{i}}\left[\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}\left[\frac{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})}{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})+\exp (v_{ip_{B}})+\exp (v_{ip_{0}})}\right]\right.\nonumber\\ \displaystyle & & \displaystyle \times \left[\frac{\exp (v_{is_{A_{t}}})}{\exp (v_{is_{A_{t}}})+\exp (v_{is_{0}})}\right]\nonumber\\ \displaystyle & & \displaystyle +\,\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}\left[\frac{\exp (v_{ip_{B}})}{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})+\exp (v_{ip_{B}})+\exp (v_{ip_{0}})}\right]\nonumber\\ \displaystyle & & \displaystyle \times \left.\left[\frac{\exp (v_{is_{A_{t}}})}{\exp (v_{is_{A_{t}}})+\exp (v_{is_{B_{t}}})+\exp (v_{is_{0}})}\right]\right]\end{eqnarray}$$
(10) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle q_{\mathbf{s}_{B}} & = & \displaystyle \frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\mathop{\sum }_{t\in \mathbf{T}_{i}}\left[\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}\left[\frac{\exp (v_{ip_{B}})}{\exp (v_{ip_{A}})+\exp (v_{ip_{B}})+\exp (v_{ip_{0}})}\right]\right.\nonumber\\ \displaystyle & & \displaystyle \times \left.\left[\frac{\exp (v_{is_{B_{t}}})}{\exp (v_{is_{B_{t}}})+\exp (v_{is_{0}})}\right]\right].\end{eqnarray}$$

Here, $q_{p_{A}}$ and $q_{p_{B}}$ are product demands of producers $A$ and $B$ , respectively, $q_{\mathbf{s}_{A}}$ and $q_{\mathbf{s}_{B}}$ are analogous service demands, and ‘0’ indicates that the customer ‘chooses the no-choice option,’ that is, refrains from choosing entirely. Note that Eq. (9) has one term more than Eq. (10) because service $\mathbf{s}_{A}$ can be used by both $p_{A}$ and $p_{B}$ .

Based on this demand model, the product profit and service profit are calculated as

(11) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{p_{j}}=q_{p_{j}}(P_{p_{j}}-C_{p_{j}}), & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(12) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}=\frac{1}{I}\mathop{\sum }_{i=1}^{I}\mathop{\sum }_{t\in \mathbf{T}_{i}}\mathop{\sum }_{j^{\prime }\in \mathbf{J}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D707}Pr_{i}(p_{j^{\prime }})Pr_{i}(s_{h_{t}}|p_{j^{\prime }})(P_{s_{h_{t}}}-C_{s_{h_{t}}}\!), & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{p_{j}}$ is the profit of product $p_{j}$ , $q_{p_{j}}$ is product demand, $P_{p_{j}}$ is product price, $C_{p_{j}}$ is product cost, $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}$ is the profit of service $\mathbf{s}_{h}$ , $P_{s_{h_{t}}}$ is price of service $s_{h_{t}}$ , $C_{s_{h_{t}}}$ is cost of service $s_{h_{t}}$ , and other symbols retain their definitions from Eq. (6). Our goal is to optimize the sum of the service and product profits.

3.4 Product–service design framework

Based on the demand system above, a framework to optimize profits for PS design is proposed and depicted schematically in Figure 2. Following a predetermined order, one firm is selected as the focal firm among producers who optimizes its profit. Then, the next producer is selected as the focal firm who maximizes profit, while the previous focal firm becomes one of its competitors. This sequential optimization proceeds until the optimization result converges to the equilibrium.

Figure 2. Profit maximization framework for PS design.

Before optimization, the current PS channel structure and competitors’ service and product prices/attributes are set. Decision variables are the PS channel structure, product price, product attributes, service prices, and service attributes. Note that the product attributes and service attributes for optimization are selected by the designer. This selection is beyond the scope of the research reported here and it is challenging in its own right.

These variables are set for the competitor, then optimized for the focal firm. Note that all decision variables are optimized at the same time and a producer can access all other previous decisions during its turn. This framework is used for the design of a single product and multiple services for each producer. (Extension to product family or line design would require a straightforward modification of the present optimization framework with a concomitantly higher-order dimensional optimization; see Michalek et al. (Reference Michalek, Ebbes, Adigüzel, Feinberg and Papalambros2011) for additional details.)

The optimization problem for the focal firm, in each iteration, is stated as follows:

(13) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle \max _{\mathbf{x}_{p_{j}},\mathbf{x}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}},\mathbf{c}\mathbf{h}_{\!jh}}\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{p_{j}}+\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}} & & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

with respect to

(14) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \mathbf{x}_{p_{j}}=[p_{p_{j}},\mathbf{a}_{p_{j}}\!] & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(15) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \mathbf{x}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}=[\mathbf{p}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}},\mathbf{a}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}] & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(16) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \mathbf{c}\mathbf{h}_{\!jh}=[ch_{\!jh_{1}},ch_{\!jh_{2}},\ldots ,ch_{\!jh_{2n-2}}],\mathit{c}\mathit{h}_{\!jh}\in \{0,1\}. & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

subject to

(17) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle lb\leqslant [\mathbf{x}_{p_{j}},\mathbf{x}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}]\leqslant ub & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(18) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle \mathbf{g}_{ch}(\mathbf{x}_{p_{j}},\mathbf{x}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}},\mathbf{c}\mathbf{h}_{\!jh},\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}}_{p_{j^{\prime }\in \mathbf{J}}},\boldsymbol{\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}}_{\mathbf{s}_{h^{\prime }\in \mathbf{H}}})\leqslant 0. & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

The objective of Eq. (13) is to maximize the overall profit which is the sum of the product profit $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{p_{j}}$ , of product $p_{j}$ , and the service profit $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{\mathbf{s}_{j}}$ of service $\mathbf{s}_{h}$ . As introduced in Section 3.3, the product demand is calculated based on product price, product attributes, and service compatibility as per Eqs. (1) to (3). Using individuals’ potential services sets, service demand is calculated based on service prices, service attributes, the PS channel, and product demand, using Eqs. (4) to (6). Product and service profits are calculated using price, cost, and demand for services and products, using Eqs. (11) and (12).

In Eq. (14), $\mathbf{x}_{p_{j}}$ is the vector of product design variables, where $p_{p_{j}}$ is the product price and $\mathbf{a}_{p_{j}}$ is the vector of product attributes. In Eq. (15), $\mathbf{x}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}$ is the vector of service design variables, where $\mathbf{p}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}$ is the vector of service prices and $\mathbf{a}_{\mathbf{s}_{h}}$ is the vector of service attributes. In Eq. (16), $\mathbf{c}\mathbf{h}_{\!jh}$ is the vector of channel design variables.

As discussed earlier, the PS channel is a binary design variable. So, if a channel links a product and a service platform, its value is 1, otherwise, 0. When there are $n$ producers in the market, the PS channel can be described as an $n\times n$ matrix, as shown in Table 1. Optimization amounts to a producer’s choosing values from within this matrix for its service and product options; note that diagonal values are 1 because services and products from the same manufacturer are always connected. Therefore, the number of channel design variables for the focal firm is $2\times (n-1)$ , where the firm decides whether to supply its product to ( $n-1$ ) competitors’ service platforms and whether to supply its service platform to ( $n-1$ ) competitors’ products. Eq. (17) shows bound constraints on the product and service design variables, and Eq. (18) shows inequality constraints for PS channels acceptance. $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{p_{j^{\prime }\in \mathbf{J}}}$ and $\unicode[STIX]{x1D6F1}_{\mathbf{s}_{h^{\prime }\in \mathbf{H}}}$ indicate product profits and service profits of competitors, respectively.

Table 1. Market setting for eBook / tablet applications

a Prices and figures in parentheses refer to the average prices and standard deviations, respectively, across 20 bestseller books.

A notable feature of the proposed framework is that it uses a competitor’s profit change as a constraint: when a given producer wants to add channels with a competitor’s product or service, if its design decision affects the competitor’s profit positively, it is taken to be a feasible design decision; otherwise, it is not. In other words, a producer can only reasonably propose channels to a competitor that will enhance that competitor’s profit. However, when more than three producers make decisions sequentially, some channels can oscillate between two producers by repeatedly adding and deleting. In our research, it is assumed that adding oscillated channels is not permitted after all other channels have converged. Deleting an oscillated channel has priority over adding one. For feasibility constraints (e.g., whether a product’s components can fit in its case), engineering and operations simulation models (Kang, Feinberg & Papalambros Reference Kang, Feinberg and Papalambros2015, Reference Kang, Feinberg and Papalambros2017) that consider uncertainties (Kang, Bayrak & Papalambros Reference Kang, Bayrak and Papalambros2018; Lee, Kang & Lee Reference Lee, Kang and Lee2019) can be applied.

The optimization proceeds iteratively across producers. After maximizing the overall profit of a focal producer, other competitors optimize their profit using the same process that the ‘optimized’ producer followed. These sequential optimizations proceed until no players (producers) can find a better design (i.e., one that increases profit). This results in a Nash equilibrium, a ‘solution concept’ widely deployed in marketing and engineering design research (Luo et al. Reference Luo, Kannan and Ratchford2007; Shiau & Michalek Reference Shiau and Michalek2009b ; Kang et al. Reference Kang, Ren, Feinberg and Papalambros2016). Here during the initial iteration, it is assumed that producers decide on all decision variables; for subsequent iterations, they decide only on product/service prices and channels. In other words, because product design decisions are slow and costly to alter, it is presumed that producers first decide product attributes, and then engage in (iterative, sequential) optimization for prices and channels for both services and products.

4 Application to the tablet and eBook market

4.1 Market setting

The proposed framework is demonstrated via tablet (product) and eBook (service) designs. Because the main purpose of this study is illustrative, market assumptions are deliberately generic, transparent, and simple, as follows. First, four main producers are selected, each of which operates in both the tablet and eBook markets: (1) Kindle/Amazon Kindle books, (2) Nook/Barnes & Noble (B&N), (3) iPad/iBooks, and (4) Nexus/Google Play books. The study focuses on single product designs (as opposed to product family designs), and therefore assumes that each producer optimizes for a single ‘flagship’ tablet with full-color display. For eBook services, price distributions across the four eBook markets are based on the real observed prices of 20 bestseller eBooks in each market available from a verified, published source (Gilbert Reference Gilbert2012); the PS channel structure is based on the market situation at the time price data collection. In addition, the assumption is that when a customer shops for an eBook from her or his tablet’s producer, she or he does so via an in-tablet app but uses a web-based interface for eBooks from other competitors (Bläsi & Rothlauf Reference Bläsi and Rothlauf2013; Ritala et al. Reference Ritala, Golnam and Wegmann2014).

Table 1 summarizes the market setting for the study, with four flagship tablets and four eBook markets. The eBook prices shown are averages of 20 bestsellers. For example, Amazon’s price of $9.78 compares favorably with those for B&N ($9.98), iBooks ($10.41), and Google Play ($10.14). The binary indicators listed in Table 1 indicate whether a channel exists between tablet and eBook markets. Note, for example, that the PS channel is asymmetric: iPad users can access all four eBook services (Row 3 of 4), while iBooks does not supply eBook services to competitors (Column 3 of 4).

4.2 Demand modeling

Two choice-based conjoint surveys were conducted, for the tablet and eBook, sequentially. 152 respondents in the United States (US) were surveyed using Amazon’s Mechanical Turk (Amazon 2012a ) in conjunction with Sawtooth Software’s CBC (Choice-Based Conjoint) Hierarchical Bayes Module (Orme Reference Orme2013); this sample size is comparable to those used in prior studies in the area (e.g., Michalek et al. Reference Michalek, Feinberg and Papalambros2005, with $n=184$ ). Respondent demographics were broadly consistent with the US in general: 41% male, 59% female; 20% were 15–24 years of age, 49% 25–34, 16% 35–44, and 15% older than 45; 72% and 58% of the respondents reported tablet and eBook use experiences, respectively. Analogous figures for the US (Census 2012; Pew Research 2013) are: tablet users are 47% male and 53% female; 18% are 15–24 years of age, 19% 25–34, 24% 35–44, and 40% are over 45. These deviations between sample and population demographics are non-significant.

For the tablet choice-based conjoint survey, five attributes – compatible eBooks, tablet brands, price, display size, and storage – were included, as shown in Table 2. Respondents were asked to suppose that they were considering purchasing a tablet, with the specific objective that they could read eBooks, and that their tablet choices would determine which of the multiple compatible eBook services would be available to them. The survey began with an ‘education’ page that ensured participants understood the nature of the eBook/tablet format, co-branding, and other key elements of the market system; for example, when the tablet brand is Kindle HD, the compatible eBook options always included Amazon (i.e., ones along the diagonal in Table 1). As is typical, each choice set included a small number (in this case, three) of tablet profiles along with a ‘none’ option (that is, the ‘no-choice option’ in which the customer chooses none of the PS options).

Table 2. Part-worths for tablet attribute levels

Previous respondents from the tablet survey were surveyed again. They were told to suppose that they had bought a tablet, and then wanted to purchase an eBook. For the eBook choice-based conjoint survey, three attributes of known importance were included – eBook market, eBook price, and ease of shopping – and shown in Table 3. Subjects were told that the prices for the same book can vary across markets. As mentioned earlier, customers can buy a book from their tablet producer’s market via an in-tablet app, or from another seller using a web-based store. This reflects the reality that using your tablet brand’s eBook market is simply more convenient than buying from a competitor. As in the tablet conjoint, each choice set included three eBook profiles, and the option of choosing ‘none.’

Table 3. Part-worths for eBook attribute levels

a When tablet and eBook market are from the same producer, eBooks can be purchased using an in-tablet app.

Using HB estimation (as per Section 3.2), individual preference functions were quantified for each of the 152 respondents. Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) draws were ‘thinned’ to every tenth; the burn-in was 50,000 (these were discarded); and the inference proceeds from the final 50,000 draws, which were used to obtain preference part-worths. Tables 2 and 3 list estimated part-worths for each level, and the average relative importance for each attribute. Cubic spline interpolation allows the estimation of continuous preference functions from the discrete part-worths used in the study (see Michalek et al. Reference Michalek, Ebbes, Adigüzel, Feinberg and Papalambros2011). Lastly, the profit values are calculated using the means of the market response distribution based on the preference parameters of these 152 customers.

The conjoint survey was supplemented by follow-up questions aimed at assessing eventual service demand, e.g., ‘Suppose you buy a new tablet now. How long do you intend to use it?’ and ‘Suppose you use the eBook service, how often are you likely to purchase eBooks?’ The mean and standard deviation of the period of product ownership were 4.4 years and 2.7 years, respectively; analogous values for the frequency of eBook purchase were 19.2 and 15.8 books per year, respectively. These data were used in calculating individual-level service demand.Footnote 1 Recall that the price data of 20 eBooks were used (Gilbert Reference Gilbert2012), some of which were the same across the four markets, while others differed. Average prices were used for optimization purposes.

Since tablets are multi-purpose products, estimating the market ‘share’ and size for tablets among eBook users is challenging. Summary statistics can provide benchmarks: 457 million eBooks were sold in 2012 (Wilson Reference Wilson2014), 25% of the eBooks are read on tablets (BWMBooks 2012), and the average number of eBooks read (among those who read electronically) is 24 books per year (Rainie Reference Rainie, Zickuhr, Purcell, Madden and Brenner2012). Based on this data, a rough estimate of the projected tablet demand used for eReading is 4.76M (i.e., $457\text{M}\times 25\%/24$ ). Because this is an input figure that ‘scales linearly’ within the model, improved estimates of the market size can be easily included in the methodology.

4.3 Cost and optimization modeling

To put our method to use, producers must build their own costing models. To this end, prior studies of tablet cost modeling are adapted (Wang, Kannan & Azarm Reference Wang, Kannan and Azarm2011) focusing on display and memory storage costs:

(19) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle C_{d_{j}}=C_{d_{0}}q_{d_{j}}^{b_{1}}z_{d_{j}}^{b_{2}} & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$
(20) $$\begin{eqnarray}\displaystyle & \displaystyle C_{m_{j}}=C_{m_{0}}z_{m_{j}} & \displaystyle\end{eqnarray}$$

where $C_{d_{j}}$ is the cost of LCD display $j$ , $C_{d_{0}}$ is $50 (of variable cost, used as a basis value), $q_{d_{j}}$ is overall demand for displays, $z_{d_{j}}$ is display size in inches, $b_{1}$ and $b_{2}$ are parameters (estimated in prior work at $-$ 0.1032 and 0.7965, respectively), $C_{m_{j}}$ is cost of flash memory $j$ , $C_{m_{0}}$ is $4 (of variable cost), and $z_{m_{j}}$ is memory size in Gigabytes (GB); any of these values can be updated as newer information becomes available. Display costs follow economies of scale, although here other costs are considered to be constant with respect to demand/production, including costs for batteries, integrated circuits, and ‘miscellaneous,’ which are assumed to be $115 in total (as per Wang et al. Reference Wang, Kannan and Azarm2011). EBook prices can themselves be broken down into margins, royalty fees, taxes, and delivery costs. Since royalty fees make up the majority of an eBook’s price (Amazon 2012b ), only the royalty fee is considered as the cost of eBook service provision, and the iBooks’ royalty rate, 70% is used (Mill City Press 2012).

4.3.1 Decision variables and optimization

Figure 2 is referred to again for an overview of the nature of the decision space and overall optimization strategy. Optimization can be achieved in various ways, and the general procedure is agnostic, to what is used. However, the procedure described below has the virtue of scaling well in the number of PS-producing firms. At its center, is an iterative process that checks whether equilibrium conditions are met at every pass. In broad schematic, at every pass, each of the four producers must enact two types of Yes/No decisions: (1) on each of the services for the other three producers (they must always offer their own service); and (2) on whether to offer its service on the other three platforms. This entails eight options which enable other services to be allowed on its product, and eight options which enable products to carry the producer’s own services. These total 64, in all. To choose among these 64 options – each of which requires that all other design elements are optimized – each of the four producers optimizes (as detailed subsequently). After all the four producers have done this, equilibrium conditions are checked; if they are not met, iteration continues. [As mentioned above, it is also possible to perform a one-shot optimization for all $(64)^{4}=16777216$ ensuing possibilities, but this number grows exponentially in the number of producers – with $k$ producers, there $2^{2k(k-1)}$ possibilities – and is prone to local maxima.]

The decision variables are the PS channels ( $z_{1},\ldots ,z_{16}=0$ or 1), tablet price ($129⩽z 17⩽$499), display size ( $7\leqslant z_{18}\leqslant 10$ ), memory storage size $(8\leqslant z_{19}\leqslant 128)$ , and eBook price change (-$2⩽z 20⩽ +$ 2). The PS channel decisions are binary decision variables. Because there are four products and four services, the PS channel matrix, as mentioned previously, is 4 by 4, so the space of possible channel combinations has the size $2^{(4\times 4)}=65,536$ . However, some of these are impermissible: the PS channels between the same producers (i.e., on the diagonal) must be set to 1, and a producer can control only its channels so that each producer has possible PS channel options of $2^{6}=64$ . Procedurally, as depicted in Figure 2, each producer optimizes its decision sequentially so that the tablet brand and the eBook market brand are optimized in order. As discussed earlier, in terms of PS channel acceptance between competitors, removing a PS channel does not require the other party’s agreement, while adding a PS channel is possible only when neither player’s profits are harmed. Profit optimization is achieved subject to this PS channel constraint in addition to the tablet and eBook design boundary constraints.

For the equilibrium calculation, optimization is carried out sequentially; this is repeated until the optimal design decisions of all producers have converged, and profit cannot be enhanced by further changes. Previous producers’ (optimal) decisions are used for the next producer’s optimization, as parameters of the demand model. Because product features cannot be changed frequently, it is assumed that producers first decide on all decision variables, including product attributes, and secondarily decide on only product/service prices and channels.

The study compares six different scenarios varying in the type of channel and optimization orders as shown in Table 4. The first and last scenarios are used as the baseline to compare with optimal channel scenario. Since there could be a first mover advantage in the game, four optimal channel scenarios are set (S1, S2, S3, and S4) with different sequential optimization orders.

Table 4. Sequential optimization scenarios

An exclusive channel scenario is the case where there is no channel among competitors, and a non-exclusive symmetric channel scenario is the case where all competitors are fully connected through channels, as explained in Section 3.2. These two scenarios fix channels, and then optimize other decision variables in order to compare them with the scenarios that find optimal channels. In the pilot test, when channels are not decision variables, the sequential optimization order does not affect the results significantly. Therefore, the exclusive channel and non-exclusive symmetric channel scenarios use the same optimization order as S1. Optimal channel scenarios are the cases that optimize all decision variables including channels at the same time. There are 24 cases when four producers make decisions sequentially, but four cases were selected where each producer can experience all orders in balance.

Since the design problem is a mixed-integer optimization one due to discrete channel decisions, all possible channel configurations are examined and the continuous decision variables are optimized for each channel configuration on every optimization pass. The profit optimization problem was solved via SQP (sequential quadratic programming), implemented in MATLAB (MathWorks 2017). Since there are 64 possible PS channel configurations for four producers, enumeration with deterministic algorithms was possible. However, if there are many producers in the market, heuristic optimization algorithms will likely be necessary.

Owing to high computational costs for performing optimization and validation at the individual level, mean part-worths were calculated and used as inputs to optimization; for validation, the demand was computed at the individual level and then averaged as in Eq. (3). Thus, heterogeneity measured via the HB conjoint model formulation was accounted for at the validation stage, and all reported metrics thereby accommodate it.

5 Discussion: optimization results and implications

The six scenarios in Table 4 were optimized with the initial values shown in Table 1. Figure 3 shows optimal results including the PS channel and product/service attributes of each producer. All results converged to equilibrium. In Figure 3, the red lines indicate inclusive channels between competitors.

Figure 3. Optimal design decisions for six scenarios.

For Amazon, in the optimal channel-S1 scenario, the Kindle’s optimal price, display size, and storage are $240, $10^{\prime \prime }$ , and 19.9GB, respectively; the optimal eBook price (for Amazon) is $11.78; and the optimal channel arrangement is for Kindle users to be able to use iBooks, while Amazon supplies eBooks to Kindle-only users. In the optimal channel-S3 scenario, the optimal channel converged to the exclusive channel, although the channel decisions are optimized.

Figure 4 shows how the optimal profit of each producer (optimal channel-S1 scenario) changed and converged over the iteration history, where the $x$ -axis indicates iteration, and $y$ -axis, profit (in dollars). Figure 5 shows the results from each producer’s (optimal) channel decisions at that iteration, where 1 indicates that a channel is connected, and 0 indicates that a channel is unconnected in the $y$ -axis. After the 21st iteration, all producers apparently converge indicating that no design change can entail more profits for any of them.

Figure 4. Convergence of sequential profit maximization for optimal channel-S1 scenario.

Figure 5. Convergence of channel decisions for optimal channel-S1 scenario.

Figure 6(a) shows the achieved overall profits (product $+$ service profits) for each of the producers in the six scenarios. Figure 6(b) shows the product and service profits separately because most product profits are negative. This result shows that most producers sell low-priced products while sacrificing product profits but make up for the loss through service profits, securing service users. Kang et al. (Reference Kang, Feinberg and Papalambros2013) showed similar results; besides, it is known that Amazon uses the same strategy (Love Reference Love2011; Clay Reference Clay2012). Lastly, Figure 7 shows the optimal prices of tablets and eBooks for the six scenarios, and Table 5 shows the eBook demand for each tablet under different channel scenarios.

Figure 6. Profits for six scenarios.

Figure 7. Optimal price decisions for six scenarios.

Table 5. eBook service usage for each tablet

Bold indicates eBook service demand of competitors’ tablets.

Main insights from the optimization results above are discussed as follows.

First, the decision order affects an equilibrium point when the channel is variable, but the first mover advantage is not guaranteed. In Figure 3, optimal channel results (S1, S2, S3, and S4) show that the optimal decisions converge at different equilibrium points depending on the decision order. One reason is that the channel decisions are affected by previous channel structures because they are required to get permission from competitors when they want to change channels. In our game, it is shown that the first mover advantage is not guaranteed. In Figure 6, Amazon, B&N, Apple, and Google get the highest profits when they are the first mover (S1), third mover (S2), third mover (S1), and third mover (S4), respectively.

Second, the difference in brand power stimulates larger profit differentials when the channel is variable. In Figure 6, optimal channel scenarios have large profit differentials among producers, while fixed channel scenarios such as exclusive channels and non-exclusive symmetric channels have comparably small profit differentials among producers. The reason is that, when producers with high brand power (brand preference) such as Amazon (eBook market) and iPad (tablet) have a choice of channel, they can utilize competitors’ products/services effectively by controlling channels (see Tables 2 and 3 for brand preference).

Third, a product with high brand power pursues an inclusive channel, while a service with high brand power pursues an exclusive channel. Amazon, with the highest brand power yields the highest profits in all scenarios. In all optimal channel scenarios, Amazon sells eBooks only to Kindle – the only ‘exclusive arrangement’ obtained – whereas the others sell to their competitors. The main distinction in the results is therefore between Amazon/Kindle and the other three: Amazon/Kindle pursues a highly inclusive strategy by which eBooks are allowed on its platform (Kindle), but a highly exclusive one in terms of whom they will sell their eBooks to, i.e., only themselves. Whether this can be generalized to other market settings is a matter of speculation, but it can be rigorously examined using the methods developed here.

Fourth, service has a lower price in the more inclusive channels. In Figure 7(b), a non-exclusive symmetric channel has much lower eBook prices than an exclusive channel. When comparing optimal channel scenarios, relatively inclusive channels (S2, S4) have lower eBook prices than relatively exclusive channels (S1, S3). The results demonstrate that inclusive channels promote competition and reduce service price. On the other hand, the analysis of tablet prices shows that a non-exclusive symmetric channel has a higher tablet price than an exclusive channel. In optimal channel scenarios, relatively inclusive channels (S2, S4) have higher tablet prices than relatively exclusive channels (S1, S3). This is because when the channel is inclusive, customers can use more services through the tablet, so the tablet’s value increases.

Fifth, the proposed framework helps decide which competitors the focal firm should cooperate with. From the results, it is shown that cooperation between Kindle and iBooks is necessary. In Figure 3, the channel between Kindle and iBooks appears in the optimal decision of most scenarios such as S1, S2, and S3. This demonstrates that this cooperation is positive for both Amazon and Apple’s profits. On the other hand, the results show that cooperation between Amazon–Google, and Apple–B&N may not be attractive, as they are never seen to cooperate in the optimal results.

Sixth, the proposed framework helps analyze the customer inflow between products and services. The proposed demand model determines where the service users (and profits) ‘come from.’ In optimal channel-S1 scenario of Table 5, since iBooks supplies eBooks not only to iPad, but also to Kindle, 29% of iBooks users come from Kindle. In a non-exclusive symmetric channel, only 42% of B&N users come from Nook users, and the other 58% of B&N users come from competitors’ tablets.

Lastly, there exist multiple equilibrium points, but the majority of the optimization results converge to one equilibrium point. Since channel structures are listed and other variables for each channel structure are optimized, channel decisions do not affect optimality. Thus, one needs to check whether other decision variables converge to a social trap which is a low-level equilibrium point inferior to another equilibrium point in that it yields lower levels of profit for all the players. In the proposed framework, optimization was carried out sequentially, i.e., the previous iteration’s optimal results were used as the initial values for the next iteration. Random initial values are generated in each iteration and sequential optimization is conducted. In the non-exclusive symmetric channel scenario, 100 optimization runs are tested, and Figure 8 shows the histogram of profit results for these runs. Approximately 60% of the tests converge with the same profits as those computed under the proposed framework. These results show that depending on initial values, it is possible to reach a social trap that yields lower overall profits, and the designer should check whether the equilibrium point is indeed a social trap or not.

Figure 8. Equilibrium points for the non-exclusive symmetric channel scenario.

Although a variety of other factors (such as procurement and contractual costs, maintaining an adequate variety of titles, offline sales of physical books, etc.) would need to be incorporated for a complete analysis of these four publishers, it is nonetheless recommended that they do not settle on identical (that is, symmetric) service channel arrangements at equilibrium, reflecting upon the differences in the firms’ input values into the PS channel optimization problem. One must underscore the various assumptions made to restrict attention to the focal variables (e.g., the lack of black-and-white tablets), which dictate that the results should be extrapolated with caution to the actual market for these four producers. However, the simulation results suggest that the proposed model yields results with reasonable face validity, and can help decision makers understand market behavior and, via market simulation, the anticipated effects of changes in both product/service attribute values, and contractual channel structures.

6 Conclusion: implications, limitations, and future research

Over the last decade, an increasing number of products have become more than the sum of their parts, capable of availing of an array of services provided by the products’ producers as well as their rivals. When a consumer chooses a cell phone, for example, she or he must envision which apps it can run, and therefore understand the degree of choice and competition in that related, service-based marketplace. Traditional demand models, primarily from marketing, operations, and engineering design, can decompose both the service and product decisions and help optimize them separately. Difficulties arise, however, when these decisions are conjoined and necessarily dependent with product choice preceding service access.

This paper has proposed a modeling framework to support complex decision-making in PS channels. The framework is designed to optimize several disparate, but interacting elements – the PS channels, product prices, product attributes, service prices, and service attributes – jointly, using the objective of overall service and product profits. Notably, it does so for three distinct multi-channel structures: exclusive, non-exclusive asymmetric, and non-exclusive symmetric. Such a framework helps producers understand how PS channel decisions affect not only their own customer demand and profit patterns, but also those of other market players. An extensive simulation and optimization study, using summary market information (e.g., prices), and conjoint choice data for both tablets and eBooks, illustrated how the model can be used for a real product category, and how channel structures affect demands and profit levels for a producer’s products and related services.

The proposed framework is expected to be used for PS design planning in a company that supplies products and the associated services. The optimization results for the tablet and eBook market provide some insights to early stage design as follows:

First, a decision order affects an equilibrium point when the channel is variable, but the first mover advantage is not guaranteed. A designer does not need to rush to make a decision, but has to watch other competitors’ channel decisions in the market closely. Second, a difference in brand power stimulates larger profit differentials when the channel is variable. If the focal company has higher brand power than its competitors, a designer should utilize competitors’ products/services actively by varying the channel. Third, a product with high brand power pursues an inclusive channel, while a service with high brand power pursues an exclusive channel. A designer should examine the brand power of product and service respectively, and make different channel strategies for the product and service. Fourth, service has the lower price in the more inclusive channels. A designer should balance between service price and product price according to the channel. Fifth, the computed results help decide which competitors the focal firm should cooperate with. Before deciding on the product/service attribute specifications at an early design stage, a designer should try to negotiate with competitors that complement the product/service, and then decide on specifications based on the cooperation results. Sixth, similarly, the computed results help analyze customer inflows between products and services. A designer should observe closely customer inflows from competitors’ products, and reinforce the positive channels.

We view the proposed framework as evolutionary building firmly on widely used techniques in marketing, design, and operations. The novel feature of the framework is to integrate techniques developed in cognate literatures: First, the demand model accommodates the actual, sequential nature of the choice of product and multiple associated services; previous customer choice research focused on a single choice of product or PS bundle. Second, the PS channel structure was accommodated via decision variables instead of predetermined parameters; previous distribution channel research in this area largely examined price optimization under a given channel structure. Lastly – and it is believed this is a methodological innovation with the potential for broad application – the proposed framework considers competitors’ profit changes as (non-negativity) constraints, owing to the fact that PS channels are shared decisions requiring acceptance from both product producers and service providers.

Future work can test this framework in different product classes and contractual contexts to determine its general applicability and robustness for different PSS. The framework can be extended to product or service family design, although this would require detailed knowledge of consumer preference heterogeneity and cost-sharing models, using firms’ internal production data.

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by a National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF) grant funded by the Korean government (NRF-2017R1C1B2005266).

Footnotes

1 Individual service demand can be calculated by eliminating $I^{-1}\sum _{i=1}^{I}$ from Eq. (6), so the sum is only over the $\mathbf{T}_{i}$ observations for individual $i$ . For example, if individual $i$ purchases 19 eBooks per year, and she or he uses a tablet for 3 years, $\mathbf{T}_{i}=19\times 3=57$ .

References

Amazon.2012a Amazon mechanical Turk. http://www.mturk.com.Google Scholar
Amazon.2012b Kindle direct publishing. http://kdp.amazon.com/self-publishing.Google Scholar
Anderson, C. 2009 Free: The Future of a Radical Price. Random House.Google Scholar
Aribarg, A. & Foutz, N. Z. 2009 Category-based screening in choice of complementary products. Journal of Marketing Research 46 (4), 518530.Google Scholar
Baines, T., Lightfoot, H., Peppard, J., Johnson, M., Tiwari, A., Shehab, E. & Swink, M. 2009 Towards an operations strategy for product-centric servitization. International Journal of Operations & Production Management 29 (5), 494519.Google Scholar
Baines, T. S., Lightfoot, H., Steve, E., Neely, A., Greenough, R., Peppard, J., Roy, R., Shehab, E., Braganza, A., Tiwari, A., Alcock, J., Angus, J., Bastl, M., Cousens, A., Irving, P., Johnson, M., Kingston, J., Lockett, H., Martinez, V., Michele, P., Tranfield, D., Walton, I. & Wilson, H. 2007 State-of-the-art in product-service systems. Proceedings of the Institution of Mechanical Engineers, Part B: Journal of Engineering Manufacture 221 (10), 15431552.Google Scholar
Barczak, G, Griffin, A. & Kahn, K. B. 2009 Perspective: trends and drivers of success in NPD practices: results of the 2003 PDMA best practices study. Journal of Product Innovation Management 26 (1), 323.Google Scholar
Beuren, F. H., Ferreira, M. G. G. & Miguel, P. A. C. 2013 Product-service systems: a literature review on integrated products and services. Journal of Cleaner Production 47 (May), 222231.Google Scholar
Bläsi, C. & Rothlauf, F.2013 On the interoperability of eBook formats. Report for European Booksellers Federation, EU Commissioner for the Digital Agenda, April.Google Scholar
Brady, T., Davies, A. & Hobday, M. 2006 Charting a path toward integrated solutions. MIT Sloan Management Review 47 (3), 3948.Google Scholar
BWMBooks.2012 eBook market 2012. http://www.bwmbooks.com.Google Scholar
Cai, G., Dai, Y. & Zhou, S. X. 2012 Exclusive channels and revenue sharing in a complementary goods market. Marketing Science 31 (1), 172187.Google Scholar
Casadesus-Masanell, R. & Llanes, G. 2011 Mixed source. Management Science 57 (7), 12121230.Google Scholar
Census.2012 Age and sex composition in the United Sates: 2012. Tech. rep., US Census Bureau.Google Scholar
Cohen, M. A. & Whang, S. 1997 Competing in service and product: a product life-cycle model. Management Science 43 (4), 535545.Google Scholar
Easton, F. F. & Pullman, M. E. 2001 Optimizing service attributes: The seller’s utility problem. Decision Sciences 32 (2), 251276.Google Scholar
Frischknecht, B. D., Whitefoot, K. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2010 On the suitability of econometric demand models in design for market systems. Journal of Mechanical Design 132 (12), 121007.Google Scholar
Gilbert, J.2012 Where to buy the cheapest eBooks: Amazon vs. iBooks vs. Google Play vs. Barnes & Noble. Huffington Post, 17 October.Google Scholar
Goedkoop, M. J., van Halen, C. J. G., te Riele, H. R. M. & Rommens, P. J. M.1999 Product service systems, ecological and economic basics. Tech. rep., Report for Dutch Ministries of Environment (VROM) and Economic Affairs (EZ).Google Scholar
Green, P. E., Krieger, A. M. & Wind, Y. 2001 Thirty years of conjoint analysis: Reflections and prospects. Interfaces 31 (3 supplement), S56S73.Google Scholar
Green, P. E. & Krieger, A. M. 1991 Product design strategies for target-market positioning. Journal of Product Innovation Management 8 (3), 189202.Google Scholar
Green, P. E. & Krieger, A. M. 1996 Individualized hybrid models for conjoint analysis. Management Science 42 (6), 850867.Google Scholar
Gustafsson, A., Herrmann, A. & Huber, F. 2013 Conjoint Measurement: Methods and Applications. Springer Science & Business Media.Google Scholar
Hudson, C., Fudge, C. & Rae, J. 2011 From products to services: Understanding the new rules of engagement. Design Management Review 22 (4), 4653.Google Scholar
Jeuland, A. P. & Shugan, S. M. 1983 Managing channel profits. Marketing Science 2 (3), 239272.Google Scholar
Jun, G. T., Ward, J. R. & Clarkson, P. J. 2010 Systems modelling approaches to the design of safe healthcare delivery. Ergonomics 53 (7), 829847.Google Scholar
Kang, N., Feinberg, F. M. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2013 A framework for enterprise-driven product service systems design. In Proceedings of the 19th International Conference on Engineering Design, Seoul, Korea, Aug 4–Aug 7, The Design Society.Google Scholar
Kang, N.2014 Multidomain demand modeling in design for market systems. Ph.D. thesis, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI.Google Scholar
Kang, N., Feinberg, F. M. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2015 Integrated decision making in electric vehicle and charging station location network design. Journal of Mechanical Design 137 (6), 061402.Google Scholar
Kang, N., Ren, Y., Feinberg, F. M. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2016 Public investment and electric vehicle design: A model-based market analysis framework with application to a USA-China comparison study. Design Science 2, e6.Google Scholar
Kang, N., Feinberg, F. M. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2017 Autonomous electric vehicle sharing system design. Journal of Mechanical Design 139 (1), 011402.Google Scholar
Kang, N., Bayrak, A. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2018 Robustness and real options for vehicle design and investment decisions under gas price and regulatory uncertainties. Journal of Mechanical Design 140 (10), 101404.Google Scholar
Lee, E. & Staelin, R. 1997 Vertical strategic interaction: Implications for channel pricing strategy. Marketing Science 16 (3), 185207.Google Scholar
Lee, J. 2002 A key to marketing financial services: The right mix of products, services, channels, and customers. Journal of Services Marketing 16 (3), 238258.Google Scholar
Lee, U., Kang, N. & Lee, I. 2019 Selection of optimal target reliability in RBDO through reliability-based design for market systems (RBDMS) and application to electric vehicle design. Structural and Multidisciplinary Optimization 115; doi:10.1007/s00158-019-02245-3.Google Scholar
Lewis, K. E., Chen, W. & Schmidt, L. C. 2006 Decision Making in Engineering Design. ASME Press.Google Scholar
Love, D.2011 Amazon loses at least $5 to sell you a Kindle, Business Insider. http://www.businessinsider.com/kindle-manufacturing-cost-2011-11.Google Scholar
Luo, L., Kannan, P. K. & Ratchford, B. T. 2007 New product development under channel acceptance. Marketing Science 26 (2), 149163.Google Scholar
McGuire, T. W. & Staelin, R. 1983 An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Marketing Science 2 (2), 161191.Google Scholar
Michalek, J. J., Papalambros, P. Y. & Skerlos, S. J. 2004 A study of fuel efficiency and emission policy impact on optimal vehicle design decisions. Journal of Mechanical Design 126 (6), 10621070.Google Scholar
Michalek, J. J., Feinberg, F. M. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2005 Linking marketing and engineering product design decisions via analytical target cascading. Journal of Product Innovation Management 22 (1), 4262.Google Scholar
Michalek, J. J., Ebbes, P., Adigüzel, F., Feinberg, F. M. & Papalambros, P. Y. 2011 Enhancing marketing with engineering: Optimal product line design for heterogeneous markets. International Journal of Research in Marketing 28 (1), 112.Google Scholar
Mill City Press.2012 Setting an eBook price & understanding eBook royalties. http://www.millcitypress.net.Google Scholar
Mont, O. K. 2002 Clarifying the concept of product-service system. Journal of Cleaner Production 10 (3), 237245.Google Scholar
Moore, W. L., Louviere, J. J. & Verma, R. 1999 Using conjoint analysis to help design product platforms. Journal of Product Innovation Management 16 (1), 2739.Google Scholar
Nash, J. F. 1950 Equilibrium points in n-person games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 36 (1), 4849.Google Scholar
Nash, J. 1951 Non-cooperative games. Annals of Mathematics 54 (2), 286295.Google Scholar
Orme, B.2013 The CBC system for choice-based conjoint analysis. Technical Paper Series. Sawtooth Software.Google Scholar
Pullman, M. E. & Moore, W. L. 1999 Optimal service design: Integrating marketing and operations perspectives. International Journal of Service Industry Management 10 (2), 239261.Google Scholar
Rainie, L., Zickuhr, K., Purcell, K., Madden, M. & Brenner, J.2012 The rise of e-reading. Technical report, Pew Research Center’s Internet & American Life Project. http://libraries.pewinternet.org/2012/04/04/the-rise-of-e-reading.Google Scholar
Reim, W., Parida, V. & Örtqvist, D. 2015 Product–service systems (PSS) business models and tactics–a systematic literature review. Journal of Cleaner Production 97 (June), 6175.Google Scholar
Ritala, P., Golnam, A. & Wegmann, A. 2014 Coopetition-based business models: The case of Amazon.com. Industrial Marketing Management 43 (2), 236249.Google Scholar
Rossi, P. E. & Allenby, G. M. 2003 Bayesian statistics and marketing. Marketing Science 22 (3), 304328.Google Scholar
Roy, R. & Baxter, D. 2009 Product-service systems. Journal of Engineering Design 20 (4), 327328.Google Scholar
Sadeghi, A. & Zandieh, M. 2011 A game theory-based model for product portfolio management in a competitive market. Expert Systems with Applications 38 (7), 79197923.Google Scholar
Sakao, T. & Lindahl, M. 2009 Introduction to Product/Service-System Design. Springer, London.Google Scholar
Sakao, T. & Shimomura, Y. 2007 Service Engineering: a novel engineering discipline for producers to increase value combining service and product. Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (6), 590604.Google Scholar
Shiau, C. N. & Michalek, J. J. 2009a Should designers worry about market systems? Journal of Mechanical Design 131 (1), 011011.Google Scholar
Shiau, C. N. & Michalek, J. J. 2009b Optimal product design under price competition. Journal of Mechanical Design 131 (7), 071003.Google Scholar
Smith, D. J. 2013 Power-by-the-hour: The role of technology in reshaping business strategy at Rolls-Royce. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management 25 (8), 9871007.Google Scholar
Sudhir, K. 2001 Structural analysis of manufacturer pricing in the presence of a strategic retailer. Marketing Science 20 (3), 244264.Google Scholar
Sundin, E. & Bras, B. 2005 Making functional sales environmentally and economically beneficial through product remanufacturing. Journal of Cleaner Production 13 (9), 913925.Google Scholar
Thornton, J. & White, L. 2001 Customer orientations and usage of financial distribution channels. Journal of Services Marketing 15 (3), 168185.Google Scholar
Vasantha, G. V. A., Roy, R., Lelah, A. & Brissaud, D. 2012 A review of product-service systems design methodologies. Journal of Engineering Design 23 (9), 635659.Google Scholar
Verma, R., Thompson, G. M., Moore, W. L. & Louviere, J. J. 2001 Effective design of products/services: An approach based on integration of marketing and operations management decisions. Decision Sciences 32 (1), 165194.Google Scholar
Wang, Z., Kannan, P. K. & Azarm, S. 2011 Customer-driven optimal design for convergence products. Journal of Mechanical Design 133 (10), 101010.Google Scholar
Williams, N., Azarm, S. & Kannan, P. K. 2008 Engineering product design optimization for retail channel acceptance. Journal of Mechanical Design 130 (6), 061402.Google Scholar
Wilson, T. D. 2014 The E-Book phenomenon: A disruptive technology. Information Research: An International Electronic Journal 19 (2), n2.Google Scholar
Zhang, S., Lee, C. K. M., Wu, K. & Choy, K. L. 2016 Multi-objective optimization for sustainable supply chain network design considering multiple distribution channels. Expert Systems with Applications 65, 8799.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Examples of market settings.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Profit maximization framework for PS design.

Figure 2

Table 1. Market setting for eBook / tablet applications

Figure 3

Table 2. Part-worths for tablet attribute levels

Figure 4

Table 3. Part-worths for eBook attribute levels

Figure 5

Table 4. Sequential optimization scenarios

Figure 6

Figure 3. Optimal design decisions for six scenarios.

Figure 7

Figure 4. Convergence of sequential profit maximization for optimal channel-S1 scenario.

Figure 8

Figure 5. Convergence of channel decisions for optimal channel-S1 scenario.

Figure 9

Figure 6. Profits for six scenarios.

Figure 10

Figure 7. Optimal price decisions for six scenarios.

Figure 11

Table 5. eBook service usage for each tablet

Figure 12

Figure 8. Equilibrium points for the non-exclusive symmetric channel scenario.