Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-01T00:29:54.920Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Sonja M. Amadae, Prisoners of Reason: Game Theory and Neoliberal Political Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016), pp. xxxix + 333, $120.95 (hardcover). ISBN: 9781107064034.

Review products

Sonja M. Amadae, Prisoners of Reason: Game Theory and Neoliberal Political Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016), pp. xxxix + 333, $120.95 (hardcover). ISBN: 9781107064034.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 April 2019

David Levy*
Affiliation:
George Mason University

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Book Reviews
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Breit, William. 1987. “Creating the ‘Virginia School’: Charlottesville as an Academic Environment in the 1960s.” Economic Inquiry 25: 645657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1959. “Positive Economics, Welfare Economics, and Political Economy.” Journal of Law and Economics 2: 124138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1975. Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 2003. “Obituary: Justice among Natural Equals: Memorial Marker for John Rawls.” Public Choice 114:iii–v.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Rawls., John 2008. “The Buchanan–Rawls Correspondence.” In Peart, Sandra J. and Levy, David M., eds., The Street Porter and the Philosopher: Conversations on Analytical Egalitarianism. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 397416.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Yoon, Yong J., eds. 1994. Return to Increasing Returns. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, Francis Y. 1881. Mathematical Psychics. London: C. Kegan Paul. With Frank Knight’s annotations. In the author’s collection.Google Scholar
Filmer, Robert. 1680. Patriarcha, or the Natural Power of Kings. London: Richard Chiswell. http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/221#Filmer_0140_94. Accessed 27 December 2018.Google Scholar
Godwin, William. 1801. “Thoughts Occasioned by the Perusal. …London: Printed by Taylor and Wilks, Chancery-Lane. http://dwardmac.pitzer.edu/anarchist_archives/godwin/thoughtsonpar.html. Accessed 27 December 2018.Google Scholar
Levy, David M., and Peart, Sandra J.. Escape from Democracy. New York:Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics: An Introductory Volume. Eighth edition. London: Macmillian. http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/1676. Accessed 27 December 2018.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1865. “Romilly’s Public Responsibility and the Ballot.” Newspaper Writings. Volume 25 of The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill . Edited by Robson, Ann. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 474475. http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/259. Accessed 27 December 2018.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel C. 1981. “Economics and Political Economy.” American Economic Review 71: 110.Google Scholar
Sidney, Algernon. 1698. Discourses Concerning Government . Edited by West, Thomas G.. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/sidney-discourses-concerning-government. Accessed 27 December 2018.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. 1759. Theory of Moral Sentiments. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ulam, Stanislaw M. 1975. Adventures of a Mathematician. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar