Published online by Cambridge University Press: 03 June 2009
The view that the opening up of Africa by metropolitan capitalism, particularly during the period of direct colonial rule, was bound to lead through evolutionary stages to economic development and modernisation has long since fallen into scholarly disrepute. In the atmosphere of radical pessimism that has pervaded academic perspectives on Africa since independence, an altogether more sceptical view of the beneficence of Africa's integration into imperial economies has prevailed. But as is often the case in scholarly debate, thesis and antithesis occupy the same battleground, and both tend to view the world through similar lenses. What modernisation and underdevelopment theories have in common is the assumption of a single universal dynamic in the making of the modern world; exposure to market forces is thus apparently destined either to reshape third world societies in the image of industrial Europe, or to “underdevelop” them in the interests of capital accumulation in the metropoles.
1 Brenner, Robert, “The Origins of Capitalist Development: A Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism,” New Left Review, 104 (07–08 1977), 25–92.Google Scholar
2 A review of this literature is to be found in Ian Roxborough, Theories of Underdevelopment (London, 1979).Google ScholarPubMed
3 See Hyden, Goran, Beyond Ujamaa: Underdevelopment and an Uncaptured Peasantry(London, 1980), 21–23Google Scholar, who asserts that the optimal interests of Western capitalism requiredthe replacement of pre-existing productive relationships. For explicitly Marxist perspectives that tend in different ways toward the view that underdevelopment is a consequence of insufficient exploitation by metropolitan capital, thereby resurrecting a more classical Marxist position. see Kay, Geoffrey, Development and Underdevelopment A Marxist Analysis (London, 1975)Google Scholar; Warren, Bill, Imperialism: Pioneer of Capitalism (London 1980).Google Scholar
4 See Lonsdale, John and Berman, Bruce, “Coping with the Contradictions: The Development of the Colonial State in Kenya, 1895–1914,” Journal of African History, 20:4 (1979). 487–505CrossRefGoogle Scholar; McCarthy, D. M. P., “Organising Underdevelopment from the Inside: The Bureaucratic Economy of Tanganyika, 1918–1940,” International Journal of African Historical Studies, 10:4 (1977), 576–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Colonial administrators were often concerned to prevent the exclusionary accumulation of resources by individuals from getting out of hand and to obstruct precolonial political elites from taking advantage of new opportunities to extend their control over land and labour beyond a point of safety. See Iliffe, John, The Emergence of African Capitalism (London 1983), 35–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Munro, J. Forbes, Britain in Tropical Africa, 1880–1960: Economic Relationships and Impact (London 1984), 46CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For specific instances in East Africa, see Wrigley, C. C., Crops and Wealth in Uganda (Kampala 1959), 48–55Google Scholar; Iliffe, John, A Modern History of Tanganyika (Cambridge 1979), 274–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Many scholars emphasise the extent to which economic paternalism undermined the accumulation of resources amongst rural producers by, for example, inhibiting too much specialisation in the growing of cash crops, which threatened to dissolve the cohesion of African productive systems. Many blame interventionist policies for the failure of African entrepreneurship to maintain its early momentum by, for example, creating marketing monopolies and restraining African commercial initiative. As a recent example from a large literature (much of which tends toward an ahistorical and dubious assumption that “free markets” lead inexorably to economic development), see Rimmer, Douglas, “The Economic Imprint of Colonialism and Domestic Food Supplies in British Tropical Africa” in Imperialism. Colonialism, and Hunger: East and Central Africa, Rotberg, Robert, ed. (Lexington Mass., 1983), 141–65.Google Scholar On the other hand, Cooper, Frederick, in 'Africa and the World Economy,“ African Studies Review, 24:2/3 (1981), 1–86, has interpreted the massive increase in bureaucratic attempts to control production methods and marketing in the 1940s and 1950s (when attitudes and imperatives had changed) as a consequence of the failure of colonial administrations to get African peasants to produce cash crops of the type and in the quantities they wanted.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
5 As an example from what is now a considerable body of literature, see Kitching, Gavin, Class and Economic Change in Kenya: The Making of an African Petite-Bourgeoisie (New Haven, 1980).Google Scholar The older conventional wisdom is reflected in, for example, Wolff, R. D., The Economics of Colonialism: Britain and Kenya, 1870–1930 (New Haven, 1974).Google Scholar
6 The image is that evoked in Palmer, Robin and Parsons, Neil, eds., The Roots of Rural Poverty in Central and Southern Africa (London 1977).Google Scholar See also Palmer, Robin, Land and Racial Domination in Rhodesia (London 1977).Google Scholar
7 Ranger, T. O., “Growing from the Roots: Reflections on Peasant Research in Central and Southern Africa,” Journal of Southern African Studies, 5:1 (1978), 99–133CrossRefGoogle Scholar; McCracken, John, “Rethinking Rural Poverty,” Journal of African History, 19:4 (1978), 611–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mosley, Paul, The Settler Economies: Studies in the Economic History of Kenya and Southern Rhodesia, 1900–1963 (Cambridge 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, ch. 3. The fragility and dependence on state supports of settler farming are revealed in Hodder-Williams, Richard, White Farmers in Rhodesia: A History of Marandellas District, 1890–1965 (London 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
8 Palmer, Robin, “White Farmers in Malawi: Before and After the Depression,” African Affairs, 84:335 (1985), 211–45.CrossRefGoogle ScholarCf. idem, “Land Alienation and Agricultural Conflict in Colonial Zambia” in Imperialism, Colonialism, and Hunger, Rotberg, , ed., 89–112.Google Scholar
9 Trapido, Stanley, “Reflections on Land, Office, and Wealth in the South African Republic, 1850–1900” in Economy and Society in Pre-Industrial South Africa, Marks, Shula and Atmore, Anthony, eds. (London 1980), 350–68Google Scholar; Keegan, Timothy, Rural Transformations in Industrialising South Africa (LondonNew York, and Johannesburg, 1986)Google Scholar, ch. 1. The last frontier for some of the older forms of rural accumulation was to be found in the colonies of white settlement farther north. Organised treks across the Limpopo River were common in the 1880s and 1890s; and many Boers settled in Kenya after the turn of the century. Sorrenson, M. P. K., Origins of European Settlement in Kenya (London 1968), 65–66, 229–30Google Scholar; Mosley, , Settler Economies, 186.Google Scholar
10 Timothy Keegan, “White Settlement and Black Subjugation on the South African High-veld: The Tlokoa Heartland in the Northeastern Orange Free State, 1850–1914,” and Delius, Peter, “Abel Erasmus: Power and Profit in the Eastern Transvaal,” both in Putting a Plough to the Ground: Accumulation and Dispossession in Rural South Africa, 1850–1930, Beinart, William and Delius, Peter, eds. (Johannesburg and London 1986), 218–58, 176–217.Google Scholar
11 Delius, Peter and Trapido, Stanley, “lnboekselings and Oorlams: The Creation and Transformation of a Servile Class” in Town and Countryside in the Transvaal: Capitalist Penetration and Popular Response, Bozzoli, Belinda, ed. (Johannesburg, 1983), 53–88.Google Scholar
12 Trapido, Stanley, “Landlord and Tenant in a Colonial Economy: The Transvaal, 1880–1910,” Journal of Southern African Studies, 5:1 (1978), 26–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13 Moore, Barrington, The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston 1966)Google Scholar; Trapido, Stanley, “South Africa in a Comparative Study of lndustrialisation,” Journal of Development Studies, 7:3 (1971), 309–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Legassick, Martin, “South Africa: Capital Accumulation and Violence,” Economy and Society, 3:3 (1974). 253–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Morris, M. L., “The Development of Capitalism in South African Agriculture: Class Struggle in the Countryside,” Economy and Society, 5:3 (1976), 292–343CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Greenberg, Stanley, Race and State in Capitalist Development: Comparative Perspectives (New Haven, 1980)Google Scholar; Cooper, Frederick, “Peasants, Capitalists, and Historians: A Review Article,” Journal of Southern African Studies, 7:2 (1981), 284–314CrossRefGoogle Scholar, esp. 300–301. For other attempts at comparison, see Kay, Cristobal, “Comparative Development of the European Manorial System and the Latin American Hacienda System,” Journal of Peasant Studies, 2:1 (1974), 69–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wiener, Jonathan M., “Class Structure and Economic Development in the American South, 1865–1955,” American Historical Review, 84:4 (1979), 970–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and see also “Special Issue on Feudalism and Non-European Societies” of the Journal of Peasant Studies, 12:2/3 (1985).Google Scholar
14 Goodman, David and Redclift, Michael, From Peasant to Proletarian: Capitalist Development and Agrarian Transitions (Oxford 1981), 102.Google Scholar
15 Mosley tells us that many early agricultural settlers in Southem Rhodesia were prospectors or alternated periods on the land with periods in retailing or government employment. In Kenya, “most” early settlers had alternative sources of income, like cutting wood for the railways (Settler Economies, 186). See also Hodder-Williams, , White Farmers in Rhodesia, 24–25Google Scholar: “…it was as intermediaries between the rural Shona and the growing urban centres that most ‘farmers’ made their living.“ These observations prompt wider comparisons with the incomplete forms of accumulation typical of some black rural economies in Africa. What has been called ”straddling“—the process whereby money earned in the wage sector or in trade is ploughed back into rural production—has been common amongst Africa's black farmers (Iliffe, Emergence of African Capitalism, 31Google Scholar; Cooper, ”Africa and World Economy,“ 42–44).Google Scholar Kitching describes in detail those black rural accumulators of Kenya who had larger landholdings and who increasingly employed members of poorer families for wages; usually these landholders were also better educated and held white-collar or clerical or teaching jobs, as well as trading interests, and hence they had greater access to nonagricultural income. Similarly, Beinart shows that in Pondoland, the initial extension of rural production was made possible by, and accompanied, the generalisation of labour migrancy, thus contradicting Bundy's assertion that mass labour migrancy was a function of the decline of peasant production. Of course this process did not proceed very far in Pondoland, which eventually was to degenerate into a labour reserve (Kitching, , Class and Economic Change, esp. 364–72Google Scholar; Beinart, William, The Political Economy of Pondoland, 1860–1930 (Cambridge 1983)Google Scholar; Bundy, Colin, The Rise and Fall of the South African Peasantry (London, 1979)). Underdevelopment theorists tend to see the farmer-worker primarily as subsidising the capitalist sector through rural household production, but the phenomenon can perhaps be better understood historically by looking at the dynamics of the rural economy rather than at the requirements of capital.Google Scholar
16 See Men of the Times: Old Colonists of the Cape Colony and the Orange River Colony (Cape Town, 1906), 631–32Google Scholar; for the case of Gradwell, W. B. of Bloemfontein district, see obituary in South Africa (London), 20 02 1925, p. 331. Fuller documentation of points raised here is provided in Keegan, Rural Transformations, ch. 4.Google Scholar
17 The Newberrys provide a telling example. From The Friend (Bloemfontein)Google ScholarPubMed, see ”Jottings from the Conquered Territory,“ 16 03 1894Google Scholar; ”Chips from Moroka,“ 15 04 1892Google Scholar; ”Opening of the New Leeuw River Mills,” 108 1893Google Scholar; “Notes from Ladybrand and District,' 18 08 1893.Google Scholar Also see letter of Harper, F. J. to editor, The Farmer's Advocate (Bloemfontein), 12 1912, p. 193Google Scholar; Bloemfontein Archives (hereafter cited as BAD), CS 4873/07, Director of Agriculture, 19 07 1907.Google Scholar
18 The Annual Cape Colonial Blue Books (magisterial reports) contain masses of evidence on booms and slumps in land transactions.
19 Generally, see Standard Bank Archives, Johannesburg, Annual Branch Inspection Reports.
20 On Nourse, see Dictionary of South African Biography, (Pretoria, 1977), III, 659–60Google Scholar; Men of the Times: Pioneers of the Transvaal and Glimpses of South Africa (Johannesburg 1905), 2829Google Scholar; BAD, NAB 861/07, Gedye, J. B., 27 08 1907.Google Scholar On Bailey's activities, see “Free State: Our Production Possibilities,” The Friend, 20 01 1911Google Scholar; Rosenthal, Eric, Other Men's Millions (Cape Town, n.d.), 178.Google Scholar On Lewis and Marks' farming enterprises, see Dictionary of South African Biography (Pretoria 1968), I, 515–18Google Scholar; “A Great Property,” The Farmer's Advocate, 10 1907, pp. 85–90.Google Scholar On the Bourkes' estates, see BAD, DA 1915/2/09, Daw, G. H., 24 06 1909.Google Scholar
21 E.g., African Farms Limited had sixty farms being worked by white managers or tenants in 1908. The company's goal was to make its farms “self-supporting” and, “if possible,” profitable. To this end the company not only provided capital, but it gathered and indexed “every kind of information which promises to eliminate the element of chance,” thus echoing the kind of entrepreneurial role in promoting scientific agriculture evident in the activities of other large landlords on the Highveld, such as the Duke of Westminster (“Farmers of Orangia,” The Farmer's Advocate, 04 1908, pp. 413–15Google Scholar; “African Farms Ltd.,” Ibid., June 1908, p. 573; “Our Weekly Causerie,” Farmer's Weekly, 10 07 1918, p. 2099).Google Scholar
22 E.g., see “Mr. S. G. Vilonel at De Rust,” The Farmer's Advocate, 03 1908, pp. 371–73.Google Scholar
23 Cartwright, A. P., The First South African: The Life and Times of Sir Percy Fitzpatrick (Cape Town, 1971), 119–20.Google Scholar
24 Trapido, Stanley, “Poachers, Proleta?ans, and Gentry in the Early Twentieth Century Transvaal,” manuscript, African Studies Seminar, University of the Witwatersrand, 1984.Google Scholar
25 “Another Diamond Mine,” The Friend, 20 May 1898Google Scholar; “Mr. Minter's Steam Plough,” Ibid.: Baumann, G. and Bright, E., The Lost Republic: The Biography of a Land Surveyor (London 1940), 141–52Google Scholar; Trapido, Stanley, “A History of Tenant Production on the Vereeniging Estates, 1896–1920” in Putting a Plough to the Ground, Beinart, and Delius, , eds., 336–72Google Scholar; Standard Bank Archives, Inspection Reports, Kroonstad, 1915.
26 Letter of Seggie, R. to editor, The Friend, 22 02 1912.Google Scholar
27 BAD, DA 1997/1/09, Fitzpatrick, P., 14 06 1909. Cf. the experience of Lord Delamere, Kenya's leading capitalist farmer, who soon discovered that his traction engine was not nearly as satisfactory as “Boer methods” of ploughing (Mosley, Settler Economies, 187). In a situation of “cheap labour, dear capital and high risk,” the use of outdated or improvised equipment and labour-intensive methods was highly appropriate, asserts Mosley.Google Scholar
28 See Keegan, , Rural Transformations, ch. 3Google Scholar; also idem, “The Sharecropping Economy on the South African Highveld in the Early Twentieth Century,” Journal of Peasant Studies, 10:2/3 (1983), 201–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
29 The spread of sharecropping in non-European parts of the world not uncommonly accompanied or followed integration into international markets. Sharecropping is entirely compatible with rural capitalism and is often found in economies in which market production is generalised and predominant. See the several contributions in Byres, T. J., ed., Sharecropping and Sharecroppers (London 1983).Google Scholar
30 The notion that the provider of land can be the economically weaker participant in the sharecropping agreement might seem strange to observers of sharecropping elsewhere in the world. The seigneurial stereotype of sharecropping, derived from the image of the European, Latin American, or Asian great estate, where a wealthy, exploitative landholder typically controls a large, impoverished tenantry, is clearly not applicable to the South African case. It has often been assumed that sharecropping did and does not exist in Africa, because of the obvious absence of the seigneurial pattern. However, recent research has shown that share contracts in fact have a long pedigree in Africa and seem typically to have been relatively equitable relationships between households by means of which scarce resources were combined in an efficient manner in order to ensure mutual survival and expanded production. Sharecropping can also be a means whereby resources are transferred within kin groups or between generations (Robertson, A. F., “On Sharecropping,” Man, 15:3 (1980), 411–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar; idem, “Abusa: The Structural History of an Economic Contract,” Journal of Development Studies, 18:4 (1982), 447–78)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Share-contracting is widely practised in parts of southern Africa today, and in these contexts it seems to be a means of ensuring the survival of the household fanning economy in areas that are no longer capable of sustaining their populations without sending out migrants to service the industrial economy of white South Africa. There is little class differentiation in such relationships, which seem by and large to be determined by cyclical, generational factors. See Murray, Colin, Families Divided: The Impact of Migrant Labour in Lesotho (Cambridge 1981), 75–85.Google Scholar
31 Cf the sharp contrast with colonial settlers in Nyasaland, who abandoned pretensions to being capitalist farmers after the Great Depression and came to rely on income from black tenant fanning (Palmer, “White Farmers in Malawi”).
32 Editorial, , The Friend, 4 02 1908Google Scholar; also evidence, E. R. Grobler's, Natives Land Commission, Minutes of Evidence, UG (Union Government) 22–1916 (Pretoria 1916), 81.Google Scholar
33 See Ross, Robert, “The First Two Centuries of Colonial Agriculture in the Cape Colony: A Historiographical Review” in Putting a Plough to the Ground, Beinart, and Delius, , eds., 56–99.Google Scholar
34 Marks, Shula and Trapido, Stanley, “Lord Milner and the South African State,” History' Workshop Journal, 8 (Autumn 1979), 59–80.Google Scholar
35 For a detailed investigation of the political processes involved, see Bozzoli, Belinda, The Political Nature of a Ruling Class: Capital and Ideology in South Africa, 1890–1933 (London 1981).Google Scholar
36 See Adam, Heribert and Giliomee, Hermann, Ethnic Power Mobilized: Can South Africa Change? (New Haven, 1979), ch. 6Google Scholar; Davies, Robert, Kaplan, David, Morris, Mike and O'Meara, Dan, “Class Struggle and the Periodisation of the State in South Africa,” Review of African Political Economy, 7 (09–12 1976), 4–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
37 For an overview, see Wilson, Francis, “Farming, 1866–1966,” in Oxford History of South Africa, Wilson, Monica and Thompson, Leonard, eds. (Oxford 1971), 11, 104–71Google Scholar; Horwitz, Ralph, The Political Economy of South Africa (London 1967), 148–54. 1934Google Scholar white farmers' debts already amounted to 100 million pounds sterling (Report of the Commission to Inquire into Co-operation and Agricultural Credit, UG 16–1934 (Pretoria 1934), 153–54). See Note 46.Google Scholar
One crucial but less tangible aspect of state intervention lay in the field of education. The state provided an altogether more sophisticated schooling to new generations of Afrikaner youths than was available to their semiliterate forebears, and improved scientific methods and techniques were tirelessly propagated through the extension services of the Department of Agriculture and in farming journals.
38 Cooper, , “Africa and the World Economy,” 18. Amongst those who were excluded in the process were, of course, many whites, including very large numbers of the old Boer population, former landowners as well as those who had never owned land. But the poor whites of the twentieth century were not on their way to becoming a rural proletariat, unlike the black tenants, due, again, in large part to state policies.Google Scholar
39 This is no longer a novel observation of course: see Bundy, Rise and Fall of the South African Peasantry.
40 The points made in this paragraph are fully elaborated in Keegan, T., “Crisis and Catharsis in the Development of Capitalism in South African Agriculture,” African Affairs, 84:336 (1985), 371–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
41 See Richards, Alan, “The Political Economy of Gutswirtschaft A Comparative Analysis of East Elbian Germany, Egypt, and Chile,” Comparative Studies in Society and Riston, 21:4 (1979), 483–518, for comparative perspectives on labour tenancy emphasising its utility in situations of incomplete control over labour.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
42 The changes in the rural areas in the crucial years since World War I constitute one of the major lacunae in our understanding of contemporary South Africa, and a great deal of research needs to be done. This paragraph is based on oral evidence to be found in the Oral History Project, African Studies Institute, University of the Witwatersrand, Johannesburg. As a telling example, see Nkadimeng, Malete and Relly, Georgina, “Kas Maine: The Story of a Black South African Agriculturist,” in Town and Countryside in the Transvaal, Bozzoli, , ed., 89–107.Google Scholar
43 See Morris, , “Development of Capitalism”: Greenberg, Race and State, chs. 4–5Google Scholar; Morris, M. L., “Apartheid, Agriculture, and the State,” South African Labour and Development Research Unit Working Paper no. 8, University of Cape Town (1977).Google Scholar
44 According to the very unreliable statistics available, a substantial difference in productivity between black and white farming has developed since the 1940s. But Merle Lipton has persuasively argued that official statistics greatly underestimate output per hectare in the black reserves, and that output per unit cost might indeed be greater than on white farms, despite the absence of incentives and the overcrowded and overexploited condition of reserve land (“South Africa: Two Agricultures?” in Farm Labour in South Africa, Wilson, Francis, Kooy, Alide, and Hendrie, Delia, eds. (Cape Town, 1977), 72–85. Also see Murray, , Families Divided, 7–8).Google Scholar
45 On the consequences of mechanisation, see Klerk, Mike de, “Seasons that Will Never Return: The Impact of Farm Mechanisation on Employment, Incomes, and Population Distribution in the Western Transvaal,” Journal of Southern African Studies, 11:1 (1984), 84–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar On population shifts, see the five-volume report of the Surplus People Project, Forced Removals in South Africa (Cape Town, 1983)Google ScholarPubMed. An overview is provided in Freund, Bill, “Forced Resettlement and the Political Economy of South Africa,” Review of African Political Economy, 29 (07 1984), 49–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
46 By 1985, farmers' debts exceeded 8,000 million rands, despite the massive weeding out of failed farmers over previous decades. Indeed, in September 1985, according to a South African Broadcasting Corporation news report, a prominent farmers' representative predicted that a “second Great Trek” from the land was in the offing, similar in scope to that which accompanied the Great Depression of the 1930s.
47 Goodman, and Redclift, , From Peasant to Proletarian. 13.Google Scholar
48 Ibid. 16–18.
49 Franklin, S. H., Rural Societies (London, 1971), 12–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Franklin notes that “the majority of holdings in Western Europe are uneconomic and with no prospect of becoming viable” (p. 22). See also idem, The European Peasantry (London 1969), 36.Google Scholar
50 See Friedmann, Harriet, “World Market, State, and Family Farm: Social Bases of Household Production in the Era of Wage Labor,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 20:4 (1978), 545–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
51 See Legassick, Martin, “The Frontier Tradition in South African Historiography,” in Economy and Society in Pre-Industrial South Africa, Marks and Atmore, eds., 44–79.Google Scholar
52 See O'Meara, Dan, Volkskapitalisme: Class, Capital, and Ideology in the Development of Afrikaner Nationalism, 1934–1948 (Cambridge, 1983).Google Scholar