Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vpsfw Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-21T07:22:21.301Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Embodied technological progress, heterogeneous multiworker firms, and unemployment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 April 2024

Kosho Tanaka*
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics, Kanazawa Seiryo University, Kanazawa, Ishikawa, Japan

Abstract

This paper studies the impact of technological progress on unemployment in a search-matching model with heterogeneous multiworker firms. In the model, some firms continue to reap rewards from new technologies over time and contribute to job creation, while other firms obsolesce and reduce their employment. Thus, the model captures an endogenous change in the aggregate composition of firms (the firm-composition effect). Considering this effect along with the two canonical effects—the capitalization and creative-destruction effects—I examine the importance of each through a simulation. The results show that the firm-composition effect explains almost all the variation in unemployment in the model, mainly through shrinking the number of obsolescing firms relative to surviving firms and increasing the aggregate technology adoption rate when technology progresses rapidly.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Hawkins, W. B.. (2014) Search with multi-worker firms. Theoretical Economics 9, 583628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P.. (1994) Growth and unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 61, 477494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aguiar, M., Bils, M., Charles, K. K. and Hurst, E.. (2021) Leisure luxuries and the labor supply of young men. Journal of Political Economy 129, 337382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aguiar, M. and Hurst, E.. (2008) The Increase in Leisure Inequality. NBER Working Paper: No. 13837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axtell, R. L. (2001) Zipf distribution of US firm sizes. Science 293(5536), 18181820.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Benmelech, E. and Bergman, N. K.. (2011) Vintage capital and creditor protection. Journal of Financial Economics 99, 308332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertola, G. and Garibaldi, P.. (2001) Wages and the size of firms in dynamic matching models. Review of Economic Dynamics 4, 335368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O. (2006) European unemployment: The evolution of facts and ideas. Economic Policy 21, 659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Giavazzi, F.. (2003) Macroeconomic effects of regulation and deregulation in goods and labor markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 879907.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Wolfers, J.. (2000) The role of shocks and institutions in the rise of European unemployment: The aggregate evidence. Economic Journal 110, 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brynjolfsson, E. and Hitt, L. M.. (2000) Beyond computation: Information technology, organizational transformation and business performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, 2348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christopoulou, R. and Vermeulen, P.. (2012) Markups in the Euro area and the US over the period 1981–2004: A comparison of 50 sectors. Empirical Economics 42, 5377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cummins, J. G. and Violante, G. L.. (2002) Investment-specific technical change in the United States (1947–2000): Measurement and macroeconomic consequences. Review of Economic Dynamics 5, 243284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Loecker, J., Eeckhout, J. and Unger, G.. (2020) The rise of market power and the macroeconomic implications. Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, 561644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ebell, M. and Haefke, C.. (2009) Product market deregulation and the US employment miracle. Review of Economic Dynamics 12, 479504.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, Z., Setty, O. and Weiss, D.. (2019) Financial risk and unemployment. International Economic Review 60(2), 475516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elsby, M. W., Hobijn, B. and Şahin, A.. (2013) Unemployment dynamics in the OECD. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 530548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elsby, M. W. and Michaels, R.. (2013) Marginal jobs, heterogeneous firms, and unemployment flows. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5(1), 148.Google Scholar
Felbermayr, G. and Prat, J.. (2011) Product market regulation, firm selection, and unemployment. Journal of European Economic Association 9(2), 278317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, R. J. and Sayed, H.. (2020) Transatlantic technologies: The role of ICT in the evolution of productivity growth in the U.S. and Europe. International Productivity Monitor 38, 5080.Google Scholar
Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z. and Krusell, P.. (1997) Long-run implications of investment-specific technological change. American Economic Review 87, 342362.Google Scholar
Greenwood, J. and Yorukoglu, M.. (1997, 1974) Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 46, pp. 4995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E. (2017) High discounts and high unemployment. American Economic Review 107(2), 305330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E. and Milgrom, P. R.. (2008) The limited influence of unemployment on the wage bargain. American Economic Review 98(4), 16531674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hornstein, A., Krusell, P. and Violante, G. L.. (2007) Technology—policy interaction in frictional labour-markets. Review of Economic Studies 74(4), 10891124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jorgenson, D. W. and Stiroh, K. J.. (2000) US economic growth in the new millennium. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 125211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luttmer, E. G. (2007) Selection, growth, and the size distribution of firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(3), 11031144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melitz, M. J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 16951725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michau, J. B. (2013) Creative destruction with on-the-job search. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(4), 691707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miyamoto, H. and Takahashi, Y.. (2011) Productivity growth, on-the-job search, and unemployment. Journal of Monetary Economics 58(6-8), 666680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mortensen, D. T. and Pissarides, C. A.. (1998) Technological progress, job creation, and job destruction. Review of Economic Dynamics 1(4), 733753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nickell, S., Nunziata, L., Ochel, W. and Quintini, G.. (2003) The Beveridge Curve, unemployment and wages in the OECD from the, 1960s, to the 1990s. In: Nickell, S., Nunziata, L., Ochel, W. and Quintini, G.. (eds.), Information, and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In Honor of Edmund S. Phelps, pp. 394431. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Oliner, S. D. and Sichel, D. E.. (2000) The resurgence of growth in the late 1990s: Is information technology the story? Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(4), 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petrongolo, B. and Pissarides, C. A.. (2001) Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function. Journal of Economic Literature 39(2), 390431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petrosky-Nadeau, N. and Wasmer, E.. (2013) The cyclical volatility of labor markets under frictional financial markets. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5(1), 193221.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. A. (2009) The unemployment volatility puzzle: Is wage stickiness the answer? Econometrica 77(5), 13391369.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. A. and Vallanti, G.. (2007) The impact of TFP growth on steady-state unemployment. International Economic Review 48(2), 607640.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shimer, R. (2005) The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies. American Economic Review 95(1), 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, E. (1999) Search, concave production, and optimal firm size. Review of Economic Dynamics 2(2), 456471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, R. (1987) We’d better watch out. New York Times Book Review, 36.Google Scholar
Stole, L. A. and Zwiebel, J.. (1996) Intra-firm bargaining under non-binding contracts. Review of Economic Studies 63(3), 375410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Timmer, M. P. and van Ark, B.. (2005) Does information and communication technology drive EU-US productivity growth differentials? Oxford Economic Papers 57(4), 693716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whelan, K. (2000) Computers, Obsolescence, and Productivity. Federal Reserve Board, Finance and Economics Discussion Series Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar