Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T03:35:52.505Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Patterns of Legal Change: Shareholder and Creditor Rights in Transition Economies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Katharina Pistor
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor for Public Policy, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.
Get access

Extract

The reform of the enterprise sector in the former socialist countries has been at the core of the economic reform programs, which were launched ten years ago, beginning in Poland and followed by other governments throughout the region. A key element of the enterprise reform package was privatisation. Depending on the country and the specific area of the law in question, this reform measure was preceded, accompanied, or followed by legal reforms. Legal reforms in the region have been comprehensive and affected not only areas immediately relevant for the enterprise sector, but the entire legal system ranging from constitutional, administrative, criminal and civil law to the organization and procedural rules of the court system. This paper focuses on laws that are immediately relevant for the restructuring and financing of enterprises, in particular the rights of shareholders as stipulated in company laws, securities regulations, and the right of creditors as holders of collateral and in bankruptcy. The paper investigates the patterns of legal change in these areas of the law and identifies key determinants of legal change. The method employed is a formalised comparison of legal change based on pre-defined legal indicators. A data base was constructed, which codes the development of shareholder and creditor rights from 1990 through 1998 for 24 transition economies (excluding only Serbia, Tadjikistan and Turkmenistan). The paper joins a growing literature that uses cross-country formalised legal indicators to investigate the interaction between legal and economic change using statistical tools. It introduces the data used and descriptively analyses the patterns of legal change that can be observed. A statistical analysis of the interaction between legal and economic change is addressed in a separate paper.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © T.M.C. Asser Press and the Authors 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Pistor, , Law Meets the Market: Matches and Mismatches in Transition Economies, (Washington D.C., unpublished mimeo, The World Bank 1995)Google Scholar; Gray, , Evolving Legal Framework for Private Sector Development in Central and Eastern Europe, (Washington, D.C., The World Bank 1993)Google Scholar; Sachs, and Pistor, , Rule of Law and Economic Reform in Russia, (Boulder, Co., Westview Press 1997).Google Scholar

2 Porta, La et al. , “Law and Finance”, 106 Journal of Political Economy (1998) 11131155CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Porta, La et al. , “Legal Determinants of External Finance”, 52 Journal of Finance (1997) 11311150CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Levine, , “The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-Run Economic Growth”, 30 Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (1998) 596613.Google Scholar

3 Pistor, et al. , “Law and Finance in Transition Economies”, Economics of Transition (2000) (forthcoming).Google Scholar

4 North, , Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press 1990), 1st edn. (New York, Norton 1981) p. 4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

5 Easterbrook, and Fischel, , The Economic Structure of Corporate Law, (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press 1991)Google Scholar. The convergence hypothesis has been most prevalent among macro-economists. They show strong trends towards convergence in levels of GDP per capita among regions within the US. See on strong convergence of OECD countries Dorwick, and Nguyen, , “OECD Comparative Economic Growth 1950-1985”, 79 American Economic Review (1989) 10101030Google Scholar; however, only conditional convergence for developing countries Barro, and Sala-i-Martin, , “Convergence”, 100 Journal of Political Economy (1992) 223251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6 North, supra n. 4; Roe, , “Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics”, 109 Harv. L. Rev. (1996) 641668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 Coffee, , “The Future As History: The Prospects for Global Convergence in Corporate Governance and Its Implications”, 93 NW Univ L Rev. (1999) 631707Google Scholar. For a similar point based on a case study of recent trends in German corporate governance see Gordon, , “Corporate Governance: Pathways to Corporate Convergence? Two Steps on the Road to Shareholder Capitalism in Germany”, 3 Colum J Eur L (1999) 219Google Scholar. However, he correctly points out that political constraints, as well as long-term practices of insider governance may limit the scope of convergence. See ibid. at p. 241.

8 Roe (1996), supra n. 6; Bebchuk, and Roe, , “A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Governance and Ownership”, 52 Stanf. L Rev. (1999) 127CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Gordon, supra n. 7.

9 Easterbrook, and Fischel, , The Economic Structure of Corporate Law, (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press 1991)Google Scholar; Ramseyer, , “The A-Contextual Logic to the Japanese Keiretsu”, in: Roe, (ed.), Corporate Governance Today, (New York City, offset 1998) pp. 527563.Google Scholar

10 See La Porta, et al. (1998), supra n. 2, at p. 1126.

11 Black, , “Is Corporate Law Trivial?: A Political and Economic Analysis”, 84 AW Univ L Rev. (1990) 542597Google Scholar. The argument holds that efficient capital markets, well-functioning and competitive managerial labor, and product markets, are more effective constraints on managerial power than formal legal constraints.

12 Black, and Kraakman, , “A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law”, 109 Harv. L. Rev. (1996); 19111982CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Hay, et al. , “Toward a Theory of Legal Reform”, 40 European Economic Review (1996) 559567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 Shleifer, and Vishny, , “A Survey of Corporate Governance”, 52 Journal of Finance (1997) 737783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14 La Porta, et al. (1998), supra n. 2; La Porta, et al. (1997), ibid. The authors of these studies also mention the importance of effective enforcement institutions. Yet, even if these variables are controlled, the contents of legal rules and their origin seems to matter.

15 Levine (1998), supra n. 2.

16 La Porta, et al. (1998), supra n. 2.

17 Bebchuk and Roe (1999), supra n. 8; Bebchuk, , “A Rent-Protection Theory of Corporate Ownership and Control”, 7203 NBER Working Paper Series (1999)Google Scholar; Pistor, , “Law as a Determinant for Stockmarket Development in Eastern Europe”, in: Murrell, (ed.), Assessing the Value of Law in Transition Economies, (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press 2000 (forthcoming)).Google Scholar

18 Despite these differences in initial conditions, commentators agree that transition economies are increasingly converging on a control structure with concentrated ownership rather than sustaining dispersed ownership. See Berglöf, , “Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and Its Policy Implications”, in: Aoki, and Kim, (eds.), Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies, (Washington, D.C., The World Bank 1995) pp. 5998Google Scholar with data for the largest companies in three transition economies. For a theoretical explanation of the instability of non-control structures, see Bebchuk (1999), supra n. 17.

19 Brainard, , “Reform in Eastern Europe: Creating a Capital Market”, Economic Rev. (1991) 4958Google Scholar; EBRD, Transition Report (London, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) 1998).Google Scholar

20 La Porta, et al. (1998), supra n. 2.

21 Many of the countries in Central and Eastern Europe modeled their legal systems in the interwar period on the German system. In the countries of South-Eastern Europe that used to be part of the Ottoman empire, French law had stronger influence, mostly because of the reception of French law in the 19th century when the Ottoman empire reformed its legal system. Nevertheless, the borrowing does not suggest that the model was followed closely, or other legal systems were not consulted in the process. A brief summary of the history of formal private law in different countries can be found in: International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law, National Reports, (Tübingen, J.C.B. Mohr 1972)Google Scholar. For a summary of the socialist legal system, see Zweigert, and Kötz, , Einführung in die Rechtsvergleichung aufdem Gebiet des Privatrechts, 2. Aufl. (Tübingen, J.C.B. Mohr Paul Siebeck 1984) pp. 332403Google Scholar. This legal family has now been discarded from this book. See Zweigert, and Kötz, , Introduction to Comparative Law, 3rd edn. (Oxford, Clarendon Press 1998).Google Scholar

22 There is, of course, a lively debate about the relevance of legal families. The area of the law for which the legal families have been developed is the core of civil law, i.e., contract law, property rights, and torts. Constitutional and administrative law development usually do not follow the same pattern. Even for other areas of private law, including corporate law and capital market development, it is doubtful, whether a consistent set of criteria exists that makes the distinction of different legal families meaningful.

23 Pistor(1995), op. cit. n. 1.

24 Butler, , Soviet Law, 2nd edn. (London, Butterworths 1988)Google Scholar; Feldbrugge, , Russian Law: The End of the Soviet System and the Role of Law, (Dordrecht, Martinus Nijhoff Publishers 1993).Google Scholar

25 See Feldbrugge (1993), op. cit. n. 24, pp. 236-239 for details.

26 See Elster, , Offe, and Preuss, , Institutional Design in Post-communist Societies: Rebuilding the Ship at Sea, (The Hague, NL, Cambridge University Press 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, for the pattern of institutional change in Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia.

27 La Porta, et al. (1998), supra n. 2.

28 Details for the definition of variables and their coding are given in Appendix 1.

29 Part of Poland, of course, received French law during the Napoleonic wars. However, subsequent German law has been stronger.

30 Note that periodically Bosnia belonged to the Austro-Hungarian empire, but this has not strongly affected its legal development during the 19th century.

31 Owen, , The Corporation under Russian Law, 1800-1917, (The Hague, NL, Cambridge University Press 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law, National Reports, supra n. 22, 1.

32 La Porta, et al. (1998), supra n. 2.

34 Compare also the indicators for economic reforms of the EBRD in: EBRD (1998), supra n. 19.

35 Feldbrugge, op. cit. n. 24; Pistor, , “Company Law and Corporate Governance in Russia”, in: Sachs, and Pistor, (eds.), supra n. 1,pp. 165187Google Scholar; Gray, and Hendely, , “Developing Commercial Law in Transition Economies: Examples from Hungary and Russia”Google Scholar, ibid., pp. 139–164.

36 This information was given by Alexander Shapleigh of USAID. According to USAID, the results have not been equally strong in all countries. Good results were achieved in shareholder rights reforms in Armenia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan and Romania. For creditor rights, good results were reported for Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Latvia, Poland, Romania and Ukraine. Since this assessment is highly subjective, in our analysis we include all countries that have received USAID for legal reforms of shareholder and creditor rights.

37 For a discussion of the effects of the takeover guideline in Poland, see Soltysinski, , “Transfer of Legal Systems as Seen by the “Import Countries”: A View from Warsaw”, in: Drobnig, et al. (eds.), Systemtransformation in Mittel- und Osteuropa und ihre Folgen für Banken, Börsen und Kreditsicherheiten, (Tübingen, Mohr Siebeck 1998) pp. 6982Google Scholar. Compare this with the positive evaluation of the City Takeover Code for transition economies by Coffee, , “The Lessons From Securities Market Failure: Privatization, Minority Protection, and Investor Confidence”, draft of September 1999.Google Scholar

38 In comparative law methodology, analyzing the function of legal rules rather than trying to find identical legal rules in different systems has long been recognized. See Zweigert and Kötz (1984), op. cit. n. 21, who call this approach a functional approach to comparative law. Critical, however, Frankenberg, , “Critical Comparisons: Re-thinking Comparative Law”, 26 Harv. Int LJ (1985) 411455Google Scholar. On the importance of functional substitutes in corporate governance and securities market regulation, see Coffee (1999), supra n. 7.

39 Hirschman, , Exit, Voice, and Loyalty; Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States, (1970)Google Scholar; Coffee, , “Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor as Corporate Monitor”, 91 Colum. L Rev. (1991) 12771368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

40 La Porta, et al. (1997), supra n. 2.

41 Black and Kraakman, supra n. 12.

42 Berglöf (1995), supra n. 18; Berglöf, and Von, Thadden, “The Changing Corporate Governance Paradigm: Implications for Transition and Developing Countries”, Proceedings of the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics, (Washington, D.C., The World Bank 1999)Google Scholar; Porta, La et al. , “Corporate Ownership Around the World”, 54 Journal of Finance (1999) 471517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

43 Coffee (1999), supra n. 37.

44 Unfortunately, it was not possible to obtain reliable data on changes in disclosure requirements for all countries. Most laws have provisions mandating the annual disclosure of company information to their shareholders. We did not include this variable, because of the lack of variance, and because it does not reflect the extent of disclosure requirements for publicly traded companies.

45 Stigler, , “Public Regulation of the Securities Markets”, 27 Journal of Business (1964) 117142CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jarrell, , “The Economic Effects of Federal Regulation of the Market for New Security Issues”, 24 J L&Econ (1981) 613675Google Scholar; Coffee, , “Market Failure and the Economic Case for a Mandatory Disclosure System”, 70 Virg. L Rev. (1984) 717753CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Seligman, , “The Historical Need for a Mandatory Corporate Disclosure System,” 9 J Corp L (1983) 161Google Scholar; Hopt, and Baum, , “Bör-senrechtsreform in Deutschland”, in: Hopt, et al. (eds.), Börsenreform - Eine ökonomische, rechts-vergleichende und rechtspolitische Untersuchung, (Stuttgart, Schäffer-Poeschel Verlag 1997) pp. 287467Google Scholar. The debate is now taking a new turn, where the importance of (some) regulation is acknowledged in principle, but the need for federal versus state (or decentral) regulation debated. See Romano, , “Empowering Investors: A market Approach to Securities Regulation”, 107 Yale Law Journal (1998) 23592430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

46 Pistor (1999), supra n. 17; Coffee (1999), supra n. 37. For experiences in other parts of the world see also Rosen, , “The Myth of Self-Regulation or the Dangers of Securities Regulation Without Administration: The Indian Experience”, 2 J Comp Corp L & Sec Reg (1979) 261302Google Scholar, as well as Pistor, and Wellons, , The Role of Law and Legal Institutions in Asian Economic Development, (Hong Kong, Oxford University Press 1999), ch. 6.Google Scholar

47 Pistor (1999), supra n. 17.

48 This requirement typically does not apply to all joint stock companies, but only those which exceed the stipulated number of shareholders, i.e., 500 in the case of Russia and Kazakhstan.

49 Pistor (1997), supra n. 35.

51 In fact, in the early period many of the former Soviet Union republics required 60%. This may, however, be counter-productive, because it decreases the likelihood for a shareholder meeting to reach the quorum.

52 Berglöf, , “Reforming Corporate Governance: Redirecting the European Agenda”, 24 Economic Policy (1997) 93119Google Scholar; Coffee (1999), supra n. 7.

53 On the pros and cons of the US Bankruptcy Code see Baird, , The Elements of Bankruptcy, (New York, Westbury 1993) p. 283.Google Scholar

54 Gray and Hendely (1997), supra n. 35.

55 Wood, , Comparative Law of Security and Guarantees, Law and Practice of International Finance (London, Sweet and Maxwell 1995).Google Scholar

56 Oda, , “Law on Secured Transaction in Russia”, in: Simons, (ed.), The Russian Civil Code, (The Hague, Kluwer Law International 2000) (forthcoming).Google Scholar

57 Pistor, op. cit. n. 1; Summers, , “Recent Secured Transaction Law Reform in the Newly Independent States and Central and Eastern Europe”, 23 Rev of Central and Eastern European Law (1997) 177203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

58 For a detailed analysis of Russian law on security interests see Oda, supra n. 56.

59 EBRD, Model Law on Secured Transactions, (London, EBRD 1994).Google Scholar

60 According to information obtained from the EBRD, the following countries have established registers for security interests which used the EBRD model law or US law: Azerbaijan (1998); Belarus (1999); Bulgaria (1996); Estonia (1996); FYR Macedonia (1998); Georgia (1997); Hungary (1997); Kazakhstan (1998); Kyrgyzstan (1997); Latvia (1999); Lithuania (1998); Moldova (1996 – simplified version now under revision); Poland (1998); Romania (1999); Ukraine (1997/99); Uzbekistan (1998). The enactment of these laws, however, is only the first step. Functioning registries for security interests in movables apparently exist as of now only in Bulgaria, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, with some reservations in Poland, and apparently since March 1999 in Ukraine.

61 Summers (1997), supra n. 57.

62 An example is the German law on concerns. Art. 317 of the German law on marketable share companies (AktG), for example, states that a company which controls another one without having concluded a control contract, may be held liable for damages incurred by that company or its shareholders, if it made that company conclude detrimental transactions without compensation.

63 Compare Art. 106 of the Russian Civil Code with Art. 6, section 3 of the Joint Stock Companies Act.

64 Note: since we do not code for law in the former Yugoslav republics, our coding is likely to overstate the absence of law in this region.

65 Information obtained from the EBRD.

66 Oda (1999), supra n. 56.

67 Note that they were first included in the Civil Code, which borrowed heavily from the Dutch Civil Code.

68 Avilov, et al. , General Principles of Company Law for Transition Economies, (OECD, 1999)Google Scholar, strongly advocate that such provisions should be strictly limited to these cases.

69 Roe, , “Some Differences in Corporate Structure in Germany, Japan, and the United States”, 102 Yale LJ (1993) 19272003CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Berglöf (1995), supra n. 18; Aoki, , “Controlling Insider Control: Issues of Corporate Governance in Transition Econmies”, in: Aoki, and Kim, (eds.), supra n. 18, pp. 332.Google Scholar

70 Rostowski, , “The Banking System, Credit and the Real Sector in Transition Economies”, in: Rostowski, (ed.), Banking Reform in Central Europe and the Former Soviet Union, (Budapest, CEU Press 1995) pp. 1641Google Scholar; Dittus, and Prowse, , “Corporate Control in Central Europe and Russia: Should Banks Own Shares?”, in: Frydman, et al. (eds.), Corporate Governance in Central Europe and Russia, (London, Central European University Press 1996), Vol. 1, pp. 2067.Google Scholar

71 Corbett, and Mayer, , “Financial Reform in Eastern Europe: Progress with the Wrong Model”, Oxf. Rev. Econ Pol (1992).Google Scholar

72 Berglöf (1995), supra n. 18.

73 Buch, , “Creating Efficient Banking Systems”, in: Sieber, (ed.), Kieler Studien, (Tübingen, J.C.B. Mohr 1996)Google Scholar; Baer, and Gray, , “Debt as a Control Device in Transitional Economies: The Experience of Hungary and Poland,” in: Frydman, et al. (eds.) supra n. 70, vol. 1, pp. 68110Google Scholar; EBRD, Transition Report - Financial Sector in Transition, (London, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) 1998).

74 Claessens, et al. , Ownership and Corporate Governance: Evidence from the Czech Republic, International Symposium on Capital Markets and Enterprise Reform (Washington D.C., World Bank 1996).Google Scholar

75 Coffee, , “Inventing a Corporate Monitor for Transitional Economies: The Uncertain Lessons from the Czech and Polish Experiences”, in: Hopt, et al. (eds.), Comparative Corporate Governance - The Slate of the Art and Emerging Research (Oxford, Clarendon Press 1998) pp. 67138.Google Scholar

76 Obviously, this can be only a rough estimate of the relative importance of shareholder and creditor rights, as the variables included are not encompassing, and not all variables may have equal weight.

77 EBRD (1998), supra n. 19, p. 118.

78 Boycko, et al. , “Voucher Privatization”, 35 Journal of Financial Economics (1993) 249CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Frydman, and Rapaczynski, , “Markets and Institutions in Large Scale Privatization: An Approach to Economic and Social Transformation in Eastern Europe”, in: Corbo, et al. (eds.), Reforming Central and Eastern European Economies: Initial Results and Challenges, (Washington, D.C., The World Bank 1992) pp. 253274Google Scholar; Classens et al., (1996), supra n. 74.

79 EBRD (1998), supra n. 19.

80 La Porta, et al. (1997), supra n. 2.

81 Blumberg, , The Multinational Challenge to Corporation Law (New York, Oxford University Press 1993) p. 316Google Scholar; Dunlavy, , “Corporate Governance in the Late 19th Century Europe and USA – The Case of Shareholder Voting Rights”, in: Hopt, et al. (ed.), supra n. 75, pp. 539Google Scholar. Accounts of the development of corporate law in the US and Germany since the 19th century show a close interaction between legal and economic development. See Assmann, in: Hopt, and Wiedemann, (eds.), Aktiengesetz: Groβkommentar, Introduction, Vol. I for Germany, (Berlin, Walter de Gruyter 1992)Google Scholar. For a summary of the development in the US, cf. Coffee, , “The Mandatory/Enabling Balance in Corporate Law: An Essay on the Judicial Role”, 89 Colum. L Rev. (1989) 16181691 and Black and Kraakman, supra n. 12CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Note also that the enactment of extensive minority shareholder protection in the US in 1933/4 follows on the heels of the publication of the famous book by Berle, and Means, , The Modern Corporation and Private Property, (New York, Council for Research in the Social Sciences, Columbia University 1932)Google Scholar, in which they point out the weakness of dispersed small shareholders vis-à-vis company management. Response driven legal evolution has also been observed for the development of corporate law and securities regulations in emerging markets in Asia. See Pistor and Wellons, op. cit. n. 46.

82 Pistor, , “Privatization and Corporate Governance in Russia: An Empirical Study” in: McFaul, and Perlmutter, (eds.) Privatization, Conversion and Enterprise Reform in Russia (Boulder, West view Press 1995), pp. 6984Google Scholar; Pistor, supra n. 35; Coffee, , “Institutional Investors in Transitional Economies: Lessons from the Czech Experience”Google Scholar, in: Frydman et al., supra n. 70; Black, , Kraakman, and Tarassova, , Russian Privatization and Corporate Governance: What Went Wrong? (Stanford, John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics 1999)Google Scholar. Among economists, there was little interest in the extent and effectiveness of the law at the outset of reform. In their attempt to explain the extremely low valuation of Russian companies in privatization, Boycko et al., do not even discuss the possible role of the weak legal environment: Boycko, et al. , “Privatizing Russia”, Brookings Papers for Economic Activity (1993) 139180Google Scholar. But see Sachs in his comments to that paper, ibid., p. 181 with reference to Pistor (1995, ibid.).

83 Pistor, supra n. 17.

84 Bebchuk (1999), supra n. 17.

85 La Porta, et al., supra n. 42.

86 Bebchuck (1999), supra n. 17

88 Frydman, , Pistor, and Rapaczynski, , “Investing in Insider-Dominated Firms: A Study of Russian Voucher Privatization Funds”, in: Frydman, et al. (eds.), supra n. 70, pp. 187241Google Scholar. Filatov, et al. , Insider Control and Managerial Entrenchment in Privatised Firms in Russia: Analysis and Policy Implications (Nottingham, University of Nottingham Business School 1999).Google Scholar

89 A first attempt is made in Pistor et al. (2000) supra n. 3. Using data on the effectiveness of legal institutions (legality) they show that countries differ remarkably in this respect and that these differences can explain differences in financial market development in transition economies. Using a large sample set (which excludes transition economies), Berkowitz, Pistor and Richard, show that domestic demand for a transplanted legal order is an important determinant for the long-term development of legality (Berkowitz, , Pistor, and Richard, , Economic Development, Legality and the Transplant Effect, EBRD mimeo (1999)).Google Scholar