Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T12:54:20.879Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Hospitalitas: Barbarian settlements and constitutional foundations of medieval Europe

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 August 2017

ANDREW T. YOUNG*
Affiliation:
Rawls College of Business, Texas Tech University, Lubbock, TX 79409

Abstract

A rough balance of political power between monarchs and a militarized landed aristocracy characterized medieval Western Europe. Scholars have argued that this balance of power contributed to a tradition of limited government and constitutional bargaining. I argue that 5th- and 6th-century barbarian settlements created a foundation for this balance of power. The settlements provided barbarians with allotments of lands or taxes due from the lands. The allotments served to align the incentives of barbarian warriors and Roman landowners, and realign the incentives of barbarian warriors and their leadership elite. Barbarian military forces became decentralized and the warriors became political powerful shareholders of the realm.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anderson, J. L. (1991), Explaining Long-Term Economic Change, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Anderson, P (2013 [1974]), Passages from Antiquity to Feudalism, London: Verso.Google Scholar
Baechler, J. (1975), The Origins of Capitalism, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Baker, M. J., Bulte, E. H. (2010), ‘Kings and Vikings: on the dynamics of competitive agglomeration’. Economics of Governance, 11 (3), 207–27.Google Scholar
Barnish, S. J. B. (1986), ‘Taxation, land and Barbarian Settlement in the Western Empire’, Papers of the British School at Rome, 54, 170–95.Google Scholar
Bates, R. H. (2008), When Things Fell Apart: State Failure in Late-Century Africa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, R. H., Greif, A., Singh, S. (2002), ‘Organizing violence’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46 (5), 599628.Google Scholar
Berman, H. J. (1983), Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bernhardt, J. W. (1993), Itinerant Kingship and Royal Monasteries in Early Medieval Germany, c. 936–1075, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, G., Buchanan, J. M. (1980), The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Blaydes, L., Chaney, E. (2013), ‘The feudal revolution and Europe's rise: political divergence of the Christian West and the Muslim world before 1500 CE’, American Political Science Review, 107 (1), 1634.Google Scholar
Bisson, T. N. (1995), ‘Medieval lordship’, Speculum, 70 (4), 743–59.Google Scholar
Bisson, T. N. (2009), The Crisis of the Twelfth Century: Power, Lordship, and the Origins of European Government, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bloch, M. (1968a [1939]), Feudal Society: Volume 2 – Social Classes and Political Organization, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bloch, M. (1968b [1940]), Feudal Society: Volume 2 – Social Classes and Political Organization, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1965), ‘An economic theory of clubs’, Economica 32 (125), 114.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M., Congleton, R. D. (2003 [1998]), Politics by Principle, Not Interest: Towards Nondiscriminatory Democracy. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Cassiodorus (1884), Cassiodori Senatoris Variae (Mommsen, T., ed.). https://archive.org/details/cassiodorisenato12cass (accessed 10 July 2017).Google Scholar
Cassiodorus (1886), The Letters of Cassiodorus: A Condensed Translation of the Variae Epistolae of Magnus Aurelius Cassiodorus Senator, translated by Hodgkin, T. (Kindle edn), London: Henry Frowde.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2007), ‘From royal to parliamentary rule without revolution: the economics of constitutional exchange within divided governments’, European Journal of Political Economy, 23 (2), 261–84.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2011a), ‘Why local governments do not maximize profits: on the value-added by the representative institutions of town and city governance’, Public Choice 149 (1/2), 187201.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2011b), Perfecting Parliament: Constitutional Reform, Liberalism, and the Rise of Western Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cronne, H. A. (1939), ‘Historical revision: XCI. – the origins of feudalism’, History, 24 (95), 251–9.Google Scholar
De Jouvenel, B. (1993 [1947]), On Power: The Natural History of its Growth, Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. (2002), ‘Toward a theory of property rights II: the competition between private and collective ownership’, Journal of Legal Studies, 31 (S2), S653S672.Google Scholar
Downing, B. M. (1988), ‘Constitutionalism, warfare, and political change in early modern Europe’, Theory and Society, 17, 756.Google Scholar
Downing, B. M. (1989), ‘Medieval origins of constitutional government in the West’, Theory and Society, 18 (1), 213–47.Google Scholar
Downing, B. M. (1992), The Military Revolution and Political Change: Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Drew, K. F. 1976. The Burgundian Code. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Ertman, T. (1997), Birth of the Leviathan, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fink, A. (2012), ‘The Hanseatic League and the concept of functional overlapping competing jurisdictions’, Kyklos, 65 (2), 194217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, F. (2011), The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution, New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Ganshof, F. L. (1939), ‘Benefice and vassalage in the age of Charlemagne’, Cambridge Historical Journal, 6 (2), 147–75.Google Scholar
Gaupp, E. T. (1844), Die Germanischen Ansiedlungen Und Landtheilungen in Den Provinzen Des Römischen Westreiches, Breslau: Verlage von Joseph Max.Google Scholar
Goffart, W. (1980), Barbarians and Romans: The Techniques of Accommodation, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Goffart, W. (1988), The Narrators of Barbarian History (AD 550–800): Jordanes, Gregory of Tours, Bede, and Paul the Deacon, Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Goffart, W. (2006), Barbarian Tides: The Migration Age and the Roman West, 376–568, Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Goffart, W. (2008), ‘Frankish military duty and the fate of Roman taxation’, Early Medieval Europe 16 (2), 166–90.Google Scholar
Goffart, W. (2010), ‘The technique of Barbarian Settlement in the fifth century: a personal, streamlined account with ten additional comments’, Journal of Late Antiquity, 3 (1), 6598.Google Scholar
González de Lara, Y., Greif, A., Jha, S. (2008), ‘The administrative foundations of self-enforcing constitutions’, American Economic Review, 98 (2), 105–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2008), ‘The impact of administrative power on political and economic development: toward a political economy of implementation’, in Helpman, E. (ed.), Institutions and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, A., Laitin, D. D. (2004), ‘A theory of endogenous institutional change’, American Political Science Review, 98 (4), 633–52.Google Scholar
Heather, P. (1998), The Goths, Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Heather, P. (2009), Empires and Barbarians: The Fall of Rome and the Birth of Europe, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hen, Y. (2011), Roman Barbarians: The Royal Court and Culture in the Early Medieval West, London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Herb, M. (2009), ‘A nation of bureaucrats: political participation and economic diversification in Kuwait and the United Arab Emirates’, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 41 (3), 375–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hintz, O. (1975 [1931]), ‘The preconditions of representative government in the context of world history’, in Gilbert, P. (ed.), The Historical Essays of Otto Hintz, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hodges, R., Whitehouse, D. (1983), Mohammed, Charlemagne & the Origins of Europe, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, A. H. M. (1986), The Later Roman Empire 284–602: A Social, Economic, and Administrative Survey (vol. 1), Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Ko, C. Y., Koyama, M., Sng, T.-H. (2016), ‘Unified China; divided Europe’, International Economic Review, forthcoming.Google Scholar
King, P. D. (1972), Law and Society in the Visigothic Kingdom, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., Svendsen, G. T. (2003), ‘Rational bandits: plunder, public goods, and the Vikings’, Public Choice, 117 (3/4), 255–72.Google Scholar
Lear, F. S. (1951), ‘The public law of the Visigothic Code’ Speculum, 26 (1), 123.Google Scholar
Leeson, P. T. (2011), ‘Government, clubs, and constitutions’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 80 (2), 301–8.Google Scholar
Leeson, P. T., Suarez, O. (2016), ‘An economic analysis of Magna Carta’, International Review of Law and Economics, 47 (S), 40–6.Google Scholar
Leeson, P. T., Williamson, C. R. (2009), ‘Anarchy and development: an application of the theory of second best’, Law and Development Review, 2 (1), 7796.Google Scholar
Libman, A., Kolzov, V., Schultz, A. (2012), ‘Roving bandits in action: outside option and governmental predation in autocracies’, Kyklos, 65 (4), 526–62.Google Scholar
Lot, F. (1928), ‘Du Régime de L'hospitalité’, Revue Belge de Philoligie et d'Histoire, 7 (3), 9751011.Google Scholar
Marongiu, A. (1968), Medieval Parliaments: A Comparative Study, London: Eyre & Spottiswoode.Google Scholar
Mathisen, R. (2011), Roman Aristocrats in Barbarian Gaul: Strategies for Survival in an Age of Transition (Kindle edn), Austin: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
McCormick, M. (2001), The Origins of the European Economy: Communications and Commerce, AD 300900, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mittal, S., Weingast, B. R. (2011), ‘Self-enforcing constitutions: with an application to democratic stability in America's first century’ Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 29 (2), 278302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C., Weingast, B. R. (1989), ‘Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England’, Journal of Economic History, 49 (4). 803–32.Google Scholar
North, D., Wallis, J. J., Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1971), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1982), The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, Hartford: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1993), ‘Dictatorship, democracy, and development’, American Political Science Review, 87 (3), 567–76.Google Scholar
Raico, R. (1994), ‘The theory of economic development and the ‘European miracle’, in Boettke, E. (ed.), The Collapse of Development Planning, New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Rajagopalan, S. (2016), ‘Magna Carta revisited: parchment, guns, and constitutional order’, International Review of Law and Economics, 47 (S): 5359.Google Scholar
Riché, P. (1993 [1983]), The Carolingians: A Family who Forged Europe, translated by Allen, M. I., Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Rio, A. (2008), ‘High and low: ties of dependence in the Frankish kingdoms’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 18, 4368.Google Scholar
Russell, C. S. R. (1982), ‘Monarchies, wars, and states in England, France, and Spain, c. 1580–1640’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 7 (2), 205220.Google Scholar
Salter, A. W. (2015a), ‘Rights to the realm: reconsidering Western political development’, American Political Science Review, 109 (4), 725–34.Google Scholar
Salter, A. W. (2015b), ‘Sovereignty as exchange of political property rights’, Public Choice, 165 (1–2), 7996.Google Scholar
Salter, A. W., Hall, A. R. (2015), Calculating bandits: quasi-corporate governance and institutional selection in autocracies’, Advances in Austrian Economics, 19, 193213.Google Scholar
Salter, A. W., Young, A. T. (2017a), ‘Polycentric sovereignty: the medieval constitution, governance quality, and the Wealth of Nations’, Working Paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2735963 (accessed 10 July 2017).Google Scholar
Salter, A. W., Young, A. T. (2017b), ‘Medieval representative assemblies: collective action and antecedents of limited government’, Working Paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2914383 (accessed 10 July 2017).Google Scholar
Sandler, T., Tschirhart, J. (1997), ‘Club theory: thirty years later’, Public Choice, 93 (3/4), 335–55.Google Scholar
Sivan, H. (1987), ‘On Foederati, hospitalitas, and the settlement of the Goths in AD 418’, American Journal of Philology, 108 (4), 759–72.Google Scholar
Stark, R. (2011), The Triumph of Christianity: How the Jesus Movement became the World's Largest Religion, New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Stasavage, D. (2010), ‘When distance mattered: geographic scale and the development of European representative assemblies’, American Political Science Review, 104 (4), 625–43.Google Scholar
Stasavage, D. (2011), States of Credit: Size, Power, and the Development of European Polities, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Stasavage, D. (2016), ‘Representation and consent: why they arose in Europe and not elsewhere’, Annual Review of Political Science, 19, 145–62.Google Scholar
Stephenson, C. (1941), ‘The origin and significance of feudalism’, American Historical Review, 46 (4), 788812.Google Scholar
Thompson, E. A. (1969), The Goths in Spain, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Thompson, E. A. (1982 [1930]), Romans and Barbarians: The Decline of the Western Empire, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Van Zanden, J., Buringh, E., Bosker, M. (2012), ‘The rise and decline of European Parliaments, 1188–1789’, Economic History Review, 65 (3), 835–61.Google Scholar
Volckart, O. (2000), ‘State building by bargaining for monopoly rents’, Kyklos, 53 (2), 265–93.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1978 [1922]), Economy and Society edited by Roth, G., Wittich, C., Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. R. (1997), ‘The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law’, American Political Science Review, 91 (2), 245–63.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. R. (2005), ‘Self-enforcing constitutions’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (3), 98108.Google Scholar
Ward-Perkins, B. (2005), The Fall of Rome and the End of Civilization, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wickham, C. (1984), ‘The other transition: from the ancient world to feudalism’, Past & Present, 103, 336.Google Scholar
Wickham, C. (2005), Framing the Early Middle Ages: Europe and the Mediterranean 400–800, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wickham, C. (2009), The Inheritance of Rome: Illuminating the Dark Ages 400–1000, London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Wickham, C. (2016), Medieval Europe, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Williams, S. F. (2016), ‘Words, words, words: the remarkable perseverance of Magna Carta’, International Review of Law & Economics, 47 (S), 6771.Google Scholar
Young, A. T. (2015), ‘From Caesar to Tacitus: changes in early Germanic governance circa 50 BC–50 AD, Public Choice, 164 (3–4), 357–78.Google Scholar
Young, A. T. (2016), ‘What does it take for a roving bandit to settle down? Theory and an illustrative history of the Visigoths’, Public Choice, 168 (1–2), 75102.Google Scholar