1 Introduction
People's ability to cooperate and overcome social dilemmas, such as in public goods games, is one of the most persistent findings in the field of behavioral economics (Dawes, Reference Dawes1980). People consistently pay costs to contribute to their group's best interests, but cooperation is fragile to defection (Dawes & Thaler, Reference Dawes and Thaler1988). Punishment is a key mechanism through which people sustain cooperation (Fehr & Gächter, Reference Fehr and Gächter2000, Reference Fehr and Gächter2002). Typically, in public goods games with punishment, participants first decide how much to contribute to the public good. After seeing the decisions of other group members, participants can pay an additional cost to impose fines on their group members (Fehr & Gächter, Reference Fehr and Gächter2000). Punishment, or second order cooperation, facilitates the successful provision of public goods when inflicted on defectors and seems to be an evolved mechanism critical to the maintenance of cooperation (Boyd et al., Reference Boyd, Gintis, Bowles and Richerson2003; Tooby et al., Reference Tooby, Cosmides and Price2006).
However, experimental evidence finds punishment can go awry. In an impressive effort of cross-cultural data collection, Herrmann et al. (Reference Herrmann, Thöni and Gächter2008) conducted public goods games with punishment in 16 different cities around the world. They find some individuals engage in antisocial punishment, where a punisher inflicts costs on a target who contributed as much or more than the punisher to the public good. Rates of antisocial punishment vary across cultures, and antisocial punishment undermines cooperation (Herrmann et al., Reference Herrmann, Thöni and Gächter2008). A reanalysis of these data examines rates of perverse punishment, or punishment inflicted on targets who contributed more than the group's average contribution, and finds similar results (Fu & Putterman, Reference Fu and Putterman2018).
Importantly, both antisocial and perverse punishment are relative, defined by the relationship between either the target and punisher's contributions or the target and group's average contributions. Rather than looking when contributing less relative to group members invites punishment, I instead rely on the data collected by Herrmann et al. (Reference Herrmann, Thöni and Gächter2008)Footnote 1 to ask: Are those who contribute less (in absolute terms) to the public good punished more often and severely? Second, are those who contribute to the public good more likely to carry out punishment than those who defect? Third, do defectors and contributors punish different types of targets? Finally, is there variation in these tendencies across cultures? Importantly, these analyses are not meant to dispute the existing work conducted using these data (Fu & Putterman, Reference Fu and Putterman2018; Herrmann et al., Reference Herrmann, Thöni and Gächter2008). Instead, they add nuance to our understanding of the relationship between target contributions and punisher behavior.
2 Who is punished?
People who contribute more to the public good are less likely to be punished and receive smaller punishments, pooling across samples (Fig. 1). This pattern is consistent across cities: Fig. 1 plots the marginal effect of target contributions on punishment (see Tables A1 and A2 for full analyses). In no case do increased contributions lead to more punishment, though in Riyadh and Muscat there is no significant relationship between target contributions and punishment. In general, for every 1 token more a player contributed, they were punished between 0.05 and 0.10 tokens less.
This pattern is consistent when examining the probability of being punished in each city (Figure A1). In the online appendix, I present robustness checks using different model specifications further indicating those who contribute more are generally punished less, and increased contributions do not invite increased punishment (Tables A2–A3 and Figures A2–A5).
3 The decision to punish
We might expect first-order cooperators—those who contribute to the public good—are more likely to be second order cooperators and pay the cost of punishment. Both are forms of costly cooperation (Yamagishi, Reference Yamagishi1986) that may be determined by similar underlying mechanisms (e.g., inequality aversion, Fehr & Schmidt, Reference Fehr and Schmidt1999). However, existing empirical work in the U.S. and U.K. fails to find a correlation between an individual's decision to cooperate and punish (Molleman et al., Reference Molleman, Kölle, Starmer and Gächter2019; Peysakhovich et al., Reference Peysakhovich, Nowak and Rand2014; Weber et al., Reference Weber, Weisel and Gächter2018).Footnote 2 Are those who contribute to the public good more willing to pay the cost of punishment across cultures?
To identify the relationship between first and second order cooperation, I regress whether someone punished and how much they punished on how much they contributed, how much the target contributed, and an interaction between the two while allowing for non-linear effects of punisher contributions (Fig. 2). There is a weak relationship between contributions and punishment, pooling across samples and across contributions of the target.
To explore differences in these results across samples, I regress whether someone punishes on their contributions in the same period, an indicator for each study location, and an interaction between the two (Fig. 2). In many cities, those who contribute to the public good are not more likely to punish than defectors. Robustness checks with alternative model specifications are available in Figures A6–A8 and Table A2. Cooperation and punishment are not necessarily orthogonal, but these results provide additional cross-cultural evidence that first order cooperation is not a necessary condition for second order cooperation.
Do cooperators and defectors punish different types of behavior? Figure 2 aggregates over contributions of the target, which may conceal variation in whether those who contribute more punish different types of players. To identify whether this is the case, I divide contribution decisions into four categories: Defect (contribute nothing), low contribution (1–9 tokens), high contribution (10–19 tokens), and full contribution (contribute 20 tokens). I then regress whether someone punishes and how much they punish on their contribution decision, the target's decision, and an interaction between the two (Fig. 3).Footnote 3
Defectors and full contributors alike engage in punishing defectors, though full contributors are more likely to do so. All types of players punish those who contribute nothing more frequently and severely than those who contribute everything. However, low contributors are more willing than high contributors to punish players who contribute everything. This pattern of behavior is consistent across cultures, with the exception of Riyadh and Muscat (Figures A9).
4 Conclusion
Across cities, those who contribute more are punished less. While this punishment is more often carried out by those who also contribute to the public good, defectors punish one another as well. The consistency in this relationship is striking given the observed variation in contributions to the public good across cities in these data (Figure A10).
While this paper seeks to describe punishment across cultures, I leave open the question of the mechanisms driving these behaviors. First, why is there so much variation in first order cooperation across cultures (Henrich et al., Reference Henrich, Boyd, Bowles, Camerer, Fehr and Gintis2005)? Second, why do first order defectors sometimes engage in second order cooperation? A large body of research has attempted to explain the motivations underlying conditional cooperation (Falk & Fischbacher, Reference Falk and Fischbacher2006; Fehr & Schmidt, Reference Fehr and Schmidt1999) and altruistic punishment (Fehr & Gächter, Reference Fehr and Gächter2002), but our knowledge would benefit from future work explicitly exploring potential differences between the two.
Acknowledgements
I thank Scott Bokemper, Andrew W. Delton, Reuben Kline, Patrick Kraft, Yanna Krupnikov, John Barry Ryan, Christian Thöni, and Oleg Smirnov for their helpful feedback on the manuscript.
Data availability
All data is available online at the following link: https://datadryad.org/resource/doi:10.5061/dryad.8730. The replication and supplementary material for the study is available at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/3KC9TT.
Declarations
Conflict of interest
The author declares no conflicts of interest.