Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T13:16:02.591Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The rule of law, central bank independence and price stability

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 June 2017

DANIYAR NURBAYEV*
Affiliation:
The Eurasian Research Institute, Almaty, Kazakhstan

Abstract

This work empirically investigates the effect of the interaction between the rule of law and legal central bank independence (CBI) on price stability (the level of inflation and inflation volatility), employing a panel dataset that covers up to 124 countries over the period from 1970 to 2013. A new, largely complete legal CBI dataset, covering 182 countries was used for the work. The results indicate that the effect of legal CBI on price stability depends on the strength of the rule of law. Moreover, the results reveal that legal CBI has no significant effect on price stability when the rule of law is weak. The findings also show that 67% of advanced countries possess a rule of law that is strong enough to maintain price stability by increasing central bank autonomy, while only 4.5% of developing countries possess it.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Querubín, P. and Robinson, J. A. (2008), ‘When does policy reform work? The case of central bank independence’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 351418.Google Scholar
Aisen, A. and Veiga, F. J. (2007), ‘Political instability and inflation volatility’, Public Choice, 135 (3–4): 207–23.Google Scholar
Anderies, J. M., Folke, C., Walker, B. and Ostrom, E. (2013), ‘Aligning key concepts for global change policy: robustness, resilience, and sustainability’, Ecology and Society, 18 (2): 8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderies, J. M., Janssen, M. A. and Ostrom, E. (2004), ‘A framework to analyze the robustness of social-ecological systems from an institutional perspective’, Ecology and Society, 9 (1): 18.Google Scholar
Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991), ‘Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations’, Review of Economic Studies, 58 (2): 277297.Google Scholar
Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1995), ‘Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models’, Journal of Econometrics, 68 (1): 2951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Gordon, D. B. (1983), ‘A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model’, Journal of Political Economy, 91 (4): 589610.Google Scholar
Bleaney, M. and Fielding, D. (2002), ‘Exchange rate regimes, inflation and output volatility in developing countries’, Journal of Development Economics, 68 (1): 233–45.Google Scholar
Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998), ‘Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models’, Journal of Econometrics, 87 (1): 115–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bodea, C. and Hicks, R. (2014), ‘Price stability and central bank independence: discipline, credibility, and democratic institutions’, International Organization, 69 (1): 3561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bond, S. R. (2002), ‘Dynamic panel data models: a guide to micro data methods and practice’, Cemmap Working Paper No. 09/02, London: Institute for Fiscal Studies.Google Scholar
Bontempi, M. E. and Mammi, I. (2012), ‘A strategy to reduce the count of moment conditions in panel data GMM’, Working Papers 843, Università di Bologna.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowdler, C. and Malik, A. (2005), ‘Openness and inflation volatility: Panel data evidence’, Nuffield College Economics Working Papers, Ref: 2005-W14, Oxford: University of Oxford Nuffield College.Google Scholar
Brambor, T., Clark, W. R. and Golder, M. (2006), ‘Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analyses’, Political Analysis, 14 (1): 6382.Google Scholar
Campillo, M. and Miron, J. A. (1997), ‘Why does inflation differ across countries?’, in Romer, C. D. and Romer, D. H. (eds), Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 335–57.Google Scholar
Chinn, M. D. and Ito, H. (2006), ‘What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions’, Journal of Development Economics, 81 (1): 163192.Google Scholar
Clarida, R., Galí, J. and Gertler, M. (1999), ‘The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37 (4): 1661–707.Google Scholar
Coppedge, M., Gerring, J., Lindberg, S. I., Teorell, J., Altman, D., Bernhard, M., Fish, M. S., Glynn, A., Hicken, A., Knutsen, C. H., McMann, K., Pemstein, D., Skaaning, S. E., Staton, J., Tzelgov, E., Wang, Y. and Zimmerman, Z. (2016), Varieties of Democracy: Dataset V, Notre Dame, IN: Varieties of Democracy Project.Google Scholar
Crowe, C. (2008), ‘Goal independent central banks: why politicians decide to delegate’, European Journal of Political Economy, 24 (4): 748–62.Google Scholar
Crowe, C. and Meade, E. E. (2007), ‘The evolution of central bank governance around the world’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21 (4): 6990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cukierman, A. (1992), Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A., Web, S. B. and Neyapti, B. (1992), ‘Measuring the independence of central banks and its effect on policy outcomes’, World Bank Economic Review, 6 (3): 353–98.Google Scholar
Eijffinger, S. and Stadhouders, P. (2003), ‘Monetary policy and the rule of law’, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3698, London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
Garriga, A. C. (2016), ‘Central bank independence in the world: a new data set’, International Interactions, 42 (5): 849–68.Google Scholar
Ghosh, A., Gulde, A., Ostry, J. and Wolf, H. (1997), ‘Does the nominal exchange rate regime matter?’, NBER Working Paper No. 5874, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Gollwitzer, S. and Quintyn, M. (2010), ‘The effectiveness of macroeconomic commitment in weak(er) institutional environments’, IMF Working Paper No. WP/10/193, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Granato, J., Lo, M. and Wong, M. C. (2006), ‘Testing monetary policy intentions in open economies’, Southern Economic Journal, 72 (3): 730–46.Google Scholar
Gruben, W. C. and Mcleod, D. (2002), ‘Capital account liberalization and inflation’, Economics Letters, 77 (2): 221–5.Google Scholar
Gruben, W. C. and Mcleod, D. (2004), ‘The openness–inflation puzzle revisited’, Applied Economics Letters, 11 (8): 465–8.Google Scholar
Gupta, A. S. (2008), ‘Does capital account openness lower inflation?International Economic Journal, 22 (4): 471–87.Google Scholar
Gwartney, J., Lawson, R. and Hall, J. (2016), ‘2016 economic freedom dataset’, Economic Freedom of the World: 2016 Annual Report, Vancouver: Fraser Institute. www.freetheworld.com/datasets_efw.html (accessed 12 June 2015).Google Scholar
Haan, J. D. and Siermann, C. L. (1996), ‘Central bank independence, inflation and political instability in developing countries’, Journal of Policy Reform, 1 (2): 135–47.Google Scholar
Hayo, B. and Hefeker, C. (2002), ‘Reconsidering central bank independence’, European Journal of Political Economy, 18 (4): 653–74.Google Scholar
Hayo, B. and Voigt, S. (2008), ‘Inflation, central bank independence, and the legal system’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 164 (4): 751–77.Google Scholar
Henisz, W. J. (2000), ‘The institutional environment for economic growth’, Economics and Politics, 12 (1): 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hetzel, R. L. and Richardson, G. (2016), ‘Money, banking, and monetary policy from the formation of the Federal Reserve until today’, FRB Richmond Working Paper No. 16–1, Richmond: Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hielscher, K. and Markwardt, G. (2012), ‘The role of political institutions for the effectiveness of central bank independenceEuropean Journal of Political Economy, 28 (3): 286301.Google Scholar
Keefer, P. and Stasavage, D. (2003), ‘The limits of delegation: veto players, central bank independence, and the credibility of monetary policy’, American Political Science Review, 97 (3): 407–23.Google Scholar
Klomp, J. and Haan, J. D. (2010a), ‘Inflation and central bank independence: a meta-regression analysis’, Journal of Economic Surveys, 24 (4): 593621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klomp, J. and Haan, J. D. (2010b), ‘Central bank independence and inflation revisited’, Public Choice, 144 (3–4): 445–57.Google Scholar
Koyama, M. and Johnson, B. (2015), ‘Monetary stability and the rule of law’, Journal of Financial Stability, 17: 4658.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. (1977), ‘Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans’, Journal of Political Economy, 85 (3): 473–91.Google Scholar
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2013), ‘Systemic banking crises database’, IMF Economic Review, 61 (2): 225–70.Google Scholar
Loungani, P. and Sheets, N. (1997), ‘Central bank independence, inflation, and growth in transition economies’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29 (3): 381–99.Google Scholar
Mahadeva, L. and Sterne, G. (eds) (2000). Monetary Policy Frameworks in a Global Context, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mehrhoff, J. (2009), ‘A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM’, Discussion Paper Series 1: Economic Studies, No.31, Frankfurt: Deutsche Bundesbank.Google Scholar
Moser, P. (1999), ‘Checks and balances, and the supply of central bank independence’, European Economic Review, 43 (8): 1569–93.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (1981), ‘Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects’, Econometrica, 49 (6): 1417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, M., Shambaugh, J. C. and Taylor, A. M. (2010), ‘Financial stability, the trilemma, and international reserves’, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2 (2): 5794.Google Scholar
Polillo, S. and Guillén, M. (2005), ‘Globalization pressures and the state: the worldwide spread of central bank independence’, American Journal of Sociology, 110 (6): 1764–802.Google Scholar
Rogoff, K. (1985), ‘The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100 (4): 1169–90.Google Scholar
Roodman, D. (2009a), ‘How to do xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata’, The Stata Journal, 9 (1): 86136.Google Scholar
Roodman, D. (2009b), ‘A note on the theme of too many instruments’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71 (1): 135–58.Google Scholar
Rother, P. C. (2004), ‘Fiscal policy and inflation volatility’, ECB Working Paper, No. 317, Frankfurt am Main: European Central Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shambaugh, J. C. (2004), ‘The effects of fixed exchange rates on monetary policy’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 (1): 301–52.Google Scholar
Svensson, L. E. O. (1997), ‘Optimal inflation targets, ‘conservative’ central banks, and linear inflation contracts’, American Economic Review, 87 (1): 98114.Google Scholar
Walsh, C. (2005), ‘Central bank independence. Prepared for the New Palgrave Dictionary’, http://people.ucsc.edu/~walshc/MyPapers/cbi_newpalgrave.pdf (accessed 20 May 2016).Google Scholar
Windmeijer, F. (2005), ‘A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators’, Journal of Econometrics, 126 (1): 2551.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (1999), ‘Optimal monetary policy inertia’, NBER Working Paper No. 7261, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar