Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
The fundamental objective of American foreign economic policy after the Second World War was to establish a regime in which impediments to the movement of capital and goods were minimized. In this quest American central decision makers were largely successful because of America's external power. However, because of the weakness of the US political system, that is, the ability of private groups to check state initiatives, public officials were constantly faced with domestic political constraints. These constraints were more apparent in the area of commercial policy, where decisions involved Congress and executive agencies susceptible to societal influences, than in monetary policy, where decisions were made in a more insulated environment. The decline of America's external power, which became evident in the mid-1960s, was accompanied by growing demands for protection as more sectors of the American economy were adversely affected by foreign trade. This has led to increasing incoherence in US policy and greater instability in the international economic regime.
1 The approach to foreign policy analysis that has been used in this essay, which begins with the needs of the state and then looks to external and internal dangers and opportunities, is suggested by mercantilist writings of the 16th, 17th, and 18th centuries. Mercantilist policies were designed to strengthen and unify the state against both the universalism of the Church and the particularism of medieval society. SeeHeckscher, Eli F., Mercantilism, Vol. 1 (London: G. Allen and Unwin, 1935), p. 21Google Scholar.
2 Jones, Joseph Marion, The Fifteen Weeks (New York: Harcourt, Brace, and World, 1955), p. 92Google Scholar; Gardner, Richard N., Sterling-Dollar Diplomacy (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1969), pp. 19–20Google Scholar; Wilkins, Mira, The Maturing of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from 1914 to 1970 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1974), p. 289Google Scholar.
3 See Krasner, Stephen D., “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics Vol. 28, No. 3 (04 1976): 318–21, for an elaboration of this argumentCrossRefGoogle Scholar.
4 Haitz, Louis, The Liberal Tradition in America (New York: Harcourt, Brace, and World. 1955)Google Scholar.
5 Gardner, pp. 8–12; Schumann, Franz, The Logic of World Power (New York: Pantheon, 1974), Part IGoogle Scholar.
6 For an argument along these lines see Gilpin, Robert, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment (New York: Basic Books, 1975), Chapter 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
7 Such alternatives have been offered by academics. For example, see Gilpin, Chapter 8, and Tucker, Robert W., The New Isolationism: Threat or Promise? (Washington: Potomac Associates, 1972)Google ScholarPubMed.
8 Krasner, , “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” pp. 333–34Google Scholar.
9 It is obviously necessary to distinguish between power resources and power itself, the ability to influence the behavior of others. For an elaboration of this point see Knorr, Klaus, The Power of Nations: The Political Economy of International Relations (New York: Basic Books, 1975), pp. 9–14Google Scholar.
10 For sophisticated analyses of this kind see ibid., and Albert Hirschman, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1946).
11 I realize that this hardly conforms with conventional notions. Liberal analysts treat the state, at worst, as an epiphenomenon whose behavior is explained by societal pressures and, at best, as another interest group or as an arbitrator among competing interests. See Lowi, Theodore, “The Public Philosophy: Interest-Group Liberalism,” American Political Science Review Vol. 61, No. 1 (03 1967): 5–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Marxists regard the state as a servant of particular economic interests or as an agency preserving the general structure of capitalist society. Both liberals and Marxists deny the assumption of this paper that the state is an independent, autonomous entity with powers and objectives that are distinct from any particular societal groups.
12 With regard to the economy, structure can be defined in terms of the nature of ownership (public versus private), the degree of concentration within an industrial sector, and the importance of particular sectors in the economy as a whole.
13 On the relationship between late industrialization and state intervention see Gerschenkron, Alexander, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1962), Chapter 1Google Scholar.
14 Polsby, Kelson, Congress and the Presidency, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1971), pp. 140–41Google Scholar.
15 Truman, David B., The Governmental Process: Political Interests and Public Opinion, 2nd ed. (New York: Knopf, 1971), p. 529Google Scholar.
16 Huntington, Samuel P., Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968), p. 110Google Scholar.
17 Burnham, Walter Dean, Critical Elections and the Mainsprings of American Politics (New York: W.W. Norton, 1970), p. 176Google Scholar.
18 Dahl, Robert, Pluralist Democracy in the United States (Chicago: Rand-McNally, 1967), p. 39Google Scholar.
19 On the bureaucratic problem see Neustadt, Richard, Presidential Power: The Politics of Leadership (New York: Wiley, 1960)Google Scholar; Allison, Graham, Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis (Boston: Little Brown, 1971)Google Scholar; and Halperin, Morton, Bureaucratic Politics and Foreign Policy (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1974)Google Scholar. For discussions of the tendency to overemphasize autonomous bureaucratic goals as opposed to general beliefs and societal pressures see Krasner, Stephen D., “Are Bureaucracies Important?,” Foreign Policy 7 (Summer 1972): 159–79Google Scholar, and Art, Robert J., “Bureaucratic Politics and American Foreign Policy: A Critique,” Policy Sciences Vol. 4 (1973): 467–90Google Scholar.
20 Fenno, Richard F. Jr., “The Internal Distribution of Influence: The House,” in The Congress and America's Future, 2nd ed., edited by Truman, David B. (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1973), pp. 63–90Google Scholar; Huitt, Ralph K., “The Internal Distribution of Power: The Senate,” in Truman, , ed., The Congress and America's Future, pp. 91–117Google Scholar.
21 Huntington, p. 129.
22 Ibid., pp. 122 ff.
23 Dahl, pp. 58–61.
24 Potter, David M., People of Plenty: Economic Abundance and the American Character (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1954), p. 112CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
25 Robert A. Pastor, “Legislative-Executive Relations and US Foreign Trade Policy: The Case of the Trade Act of 1974,” Paper prepared for delivery at the 1976 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, 111., September 2–5,1976, p. 17; and Marks, Mathew J. and Malmgren, Harald B., “Negotiating Nontariff Distortions to Trade,” Law and Policy in International Business Vol. 7, No. 2 (1975): 348Google Scholar.
26 Weil, Gordon L., American Trade Policy: A New Round (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1975), p. 56; and Pastor, p. 16Google Scholar.
27 Evans, John W., The Kennedy Round in American Trade Policy: Tlie Twilight of the GATT? (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1971), pp. 17–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Weil, pp. 37–38
28 National Journal Reports, January 18,1975, pp. 77–78; and US Congress, Senate, Committee on Finance, United States International Trade Policy and the Trade Act of 1974, Committee Print, 94th Cong., 2nd sess., p. 19.
29 National Journal Reports, May 10,1975, p. 696.
30 On the importance of decision-making arenas see Schattschneider, E.E., The Semi-Sovereign People: A Realist's View of Democracy in America (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1960)Google Scholar, Chapter 1. For the US, monetary policy is unusual in that it is decided in a small number of arenas that are insulated from societal pressures. Other aspects of foreign economic policy, including investment and aid as well as commercial policies, are fought over in a larger number of arenas.
31 Gardner, pp. 65–67.
32 Eckes, Alfred E. Jr., A Search for Solvency: Bretton Woods and the International Monetary System, 1941–1971 (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1975), Chapter 2Google Scholar.
33 Gardner, pp. xxx–xxxi, 118, and 312 ff; Eckes, pp. 220–22.
34 Jones, p. 95; Gardner, pp. 288–93; and Acheson, Dean, Present at the Creation: My Years in the State Department (New York: W.W. Norton, 1969), pp. 230–71Google Scholar.
35 Wilkins, pp. 300–01.
36 Gardner, pp. 77, 87 ff; Eckes, pp. 220–22;and Wilkins, p. 288.
37 Gardner, pp. 194, 349.
38 Jones, The Fifteen Weeks.
39 Ibid., pp. 5–11 and 96; Acheson, p. 226.
40 Acheson, p. 233.
41 Lowi, Theodore J., The End of Liberalism: Ideology, Policy and the Crisis of Public Authority (New York: W.W. Norton, 1969), pp. 174–75Google Scholar.
42 Eckes, pp. 224–25; Yeager, Leland B., International Monetary Relations: Theory, History and Policy, 2nd ed., (New York: Harper and Row, 1976), pp. 385–86Google Scholar.
43 Ibid., pp. 410–13; Sidney E. Rolfe and James L. Burtle, The Great Wheel: The World Monetary System, A Reinterpretation (New York: McGraw Hill, 1975), pp. 67–68.
44 Evans, p. 72.
45 Bauer, Raymond A., Pool, Ithiel de Sola, and Dexter, Lewis Anthony, American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade (New York: Atheiton, 1967), pp. 60–61, 363–72Google Scholar.
46 Because Great Britain did not enter the Common Market in the mid-1960s, this provision had little practical effect.
47 Evans, pp. 142–43.
48 Preeg, Ernest H., Traders and Diplomats: An Analysis of the Kennedy Round of Negotiations Under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1970), pp. 31–32Google Scholar; Evans, pp. 138–44.
49 Evans, pp. 167, 201–02, 230–31; Pastor, p. 28.
50 Marks and Malmgien, p. 375.
51 Information from the International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Restrictions, various years, US country pages.
52 Odell, John, “The United States in the International Monetary System: Sources of Foreign Policy Change” (Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Wisconsin, 1976)Google Scholar.
53 Conybeare, John A.C., “United States Foreign Economic Policy and the International Capital Markets: The Case of Capital Export Controls, 1963–1974” (Ph.D. Dissertation, Harvard University, 1976), Chapter 5 and pp. 231–37Google Scholar.
54 Kindleberger, Charles P., “U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, 1776–1976,” Foreign Affairs Vol. 55, No. 2 (01 1977)CrossRefGoogle Scholar: 413. The overall balance had been in deficit almost continuously after 1949.
55 Graebner, Linda S., “The New Economic Policy, 1971,” in US Commission on the Organization of the Government for the Conduct of Foreign Policy, Appendices, Vol. 3 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1975), pp. 160–61Google Scholar.
56 Vries, Tom de, “Jamaica, Or the Non-Reform of the International Monetary System,” Foreign Affairs Vol. 54, No. 3 (04 1976): 577–605CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
57 Wall Street Journal, March 16, 1976, p. 4:3; June 14, 1976, p. 7:2; and New York Times, June 17, 1976, p. 1:6.
58 Wall Street Journal, June 7, 1976, p. 1:6; December 8,1976, p. l:6; and New York Times, December 13,1975, p. 37:8.
59 For example, Sylvania has supported quotas to protect the US color television industry, while RCA, which earns considerable sums from licensing fees in Japan, has opposed them. See Wall Street Journal, December 16, 1976, p. 21:3.
60 For coherence as an important criterion for assessing policy see Katzenstein, Peter J., “International Relations and Domestic Structures: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States,” International Organization Vol. 30, No. 1 (Winter 1976): 1–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
61 Weil, pp. 53–56.
62 Kelly, William B. Jr., “Antecedents of Present Commercial Policy, 1922–1934,” in Studies in United States Commercial Policy, Kelly, William B. Jr., ed., (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1963), p. 15Google Scholar; Bauer, Dexter and Pool, pp. 27, 37.
63 NationalJournal Reports, April 17, 1976, pp. 502–04.
64 Wall Street Journal, January 1, 1976, p. 4:2; March 12, 1976, p. 24:2; March 17, 1976, p. 2:2;and New York Times, June 12,1976, p. 29:5.
65 Wall Street Journal, May 5, 1976, p. 3:1; May 6,1976, p. 5:2; July 6,1976, p. 9:1; August 11,1976, p. 2:2.
66 New York Times, December 27,1976, p. D4:4.
67 Bank for International Settlements, Fortieth Annual Report (Basle: 1970), p. 151Google Scholar; Forty-fifth Annual Report (Basle: 1975), p. 131Google Scholar.