Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T08:06:51.997Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Ideological Hedging in Uncertain Times: Inconsistent Legislative Representation and Voter Enfranchisement

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 March 2011

Abstract

Can ideological inconsistency in legislators’ voting records be explained by uncertainty about constituent preferences? Do legislators ‘hedge their bets’ ideologically when faced with constituency uncertainty? This article presents an uncertainty-based theory of ideological hedging. Legislators faced with uncertainty about their constituent preferences have an incentive to present ideologically inconsistent roll-call records. Legislators experiment with a variety of roll-call positions in order to learn the preferences of their constituents. An examination of US senators during 1961–2004 shows that uncertainty due to black enfranchisement and mobilization led to higher ideological inconsistency in legislative voting records. Ideologically inconsistent behaviour by elected officials can be characterized as best responses to a changing and uncertain environment. These results have implications for representation and the stability of democracy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Mansbridge, Jane, ‘Rethinking Representation’, American Political Science Review, 97 (2003), 515528CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 517.

2 Clapp, Charles L., The Congressman: His Work as He Sees It (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1963), p. 159Google Scholar.

3 Gore, Albert Sr, Let the Glory Out: My South and Its Politics (Athens, Ga.: Hill Street Classics, 2000), p. 211Google Scholar.

4 For example, see: Adams, James, ‘A Theory of Spatial Competition with Biased Voters: Party Policies Viewed Temporally and Comparatively’, British Journal of Political Science, 31 (2001), 121158CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Adams, James, Bishin, Benjamin G. and Dow, Jay, ‘Representation in Congressional Campaigns: Evidence for Discounting/Directional Voting in U.S. Senate Elections’, Journal of Politics, 66 (2004), 348373CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Adams, James and Somer-Topcu, Zeynep, ‘Policy Adjustment by Parties in Response to Rival Parties’ Policy Shifts: Spatial Theory and the Dynamics of Party Competition in Twenty-Five Post-War Democracies’, British Journal of Political Science, 39 (2009), 825846CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Budge, Ian, ‘A New Spatial Theory of Party Competition: Uncertainty, Ideology, and Policy Equilibria Viewed Comparatively and Temporally’, British Journal of Political Science, 24 (1994), 443467CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper Collins, 1957)Google Scholar.

5 Others have examined uncertainty in the context of the US House. For example, see: Bertelli, Anthony M. and Carson, Jamie, ‘Constituency Effects, Redistricting, and Representation in U.S. House Elections’ (paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, 2006)Google Scholar; Espino, Rodolfo and Canon, David T., ‘Vote Switching in the U.S. House’, Journal of Politics, 71 (2009), 324338CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Richman, Jesse, ‘Uncertainty and the Prevalence of Committee Outliers’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 33 (2008), 323347CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Scholars have also examined how think tanks can reduce policy uncertainty. For example, see: Bertelli, Anthony M. and Wenger, Jeffrey B., ‘Demanding Information: Think Tanks and the US Congress’, British Journal of Political Science, 39 (2009), 225242CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Esterling, Kevin M., The Political Economy of Expertise (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Many scholars have noted the impact of increased black enfranchisement on the politics of the US South and the subsequent rise of the Republican party. For example, see: Aistrup, Joseph, Southern Strategy Revisited (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1996)Google Scholar; Bullock, Charles S., ‘Racial Crossover Voting and the Election of Black Officials’, Journal of Politics, 46 (1984), 238251CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Keech, William R., The Impact of Negro Voting (Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press, 1981)Google Scholar; Lublin, David I., The Republican South (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2004)Google Scholar; Stanley, Harold W., Voter Mobilization and the Politics of Race (New York: Praeger, 1987)Google Scholar. We also know quite a bit about ideological shifts among southern House members in response to increases in black voting power. For example, see: Bullock, Charles S., ‘Congressional Voting and the Mobilization of a Black Electorate in the South’, Journal of Politics, 46 (1981), 662682CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Grose, Christian R., Congress in Black and White (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Grose, Christian R., ‘Disentangling Constituency and Legislator Effects in Legislative Representation’, Social Science Quarterly, 86 (2005), 427443CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Whitby, Kenny J. and Gilliam, Franklin D., ‘A Longitudinal Analysis of Competing Explanations for the Transformation of Southern Congressional Politics’, Journal of Politics, 53 (1991), 504518CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Much less is known about senators’ roll-call voting (though see Hood, M. V., Kidd, Quentin and Morris, Irwin L., ‘The Key Issue: Constituency Effects and Southern Senators’ Roll-call Voting on Civil Rights’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 26 (2001), 599621CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Hutchings, Vincent L., McClerking, Harwood K., and Charles, Guy-Uriel, ‘Congressional Representation of Black Interests’, Journal of Politics, 66 (2004), 450468CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and we know almost nothing about the ideological consistency of voting in legislatures.

7 Black, Earl and Black, Merle, The Rise of Southern Republicans (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2002), p. 125Google Scholar.

8 Brady, Michael C. and Rohde, David W., ‘When Good Predictions Go Bad: Vote Context, Win Margins, and Misclassified Votes in the 75th to 108th Congresses’ (unpublished manuscript, Duke University, 2007)Google Scholar.

9 However, see: Burden, Barry, The Personal Roots of Representation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2007)Google Scholar.

10 For example, Shafer, Byron E. and Johnston, Richard G. C., ‘The Transformation of Southern Politics Revisited: The House of Representatives as a Window’, British Journal of Political Science, 31 (2001), 601625CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 However, see: Hood, M. V. III, Kidd, Quentin and Morris, Irwin L., ‘Of Byrd[s] and Bumpers: Using Democratic Senators to Analyse Political Change in the South, 1960–1995’, American Journal of Political Science, 43 (1999), 465487Google Scholar.

12 Uncertainty due to constituency change has also been applied in the context of redistricting in the United States. For example, see: Murphy, Chad and Yoshinaka, Antoine, ‘Are Mapmakers Able to Target and Protect Congressional Incumbents? The Institutional Dynamics of Electoral Competition’, American Politics Research, 37 (2009), 955982CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Yoshinaka, Antoine and Murphy, Chad, ‘Partisan Gerrymandering and Population Instability: Completing the Redistricting Puzzle’, Political Geography, 28 (2009), 451462CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Yoshinaka, Antoine and Murphy, Chad, ‘The Paradox of Representation: How Partisan Mapmakers Foster Competition but Disrupt Representation’, Political Research Quarterly (forthcoming)Google Scholar.

13 For example, see: McElroy, Gail and Benoit, Kenneth, ‘Party Groups and Policy Positions in the European Parliament’, Party Politics, 13 (2007), 528CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Peress, Michael, ‘Candidate Positioning and Responsiveness to Constituent Opinion in the U.S. House of Representatives’ (unpublished manuscript, University of Rochester, 2008)Google Scholar; and Poole, Keith T. and Rosenthal, Howard, Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting (New York: Oxford University Press, 1997)Google Scholar.

14 Fenno, Richard F. Jr, Senators on the Campaign Trail (Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1996), p. 277Google Scholar.

15 Kingdon, John, Congressmen's Voting Decisions, 3rd edn (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 For example, Calvert, Randall L., ‘Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model: Candidate Motivations, Uncertainty, and Convergence’, American Journal of Political Science, 29 (1985), 6995CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Hinich, Melvin J. and Munger, Michael C., Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1996)Google Scholar. Calvert finds that under uncertainty, candidates would still be likely to converge, though not under some conditions (i.e., uncertainty combined with extreme personal policy preferences for the candidates and motivations based on both winning and policy).

17 Calvert, , ‘Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model’, p. 86Google Scholar.

18 For example, Fenno, Richard F. Jr, Congressmen in Committees (Boston, Mass.: Little, Brown, 1973)Google Scholar; and Burden, The Personal Roots of Representation.

19 Non-median positions are also likely when legislators appeal to various subconstituencies. For example, see: Bishin, Benjamin G., ‘Constituency Influence in Congress: Do Subconstituencies Matter?’ Legislative Studies Quarterly, 25 (2000), 389415CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Bishin, Benjamin G., Tyranny of the Minority: The Subconstituency Politics Theory of Representation (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 2009)Google Scholar. Even under this framework, however, legislators who are uncertain about the location of those subconstituencies should appear more inconsistent than legislators who have more certainty about the preferences of various groups.

20 Van Houweling, Robert P., ‘Legislators’ Personal Policy Preferences and Partisan Legislative Organization’ (doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, 2003)Google Scholar.

21 For example, Lawrence Evans, C., ‘How Senators Decide’, in Bruce I. Oppenheimer, ed., U.S. Senate Exceptionalism (Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 2002), pp. 262282Google Scholar; Fenno, Richard F. Jr, Home Style: House Members in Their Districts (Boston, Mass.: Little, Brown, 1978)Google Scholar; Kingdon, Congressmen's Voting Decisions; and Kollman, Ken, Miller, John H. and Page, Scott E., ‘Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes’, British Journal of Political Science, 28 (1998), 139158CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Sulkin, Tracy, Issue Politics in Congress (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Evans, , ‘How Legislators Decide’, p. 272Google Scholar.

23 Espino and Canon, ‘Vote Switching in the U.S. House’, examine legislator uncertainty over the content of specific roll calls to explain why legislators switch their votes on the same roll calls. Our study differs, as we focus on the uncertainty legislators have about constituent preferences and on the resulting ideological inconsistency.

24 Fox, Justin, ‘Government Transparency and Policymaking’, Public Choice, 131 (2007), 2344CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 In some ways, a large increase in a new voter group is similar to a ‘surprise’ that occurs through experiential learning. For example, Cohen, Michael D. and Axelrod, Robert, ‘Coping with Complexity: The Adaptive Value of Changing Utility’, American Economic Review, 74 (1984), 3042Google Scholar.

26 Hinich, Melvin J. and Munger, Michael C., Analytical Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), p. 119CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Coughlin, Peter J., Probabilistic Voting Theory (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), pp. 1920CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 Hinich and Munger, Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice (pp. 137–8).

28 Hinich and Munger, Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice.

29 The types of positions taken in a campaign that are empty and not part of roll-call voting are distinct from roll-call votes as legislators are unable to control the agenda and timing of roll-call votes. See Grose, Christian R. and Middlemass, Keesha M., ‘Listen to What I Say, Not How I Vote: Congressional Support for the President in Washington and at Home’, Social Science Quarterly, 91 (2010), 143167CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Middlemass, Keesha M. and Grose, Christian R., ‘The Three Presidencies? Legislative Position-taking in Support of the President on Domestic, Foreign, and Homeland Security Policies in the 107th Congress’, Congress & the Presidency, 34 (2007), 5780CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Grose, Christian R., ‘Bridging the Divide: Interethnic Cooperation, Minority Media Outlets, and the Coverage of Latino, African-American, and Asian-American Members of Congress’, Harvard International Journal of Press/Politics, 11 (2006), 115130CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

30 Grose, Christian R., ‘Priming Rationality: A Theory and Field Experiment of Participation in Legislatures’ (paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Toronto, 2009)Google Scholar.

31 Shepsle, Kenneth A., ‘The Strategy of Ambiguity: Uncertainty and Electoral Competition’, American Political Science Review, 66 (1972), 555568CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 While not a part of our theory, it is possible that voters may have a preference for inconsistent or ambiguous behaviour from their legislators. For example, Tomz, Michael and Van Houweling, Robert P., ‘The Electoral Implications of Candidate Ambiguity’, American Political Science Review, 103 (2009), 8398CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33 Kollman, , Miller, and Page, , ‘Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes’, p. 143Google Scholar.

34 For example, Fenno, Home Style.

35 For example, Shepsle suggests that incumbents cannot be ambiguous as they have a pre-existing record; we argue that incumbent ambiguity can be achieved to some extent via inconsistency. See Shepsle, ‘The Strategy of Ambiguity’.

36 Theoretically, the new voter could be located anywhere along the dimension. In the case we examine later, senators may have surmised that newly enfranchised African-American voters were not on the far right. Of course, if a legislator surmised that black voters are located somewhere on the left side of the spectrum, then (in Figure 2) there will still be uncertainty over the location of the median compared to the scenario with no new voters, but this uncertainty space would be smaller than the more general scenario presented in the figure. Further, while the partisan preferences of black voters are generally known to legislators, there is little evidence that elected officials have in-depth knowledge of the ideological or issue preferences of these new voters.

37 Key, V. O. Jr, Southern Politics in State and Nation (New York: Knopf, 1949), p. 86Google Scholar.

38 For example, Brady and Rohde, ‘When Good Predictions Go Bad’; Doriean, Charles and Page, Scott, ‘Is McCain a Maverick? And What is a Maverick Anyway?’ (unpublished manuscript, University of Michigan, 2008)Google Scholar; Lauderdale, Benjamin E., ‘Unpredictable Voters in Ideal Point Estimation’, Political Analysis, 18 (2010), 151171CrossRefGoogle Scholar; McCarty, Nolan, Poole, Keith and Rosenthal, Howard, ‘McCain for president? A conservative–liberal oscillation cements his maverick reputation’, San Diego Union-Tribune (31 August 2008); and Richman, ‘Uncertainty and the Prevalence of Committee Outliers’Google Scholar.

39 Poole and Rosenthal, Congress, p. 32; and McElroy and Benoit, ‘Party Groups and Policy Positions in the European Parliament’.

40 We also estimated regression models with dependent variables measuring misclassification rates based on three- and four-dimensional models of voting, and the results were substantively the same as the two-dimensional results we present here. This alleviates concerns that the presence of additional dimensions may be driving our results (e.g., what if some legislators are voting consistently on an unobserved third dimension?). We ruled out that possibility by estimating models with misclassified votes using Optimal Classification (OC) scores in three and four dimensions as the dependent variable, and our inferences remain unchanged (see online appendix, which may be viewed at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps).

41 For more details, see: Poole and Rosenthal, Congress; and Brady and Rohde, ‘When Good Predictions Go Bad’.

42 Longley, Kyle, Senator Albert Gore, Sr.: Tennessee Maverick (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 2004), p. 148Google Scholar.

43 Could Long's inconsistency in Congress during the mid-1960s have also been fuelled by idiosyncratic factors such as his heavy drinking, which provoked ‘erratic and boisterous behaviour’ on his part? See Mann, Robert, Legacy to Power: Senator Russell Long of Louisiana (New York: Paragon, 2003 [1992]), p. 288Google Scholar. We leave this question for others to answer as alcohol consumption is not part of our theory of legislator inconsistency.

44 Mervin, David, ‘United States Senate Norms and the Majority Whip Election of 1969’, Journal of American Studies, 9 (1975), 321333CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

45 Data on changes in black electoral strength are not available nationally for this entire time period, but are available for the southern states from 1960 onwards. Southern states are identified as Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Louisiana, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas and Virginia.

46 The average southern senator cast 596 non-unanimous roll-call votes per congress during that period.

47 We use census figures during census years and census population estimates for intervening years.

48 This measure is from Hood, Kidd and Morris, ‘Of Byrd[s] and Bumpers’.

49 This measure is ideal as it assesses both the change in the state's black voter population over a two-year time period and the relative size of the enfranchised and mobilized black population.

50 See David, Paul T., Party Strength in the United States, 1872–1970 (Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 1972)Google Scholar; Hood, Kidd and Morris, ‘Of Byrd[s] and Bumpers’; and Lamis, Alexander P., The Two-party South (New York: Oxford University Press, 1988)Google Scholar. We are grateful to Trey Hood for sharing these political competition data and the black electoral strength data.

51 See Shafer, Byron E. and Johnston, Richard, The End of Southern Exceptionalism: Class, Race, and Partisan Change in the Postwar South (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2006)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. To construct this measure, we read the biographies of all senators in the Congressional Biographical Directory, which detail their places of birth and residencies through college (we also referred to other biographical sources when needed). We also employed alternative measures of the cosmopolitan variable (e.g., coding senators as non-natives or natives of the state they represent), and the results were substantively the same as those we present here. We also estimated a model without this variable, and the remaining results were consistent (see online appendix, which may be viewed at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps).

52 Poole and Rosenthal, Congress, pp. 31–3.

53 Alternatively, we also estimated a regression with fixed effects for each congress (reported in Table 3).

54 Lee, Frances E. and Oppenheimer, Bruce I., Sizing Up the Senate (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999)Google Scholar.

55 Richman, Jesse, ‘Why the Issue Dimensionality of Political Systems Varies’ (doctoral dissertation, Carnegie Mellon University, 2005)Google Scholar.

56 While this variable is theoretically relevant, in the South during the time period examined it amounts to a dummy variable for Harry Flood Byrd Jr. (I-Virginia), who switched from Democrat to Independent in 1970. For more on party switchers, see: Grose, Christian R. and Yoshinaka, Antoine, ‘The Electoral Consequences of Party Switching by Incumbent Members of Congress, 1947–2000’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 28 (2003), 5575CrossRefGoogle Scholar; McElroy, Gail and Benoit, Kenneth, ‘Party Policy and Group Affiliation in the European Parliament’, British Journal of Political Science, 40 (2010), 377398CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Yoshinaka, Antoine, ‘House Party Switchers and Committee Assignments: Who Gets ‘What, When, How?’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 30 (2005), 391406CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Yoshinaka, Antoine, ‘Party Building Through Conversion’, in Charles S. Bullock III and Mark J. Rozell, eds, Oxford Handbook of Southern Politics (New York: Oxford University Press, forthcoming)Google Scholar; and Yoshinaka, Antoine, Crossing the Aisle: Party Switching by U.S. Legislators in the Postwar Era (unpublished manuscript, American University, 2011)Google Scholar. Since Byrd caucused with the Democrats even after affiliating as an independent, we estimated the results with Byrd coded as a Democrat and therefore no third-party dummy, and the results were nearly identical to those presented later (see online appendix, which may be viewed at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps).

57 See Arellano, Manuel and Bond, Stephen, ‘Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations’, Review of Economic Studies, 58 (1991), 277297CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Judson, Ruth A. and Owen, Ann L., ‘Estimating Dynamic Panel Data Models: A Guide for Macroeconomics’, Economic Letters, 65 (1999), 915CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The Arellano–Bond estimator assumes strict exogeneity; that is, current values of X should not be correlated with past values of the error term. Most of the independent variables we include can easily be assumed to be strictly exogenous. However, if past values of the error term affect a senator's career, it is possible that variables related to re-election may not be strictly exogenous. In the online appendix, which may be viewed at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps, we show that our results hold if we exclude variables related to re-election.

58 Given the presence of interactive terms, the computation of the marginal effects of changes in black electoral strength (X 3) for a Democratic senator is based on varying all values of the relevant constitutive and interaction terms.

59 We also estimated a model that included a three-way interaction between black electoral strength, Democrat and competitiveness (and all constitutive terms and two-way interactions). The results show that the combined effect of changes in black electoral strength and competitiveness is larger for Democratic than for Republican senators. Democratic senators from competitive states cast inconsistent votes when faced with changes in black electoral strength (see online appendix at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps).

60 Wright, Gerald C. Jr and Berkman, Michael B., ‘Candidates and Policy in United States Senate Elections’, American Political Science Review, 80 (1986), 567588CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

61 Arellano and Bond, ‘Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data’.

62 We also re-estimated Models 1 and 4 using generalized least squares (GLS) with an AR(1) process and the results were similar to those presented in the text (see online appendix at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps).

63 We used this alternative measure as the dependent variable in regressions with the same independent variables as those reported earlier in the article, and the results were substantively similar.

64 Doriean and Page, ‘Is McCain a Maverick?’; Fenno, Richard F. Jr, The Power of the Purse: Appropriations Politics in Congress (Boston, Mass.: Little, Brown, 1966)Google Scholar; Lauderdale, ‘Unpredictable Voters in Ideal Point Estimation’; Rieselbach, Leroy N., Congressional Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1973)Google Scholar; and Wainer, Howard, Gruvaeus, Gunnar and Zill, Nicholas II, ‘Senatorial Decision Making: I. The Determination of Structure’, Behavioural Science, 18 (1973), 719CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

65 Lander, Ernest McPherson, A History of South Carolina, 1865–1960 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1960), p. 50Google Scholar.

66 ‘The Congress: Makings of the 73rd’, Time (26 September 1932), available at http://www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,744423,00.html [accessed 6 August 2009].

67 For example, Agnes Geelan, The Dakota Maverick: The Political Life of William Langer, Also Known as “Wild Bill” Langer (Fargo, N. Dak.: Geelan, 1975); and Larsen, Lawrence H., ‘William Langer: A Maverick in the Senate’, Wisconsin Magazine of History, 44 (1961), 189198Google Scholar.

68 Gleijeses, Piero, Shattered Hope: The Guatemalan Revolution and the United States, 1944–1954 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1991)Google Scholar.

69 Huitt, Ralph K., ‘The Outsider in the Senate: An Alternative Role’, American Political Science Review, 55 (1961), 566575CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 566.

70 David Johnson, Robert, Ernest Gruening and the American Dissenting Tradition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1998), p. 226Google Scholar.

71 Greider, William, ‘A Peculiar Politician’, The Nation (14 March 2006)Google Scholar.

72 For example, see: Druckman, Mason, Wayne Morse: A Political Biography (Portland: Oregon Historical Society Press, 1997)Google Scholar; and Fenno, , The Power of the Purse, pp. 513–17Google Scholar.

73 Robert Smith, Arthur, The Tiger in the Senate: The Biography of Wayne Morse (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1962), p. 289Google Scholar.

74 Mervin, David, ‘Parochialism and Professionalism in a Congressional Election’, Political Studies, 20 (1972): 277286CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

75 Bird Johnson, Lady, A White House Diary (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1973)Google Scholar.

76 For example, Odenkirk, James E., Frank J. Lausche: Ohio's Great Political Maverick: A Biography (Wilmington, Ohio: Orange Frazer, 2005)Google Scholar; and Porter, Philip W., Cleveland: Confused City on a Seesaw (Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 1976), pp. 129130Google Scholar.

77 Fenno, , The Power of the Purse, p. 504Google Scholar.

78 ‘The Congress’, Time (16 January 1950).

79 Others have attempted to uncover a measure of maverickness, see, e.g., Lauderdale, ‘Unpredictable Voters in Ideal Point Estimation’.

80 Evans, ‘How Legislators Decide’.

81 Huntington, Samuel P., ‘Political Development and Political Decay’, World Politics, 17 (1965), 386430CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 407.

82 For example, Carson, Jamie L., Crespin, Michael H., Finocchario, Charles J. and Rohde, David W., ‘Redistricting and Party Polarization in the U.S. House of Representatives’, American Politics Research, 35 (2007), 878904CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Hetherington, Marc J., ‘Review Article: Putting Polarization in Perspective’, British Journal of Political Science, 39 (2009), 413448CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

83 Yoshinaka, Antoine and Grose, Christian R., ‘Partisan Politics and Electoral Design: The Enfranchisement of Felons and Ex-felons in the U.S., 1960–1999’, State and Local Government Review, 37 (2005), 4960CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

84 See McCarty, Nolan, Poole, Keith T. and Rosenthal, Howard, Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2006)Google Scholar.

Supplementary material: File

Yoshinaka Supplementary Material

Yoshinaka Supplementary Appendix

Download Yoshinaka Supplementary Material(File)
File 228.4 KB