Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T03:44:16.506Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE MACHINE IN ADAM SMITH’S ECONOMIC AND WIDER THOUGHT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 November 2012

Abstract

This paper exhaustively examines all Adam Smith’s references to “machines,” including machine metaphors or analogies, with a view to a comprehensive interpretation of the significance of the machine in his thought as a whole. By bringing together all Smith’s references to machines (and variants of that term), as well as his references to related phenomena, mechanics and engines (and variants), the totality of the various different kinds of uses of these terms assists in clarifying the meaning of each of them. However, this exercise is undertaken particularly with a view to the significance of machines in Smith’s political economy.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aspromourgos, Tony. 2009. The Science of Wealth: Adam Smith and the Framing of Political Economy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Babbage, Charles. [1832] 1835. On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures. Fourth edition. London: Charles Knight.Google Scholar
Bryce, John C., ed. 1983a. Adam Smith. Lectures on Rhetoric and Belles Lettres. Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, volume 4. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Bryce, John C. 1983b. “Introduction.” In Bryce, J. C., ed., Adam Smith. Lectures on Rhetoric and Belles Lettres. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Campbell, Roy H., and Skinner, Andrew S.. 1976. “General Introduction.” In Campbell, R. H., Skinner, A. S., and Todd, W. B., eds., Adam Smith. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Two volumes. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Campbell, Roy H., Skinner, Andrew S., and Todd, William B., eds. 1976. Adam Smith. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Two volumes. Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, volume 2. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Christie, John R. R. 1987. “Adam Smith’s Metaphysics of Language.” In Benjamin, A. E., Cantor, G. N., and Christie, J. R. R., eds., The Figural and the Literal: Problems of Language in the History of Science and Philosophy, 1630–1800. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 202229.Google Scholar
Cremaschi, Sergio. 2002. “Metaphors in the Wealth of Nations.” In Boehm, S., Gehrke, C., Kurz, H. D., and Sturn, R., eds., Is There Progress in Economics? Knowledge, Truth and the History of Economic Thought. Cheltenham: Elgar, pp. 89114.Google Scholar
Dascal, Marcelo. 2006. “Adam Smith’s Theory of Language.” In Haakonssen, K., ed., The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 79111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, Walter A. 1975. “Adam Smith’s Theory of Economic Growth.” In Skinner, A. S. and Wilson, T., eds., Essays on Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon, pp. 426454.Google Scholar
Eltis, Walter A. 1984. The Classical Theory of Economic Growth. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groenewegen, Peter D. 1977. “Adam Smith and the Division of Labour: A Bicentenary Estimate.” Australian Economic Papers 16 (December): 161174. As repr. in P.D. Groenewegen, 2002, Eighteenth-Century Economics: Turgot, Beccaria and Smith and Their Contemporaries. London: Routledge, pp. 388–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
InteLex Corporation. 2002. The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, with Supplementary Texts (Past Masters: Humanities Databases, Full Text Scholarly Editions). Charlottesville, VA.Google Scholar
Liddell, Henry G., and Scott, Robert. 1940. A Greek-English Lexicon. Ninth edition. Revised and augmented byJones, H. S. and McKenzie, R.. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Lindgren, J. Ralph. 1969. “Adam Smith’s Theory of Inquiry.” Journal of Political Economy 77 (6): 897915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindgren, J. Ralph. 1973. The Social Philosophy of Adam Smith. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1967. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. Volume 1. New York: International Publishers. First German edition, 1867; first English edition, 1887.Google Scholar
Mayr, Otto. 1986. Authority, Liberty & Automatic Machinery in Early Modern Europe. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meek, Ronald L., Raphael, David D., and Stein, Peter G., eds. 1978. Adam Smith. Lectures on Jurisprudence. Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith. volume 5. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Montes, Leonidis. 2003. “Smith and Newton: Some Methodological Issues Concerning General Equilibrium Theory.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 27 (5): 723747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montes, Leonidis. 2004. Adam Smith in Context: A Critical Reassessment of Some Central Components of His Thought. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mossner, Ernest C., and Ross, Ian S., eds. 1977. The Correspondence of Adam Smith. Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, volume 6. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Raphael, David D., and Macfie, Alec L., eds. 1976a. Adam Smith. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, volume 1. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Raphael, David D. 1976b. “Introduction.” In Raphael, D. D. and Macfie, A. L., eds., Adam Smith. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1998. The Myth of Adam Smith. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Redman, Deborah A. 1997. The Rise of Political Economy as a Science: Methodology and the Classical Economists. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1965. “Adam Smith on the Division of Labour: Two Views or One?Economica 32 (May): 127139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Ian S. 1995. The Life of Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schliesser, Eric. 2005. “Some Principles of Adam Smith’s Newtonian Methods in the Wealth of Nations.” Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 23–A: 3374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew S. 1996. A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith. Second edition. Oxford: Clarendon.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, Dugald. [1794] 1811. “Account of the Life and Writings of Adam Smith, LL.D.” In Stewart, D., Biographical Memoirs of Adam Smith, LL.D. of William Robertson, D.D. and of Thomas Reid, D.D. …. Edinburgh: Creech, Bell and Bradfute [and others]. As repr. in W.P.D. Wightman, J.C. Bryce, and I.S. Ross, eds., 1980, Adam Smith. Essays on Philosophical Subjects. Oxford: Clarendon, pp. 269–351.Google Scholar
Thorpe, David. 2007. “Science and Its Applications in The Theory of Moral Sentiments.” In Cockfield, G., Firth, A., and Laurent, J., eds., New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Cheltenham: Elgar, pp. 124140.Google Scholar
Ure, Andrew. 1835. The Philosophy of Manufactures: or, an Exposition of the Scientific, Moral, and Commercial Economy of the Factory System of Great Britain. London: Charles Knight.Google Scholar
Wightman, William P. D., Bryce, John C.., and Ross, Ian S., eds. 1980. Adam Smith. Essays on Philosophical Subjects. Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, volume 3. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1928. “Increasing Returns and Economic Progress.” Economic Journal 38 (December): 527542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar