Published online by Cambridge University Press: 11 May 2011
Economics and history both strive to understand causation: economics by using instrumental variables econometrics, and history by weighing the plausibility of alternative narratives. Instrumental variables can lose value with repeated use because of an econometric tragedy of the commons: each successful use of an instrument creates an additional latent variable problem for all other uses of that instrument. Economists should therefore consider historians' approach to inferring causality from detailed context, the plausibility of alternative narratives, external consistency, and recognition that free will makes human decisions intrinsically exogenous.
1 Lazear, Edward, “Economic Imperialism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, no. 1 (Feb. 2000): 99–146CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fischer, Irving, “Statistics in the Service of Economics,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 28, no. 181 (Mar. 1933): 1–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar; McCloskey, Deirdre N., The Rhetoric of Economics (Madison, Wisc., 1985).Google Scholar
2 Ford, Henry, with Crowther, Samuel, My Life and Work (Garden City, N.Y., 1922), 43–44Google Scholar; McLuhan, Marshall, The Gutenberg Galaxy: The Making of Typographic Man (Toronto, 1962)Google Scholar; Derrida, Jacques, De la Grammatologie (Paris, 1967).Google Scholar
3 Lamoreaux, Naomi R., Raff, Daniel M. G., and Temin, Peter, “Economic Theory and Business History,” in The Oxford Handbook of Business History, ed. Jones, Geoffrey and Zeitlin, Jonathan (Oxford, 2007), ch. 3Google Scholar; Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise (Cambridge, Mass., 1962)Google Scholar; Wilkins, Mira, The Emergence of Multinational Enterprise (Cambridge, Mass. 1970)Google Scholar; Hertner, Peter and Jones, Geoffrey, Multinationals: Theory and History (Aldershot, U.K., 1986)Google Scholar; Jones, Geoffrey, Multinationals and Global Capitalism: From the Nineteenth to the Twenty-First Century (Oxford, 2005); and many others.Google Scholar
4 Popper, Carl, Logik der Forschung (Vienna, 1934).Google Scholar
5 Wilson, Edward O., Consilience: The Unity of Knowledge (New York, 1998), 47.Google Scholar
6 Kuhn, Thomas, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago, 1962).Google Scholar
7 Malthus, Thomas, An Essay on the Principle of Population (London, 1798), 4.Google Scholar
8 Edgeworth, Francis, Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences (London, 1881), 77, 79.Google Scholar
9 Galbraith, John Kenneth, The New Industrial State (London, 1967), 36.Google Scholar
10 Levy, David and Peart, Sandra, “Soviet Growth and American Textbooks,” Economics Department, George Mason University working paper, 2009.Google Scholar
11 Krugman, Paul, The Conscience of a Liberal (New York, 2007)Google Scholar; Sachs, Jeffrey, The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time (New York, 2005)Google Scholar; Stiglitz, Joseph, Making Globalization Work (New York, 2006).Google Scholar
12 Rajan, Raghuram and Zingales, Luigi, Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists (Princeton, 2004)Google Scholar; Feldstein, Martin, “Rethinking the Role of Fiscal Policy,” American Economic Review 99, no. 2 (2009): 556–59; James Buchanan, “Public Choice: The Origins and Development of a Research Program,” Center for the Study of Public Choice at George Mason University, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13 Kuhn, Thomas, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago, 1962).Google Scholar
14 Black, Fischer, “The Trouble with Econometric Models,” Financial Analysts Journal 38, no. 2 (1982): 29–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
15 Diamond, Jared and Robinson, James A., eds., Natural Experiments of History (Cambridge Mass., 2010).Google Scholar
16 Godley, Andrew, Jewish Immigrant Entrepreneurship in New York and London, 1880–1914: Enterprise and Culture (New York, 2001).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
17 Henry, Peter and Miller, Conrad, “Institutions versus Policies: A Tale of Two Islands,” American Economic Review 99, no. 2 (2009): 261–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
18 King, Robert, and Levine, Ross, “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, no. 3 (1993): 717–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
19 Camerer, Colin, Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction (Princeton, 2010)Google Scholar; Deaton, Angus, “Instruments, Randomization, and Learning about Development,” Journal of Economic Literature 48 (June 2010): 424–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
20 Diamond and Robinson, eds., Natural Experiments of History.
21 Tobin, James, “Money and Income: Post Hoc Ergo Propter Hoc?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, no. 2 (1970): 301–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
22 Banerjee, Abhijit and Iver, Lakshmi, “Colonial Land Tenure, Electoral Competition and Public Goods in India,” in Natural Experiments of History, ed. Diamond, Jared and Robinson, James A. (Cambridge, Mass., 2010), ch. 6.Google Scholar
23 Stock, James and Watson, Mark, Introduction to Econometrics, 2nd ed. (Boston, 2007).Google Scholar
24 Weimer, David, “Collective Delusion in the Social Sciences: Publishing Incentives for Empirical Abuse,” Review of Policy Research 5, no. 4 (1986): 705–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
25 Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review 91, no. 5 (2001): 1369–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
26 David Albouy, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Investigation of the Settler Mortality Data,” National Bureau of Economic Research working paper no. 14130, 2008; Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson, “A Response to Albouy's ‘A Reexamination Based on Improved Settler Mortality Data,’ ” mimeo (Mar. 2005); Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson, “Reply to the Revised (May 2006) version of David Albouy's ‘The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Investigation of the Settler Mortality Data’ ” (2006).
27 Hardin, Garrett, “The Tragedy of the Commons,” Science 162, no. 3859 (1968): 1243–48.Google ScholarPubMed
28 Logarithmic utility assumes a subject's utility (hedonic pleasure) from consuming C to be a function of the form U = a log(C), while constant elasticity of substitution utility assumes U = C 1–a/(1 – a). The two are equivalent if a is 1, but not otherwise. Economic theorists often choose a functional form to make the algebra easier; however, results based on one form often do not follow if another is used instead.
29 Campbell, John, Lo, Andrew, and MacKinlay, A. Craig, The Econometrics of Financial Markets (Princeton, 1997), ch. 4.Google Scholar
30 Nelson, C. R., “The Prediction Performance of the F.R.B.-M.I.T.-Penn. Model of the U.S. Economy,” American Economic Review 62 (1972): 902–17Google Scholar; Roll, Richard, “R-Squared,” Journal of Finance 43, no. 3 (1988): 541–66Google Scholar; Diebold, Francis, “The Past, Present and Future of Macroeconomic Forecasting,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, no. 2 (1998): 175–92; Ricardo Caballero, “Macroeconomics after the Crisis: Time to Deal with the Pretence-of-Knowledge Syndrome,” MIT Department of Economics Working Paper No. 10-16, 2010; and others.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
31 Granger, Clive, “Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross-spectral Methods,” Econometrica 37 (1969): 424–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wiener, Norbert, “The Theory of Prediction,” in Modern Mathematics for Engineers I, ed. Beckenbach, E. F. (New York, 1956).Google Scholar
32 Muth, John, “Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements,” Econometrica 29 (1961): 315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
33 Summers, Lawrence and Stambaugh, Robert, “Does the Stock Market Rationally Reflect Fundamental Values?” Journal of Finance 41, no. 3 (1986): 591–603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
34 Jones, Geoffrey and Khanna, Tarun, “Bringing History (Back) into International Business,” Journal of International Business Studies 37 (2006): 453–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
35 Fohlin, Caroline, “The History of Corporate Ownership and Control in Germany,” in A History of Corporate Governance around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers, ed. Morck, Randall K. (Chicago, 2005), 223–77Google Scholar; Morck, Randall K. and Nakamura, Masao, “Business Groups and the Big Push: Meiji Japan's Mass Privatization and Subsequent Growth,” Enterprise and Society 8, no. 3 (2007): 543–601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
36 Michie, Ranald, The Global Securities Market: A History (Oxford, 2008).Google Scholar
37 See Rajan, Raghuram and Zingales, Luigi, “The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century,” Journal of Financial Economics 69, no. 1 (2003): 5–50.Even communist China has established stock markets. Their contribution toward that country's further development remains to be seen.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
38 Haber, Stephen H., “Politics Banking, and Economic Development: Evidence from New World Economies,” in Natural Experiments of History, ed. Diamond, Jared and Robinson, James A. (Cambridge Mass., 2010), ch. 3.Google Scholar
39 Jones, and Khanna, , “Bringing History (Back) into International Business,” 453–68Google Scholar; Morck, Randall K. and Yeung, Bernard, “History in Perspective: Comment on Jones and Khanna, ‘Bringing History (Back) into International Business,’” Journal of International Business Studies 38 (2007): 357–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
40 Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions.
41 Quoted in Wilson, Consilience: the Unity of Knowledge, 52.
42 Kragh, Helge, Quantum Generations: A History of Physics in the Twentieth Century (Princeton, 2002).Google Scholar
43 Larson, Edward, Evolution: The Remarkable History of a Scientific Theory (New York, 2004).Google Scholar
44 Wilkins, The Emergence of Multinational Enterprise; Hertner and Jones, Multinationals; Jones, Multinationals and Global Capitalism; and others.
45 Scranton, Philip, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865–1925 (Princeton, 1997).Google Scholar
46 Morck, Randall, ed., A History of Corporate Governance around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers (Chicago, 2005).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
47 Tolliday, Steven and Zeitlin, Jonathan, eds., The Automobile Industry and Its Workers: Between Fordism and Flexibility—Comparative Analysis of Developments in Europe, Asia, and the United States from the Late Nineteenth Century to the Mid-1980s (New York, 1987).Google Scholar
48 Engerman, Stanley and Fogel, Robert, Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery (Boston, 1974).Google Scholar
49 Fogel, Robert, The Slavery Debates, 1952–1990: A Retrospective (Baton Rouge, 2003)Google Scholar; Gutman, Herbert, Slavery and the Numbers Game: A Critique of Time on the Cross (Champaign, Ill., 2003).Google Scholar
50 Kindleberger, Charles, Manias, Panics and Crashes (New York, 1978).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
51 Lal, Deepak, The Poverty of “Development Economics” (Cambridge, Mass., 1985).Google Scholar
52 Haber, Stephen H., How Latin America Fell Behind: Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800–1914 (Stanford, 1997).Google Scholar
53 Haber, Stephen, North, Douglass, and Weingast, Barry, Political Institutions and Financial Development (Stanford, 2008)Google Scholar; North, Douglass, Wallis, John, and Weingast, Barry, Violence and Social Orders (Cambridge, U.K., 2009).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
54 Laplace, Pierre-Simon, Essai philosophique sur les probabilités (1814), transl. by Truscott, Frederick and Emory, Frederick, A Philosophical Essay on Probabilities (Dover, U.K., 1951).Google Scholar
55 Mirowski, Philip, More Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics (Cambridge, U.K., 1991).Google Scholar
56 Casson, Mark, Yeung, Bernard, Basu, Anuradha, and Wadeson, Nigel, eds., Oxford Handbook of Entrepreneurship (Oxford, 2006)Google Scholar; Casson, Mark, “Entrepreneurship,” in The Fortune Encyclopedia of Economics, ed. Henderson, D. R. (New York, 1993).Google Scholar
57 Cox, Richard and Wallace, David, eds., Archives and the Public Good: Accountability and Records in Modern Society (Westport, Conn., 2002).Google Scholar
58 Tufte, Edward, The Cognitive Style of PowerPoint (Cheshire, Conn., 2003).Google Scholar
59 Lakatos, Imre, Proofs and Refutations (Cambridge, U.K., 1976).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
60 Feyerabend, Paul, Against Method: Outline of an Anarchistic Theory of Knowledge (London, 1975); Jones and Khanna, “Bringing History (Back) into International Business,” 453–68.Google Scholar
61 Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (London, 1776).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
62 Lazear, “Economic Imperialism,” 99–146; Lamoreaux, Raff, and Temin, “Economic Theory and Business History,” in The Oxford Handbook of Business History, ed. Jones and Zeitlin, ch. 3.