Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T08:28:45.357Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ON THE ROLE OF VALUES IN ECONOMIC SCIENCE: ROBBINS AND HIS CRITICS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2009

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
A Symposium on The Nature and Significance of Economic Science by Lionel Robbins
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

American Economic Association, ed. 1961. Index of Economic Journal. Volume II: 1925–1939. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Aslanbeigui, N. 1990. “On the Demise of Pigovian Economics.” Southern Economic Journal 56: 616–627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, R. and Medema, S.. 2009. “Robbins’s Essay and the Axiomatization of Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought. 31 (4): 485–499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W. J. 1981. “Lionel Robbins, 1898–1984.” In Greenaway, D. and Presley, J. R., eds., Pioneers of Modern Economics in Britain. Vol. 2. New York: St. Martin's Press, pp. 11–23.Google Scholar
Benham, F. C. 1930. “Economic Welfare.” Economica 10: 173–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beveridge, W. 1960. The LSE and Its Problems, 1919–1937. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Blaug, M. 1992. The Methodology of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, M. 1996. Economic Theory in Retrospect. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Boulding, K. E. 1969. “Economics as a Moral Science.” American Economic Review 59 (1): 1–12.Google Scholar
Cannan, E. 1914. Wealth. London: P. S. King & Son, 1930.Google Scholar
Cannan, E. 1932. “Review of Robbins (1932),” Economic Journal 42: 424–427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chipman, J. S. and Moore, J. C. 1978. “The New Welfare Economics 1939–1974.” International Economic Review 19: 547–584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Churchman, C. W. 1956. “Science and Decision Making.” Philosophy of Science 33: 247–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, D. 2009. “What Was ‘It’ that Robbins Was Defining?Journal of the History of Economic Thought 31 (4): 437–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobb, M. 1969. Welfare Economics and the Economics of Socialism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Douglas, H. 2000. “Inductive Risk and Values in Science.” Philosophy of Science 67: 559–579.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Douglas, H. 2007. “Rejecting the Ideal of Value-Free Science.” In Kincaid, H., Dupre, J., and Wylie, A., eds., Value-Free Science? Ideas and Illusions. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 143–163.Google Scholar
Fraser, L. M. 1932. “How Do We Want Economists to Behave?Economic Journal 42: 555–570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraser, L. M. 1937. Economic Thought and Language. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Fraser, L. M. 1938. “Economists and Their Critics.” Economic Journal 48: 196–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. 1953. “Essay on the Methodology of Positive Economics.” In Essays on Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Greenaway, D. and Presley, J. R., eds. Pioneers of Modern Economics in Britain. Vol. 2. New York: St. Martin's Press.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. F. 1938. “Scope and Method of Economics.” Economic Journal 48: 383–412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. M. and McPherson, M. S. 1993. “Taking Ethics Seriously: Economics and Contemporary Moral Philosophy.” Journal of Economic Literature 31: 671–731.Google Scholar
Hawtrey, R. G. 1926. The Economic Problem. London: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Hempel, C. 1965. “Science and Human Values.” In Aspects of Scientific Explanation and Other Essays in the Philosophy of Science. New York: The Free Press, pp. 81–96.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1939. “The Foundations of Welfare Economics.” Economic Journal 49: 696–712. Reprinted in Hicks (1981), pp. 59–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1981. Wealth and Welfare: Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Vol. I. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hutchinson, W. K. 1976. History of Economic Analysis: A Guide to Information Sources. Detroit: Gale Research Company.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. 1938. The Significance and Basic Postulates of Economic Theory. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. 1964. “Positive” Economics and Policy Objectives. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Jeffrey, R. C. 1956. “Valuation and Acceptance of Scientific Hypotheses.” Philosophy of Science 33: 237–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jevons, S. 1871. The Theory of Political Economy. 5th edition. New York: Sentry Press. 1965.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1939. “Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility.” Economic Journal 49: 549–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kincaid, H., Dupré, J., and Wylie, A., eds. 2007. Value-Free Science? Ideas and Illusions. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 143–163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kociba, R., Keyes, D. G., Beyer, J. E., Carreon, R. M., Wade, C. E., Dittenber, D. A., Kanins, R. P., Frauson, L. E., Park, C. N., Barnard, S. D., Hummel, R. A., and Humiston, C. G. (1978), “Results of a Two-Year Chronic Toxicity and Oncogenicity Study of 2,3,7,8-Tetrachlorododibenzo-p-Dioxin in Rats.” Toxicology and Applied Pharmacology 46: 279–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, T. 1977. “Objectivity, Values and Theory Choice.” In The Essential Tension. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 320–339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laudan, L. 1984. Science and Values. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Levi, I. 1960. “Must the Scientist Qua Scientist Make Value Judgements?Journal of Philosophy 57: 345–357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, I. M. D. 1950. A Critique of Welfare Economics, 2nd edition. London: Oxford University Press. 1957.Google Scholar
Longino, H. E. 1990. Science as Social Knowledge. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lynn, F. M. 1986. “The Interplay of Science and Values in Assessing and Regulating Environmental Risks.” Science, Technology and Human Values 11: 40–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machamer, P. and Douglas, H. 1999. “Cognitive and Social Values.” Science and Education 8: 45–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machlup, F. 1978. Methodology of Economics and Other Social Sciences. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Masini, F. 2009. “Economics and Political Economy in Lionel Robbins's Writings.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 31 (4): 421–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, H. 1922. “Untersuchungen Zu Dem Grundgesetz Der Wirtschaftlichen Wertrechnung.” In Zeitschrift Fur Volkwirtschaft und Sozialpolitik, BD II.Google Scholar
McMullin, E. 1983. “Values in Science.” In Asquith, P. D. and Nickles, T., eds., Proceedings of the 1992 Biennial Meeting of the Philosophy of Science Association, Volume I. Philosophy of Science Association: East Lansing, pp. 3–28.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1844. Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy. London: J.W. Parker, Harrison.Google Scholar
Mishan, E. J. 1960. “A Survey of Welfare Economics, 1939–1959.” Economic Journal 278: 197–265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mongin, P. 2006. “Value Judgments and Value Neutrality in Economics.” Economica 73 (290): 257–286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myrdal, G. 1970. Objectivity in Social Science. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
Nath, S. K. 1969. A Reappraisal of Welfare Economics. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
O'Brien, D. P. 1988a. Lionel Robbins. New York: St. Martin's Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, D. P. 1988b. “Lionel Charles Robbins, 1898–1984.” Economic Journal 98: 104–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, T. 1934. “Some Reflections on ‘The Nature and Significance of Economics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 48: 511–545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peston, M. 1981. “Lionel Robbins: Methodology, Policy and Modern Theory.” In Shackleton, J. R. and Locksley, G., eds., Twelve Contemporary Economists. New York: John Wiley & Sons, pp. 183–198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peston, M. and Corry, B. 1972. Preface. In Peston, M. and Corry, B., eds., Essays in Honour of Lord Robbins. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. 4th edition. London: Macmillan. 1932.Google Scholar
Presley, J. R. 1981. “Sir John R. Hicks, 1904–.” In Greenaway, D. and Presley, J. R., pp. 96–119.Google Scholar
Rescher, N. 1969. Introduction to Value Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Inc.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1927. “Mr Hawtrey and the Scope of Economics.” Economica 7: 172–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. 1932 [1935] [1984]. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science 3rd edition. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1934. “Remarks on the Relationship Between Economics and Psychology.” Manchester School 5: 89–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. 1938a. “Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility: A Comment.” Economic Journal 48: 635–641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. 1938b. “Live and Dead Issues in the Methodology of Economics.” Economica 5: 342–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. 1959. “The Present Position of Economics.” In Henderson, E. and Spaventa, L., eds., Guest Lectures in Economics: Twenty Lectures Delivered in English at Professor G.U. Papi's Seminar, Institute of Economics and Public Finance, Faculty of Law, University of Rome, 1956–1961. Milano: A. Giuffré, 1962, pp. 31–46.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1963. Politics and Economics. New York: St. Martin's Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. 1971. Autobiography of an Economist. London: Macmillan, St. Martin's Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. 1981. “Economics and Political Economy.” American Economic Review 71: 1–10. Reprinted in Robbins (1984), pp. xi–xxxiii.Google Scholar
Roberts, J. 2007. “Is Logical Positivism Committed to the Ideal of Value-Free Science?” In Kincaid, H., Dupré, J., and Wylie, A., eds., Value-Free Science? Ideas and Illusions. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 143–163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roll, E. 1938. A History of Economic Thought, 4th edition. London: Faber and Faber, 1973.Google Scholar
Rooney, P. 1992. “On Values in Science: Is the Epistemic/Non-Epistemic Distinction Useful?” In Hull, D., Forbes, M., and Okruhlik, K., eds., Proceedings of the 1982 Biennial Meeting of the Philosophy of Science Association. East Lansing, pp. 13–22.Google Scholar
Ross, D. Forthcoming. “Robbins, Positivism and the Demarcation of Economics from Psychology.”Google Scholar
Rudner, R. 1953. “The Scientist qua Scientist Makes Value Judgments.” Philosophy of Science 20: 1–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1950. “Evaluation of Real National Income.” Oxford Economic Papers 2: 1–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1941. “A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics.” Review of Economic Studies 9: 77–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scriven, M. 1980. “The Exact Role of Value Judgments in Science.” In Klemke, E., Hollinger, R., and Kline, A., eds. Introductory Readings in the Philosophy of Science. Buffalo, NY: Prometheus Books, pp. 269–291.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1979. “The Welfare Basis of Real Income Comparisons.” Journal of Economic Literature 17: 1–45.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1980. “Description as Choice.” Oxford Economic Papers: 32: 353–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Senior, N. W. 1836. An Outline of the Science of Political Economy. London: W. Clowes.Google Scholar
Shrader-Freschette, K. S. 1985. Science Policy, Ethics, and Economic Methodology. D. Reidel Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Souter, R. W. 1933. “The Nature and Significance of Economic Science in Recent Discussion.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 47: 377–413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spengler, J. J. 1934. “Have Values a Place in Economics?International Journal of Ethics 44 (3): 313–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streeten, P. 1953. “Appendix: Recent Controversies,” translated by Streeten, P.. In Myrdal, G., The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Sutton, C. 1937. “The Relation Between Economic Theory and Economic Policy.” Economic Journal 47: 44–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thirlwall, A. P. 1987. Nicholas Kaldor. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, P. H. 1910. The Common Sense of Political Economy, 2nd edition. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Wiseman, J. 1985. “Lionel Robbins, the Austrian School and the LSE tradition.” In Samuels, W. J., ed., Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 3, pp. 147–159.Google Scholar
Wootton, B. 1938. Lament for Economics. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar