Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T08:56:31.195Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political and Economic Explanations for Unemployment: A Cross-National and Long-Term Analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

This article shows that the widely accepted supply shock and real wage gap explanation of increases in unemployment rates since 1973 has only limited empirical support. The causal factors behind unemployment are best understood by focusing on conflicts of interest in Western democracies, on the distribution of power resources between major interest groups and on strategies of conflict. Given economic constraints, from this perspective unemployment appears as the labour market expression of distributive conflict, alternatives to which are inflation and industrial disputes. Strategic action by government elites and long-term patterns in settling conflicts are major factors behind the two great transformations of Western unemployment levels – the introduction of full employment in the immediate post-war period and the return to high unemployment since 1973 – as well as in variations in unemployment among eighteen Western democracies.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Beveridge, W., Social Insurance and the Allied Services (London: HMSO, 1942), p. 164.Google Scholar

2 Maddison, A., Phases of Capitalist Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1982).Google Scholar

3 Okun, A., The Political Economics of Prosperity (Washington, DC.: The Brookings Institution, 1970).Google Scholar

4 For example, Alt, J. E., ‘Political Parties, World Demand, and Unemployment: Domestic and International Sources of Economic Activity’, American Political Science Review, 79 (1985), 1016–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Schmidt, M. G., ‘The Welfare State and the Economy in Periods of Economic Crisis: A Comparative Study of Twenty-three OECD Nations’, European Journal of Political Research, 11 (1983), 126CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Therborn, G., Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others (London: Verso, 1986)Google Scholar; Hibbs, D. A., ‘Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy’, American Political Science Review, 71 (1977), 1467–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

5 For introductions to and reviews of this large literature, see Helliwell, J. F., ‘Comparative Macroeconomics of Stagflation’, Journal of Economic Literature, 26 (1988), 128Google Scholar; Lawrence, R. Z. and Schultze, C. L., eds, Barriers to European Growth: A Transatlantic View (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1987)Google Scholar; Bean, C. R., Layard, P. R. G. and Nickell, S. J., ‘The Rise in Unemployment: A Multi-Country Study’, Economica (Supplement), 53 (1986), 122CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Johnson, G. E. and Layard, P. R. G., ‘The Natural Rate of Unemployment: Explanation and Policy’, chap. 16Google Scholar in Ashenfelter, O. C. and Layard, R., eds, Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 2 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986)Google Scholar; Greenhalgh, C. A., Layard, P. R. G. and Oswald, A. J., eds, The Causes of Unemployment (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1983).Google Scholar

6 For example, Cross, R., ed., Unemployment, Hysteresis, and the Natural Rate Hypothesis (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1988)Google Scholar; Blanchard, J. O. and Summers, L. H., ‘Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem’, in Fischer, S., ed., NBER Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1986).Google Scholar

7 The exceptionally high rates of unemployment in many European countries have also been interpreted as a failure of European management systems, labour relations, capital market institutions and government policies to adapt from the Golden Age based on catch-up technologies and to move up to the technological frontiers of post-industrial society, involving automation and microprocessors. Competition from the newly industrializing countries has also been suggested as a cause of increasing unemployment in the OECD area.

8 For example, Grubb, D., Jackman, R. and Layard, R., ‘Causes of the Current Stagflation’, Review of Economic Studies, 49 (1982), 707–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Coe, D. T. and Gagliardi, J., ‘Nominal Wage Determination in Ten OECD Economies’, OECD, Economics and Statistics Department Working Papers (Paris: OECD, 1985)Google Scholar; Sachs, J. D., ‘Real Wages and Unemployment in the OECD Countries’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 (1983), 255304CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bruno, M. and Sachs, J. D., Economics of Worldwide Stagflation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bruno, M., ‘Aggregate Supply and Demand Factors in OECD Unemployment: An Update’, Economica (Supplement), 53 (1986), 3552CrossRefGoogle Scholar; OECD, Economic Outlook, No. 21 (1977), 61–4Google Scholar; OECD, Economies in Transition: Structural Adjustments in OECD Countries (Paris: OECD, 1989).Google Scholar

9 For example, OECD, Economies in Transition: Structural Adjustment in OECD countries, p. 33 ff.Google Scholar; Bruno, and Sachs, ; Economics of Worldwide StagflationGoogle Scholar, chap. 9; Bruno, , ‘Aggregate Supply and Demand Factors in OECD Unemployment: An Update’.Google Scholar

10 The wage gap measure is illustrated in OECD, Economies in Transition, p. 35.Google Scholar Although this type of measure diners somewhat from the one originally developed by Bruno and Sachs, it has been used also by them (Bruno, and Sachs, , Economics of Worldwide Stagflation, pp. 229–30).Google Scholar Non-wage labour costs are not available for Australia, Denmark and New Zealand, but are known to be comparatively small in these countries.

11 Bruno, and Sachs, , Economics of Worldwide Stagflation, p. 185.Google Scholar

12 Kendric, J. W., ‘International Comparisons of Recent Productivity Trends’, in Fellner, W., ed., Contemporary Economic Problems (Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, 1981)Google Scholar; Bruno, and Sachs, , Economics of Worldwide StagflationGoogle Scholar, chap. 12; Maddison, A., ‘Growth and Slowdown in Advanced Capitalist Economies: Techniques of Quantitative Assessment’, Journal of Economic Literature, 25 (1987), 649–98.Google Scholar

13 Examples of such factors are the search intensity of unemployed workers and the degree of mismatch between vacancies and the unemployed. In Britain, however, the degree of mismatch does not appear to have increased. See Layard, R., How to Beat Unemployment (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Jackman, R. and Roper, S., ‘Structural Unemployment’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 49 (1987), 936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14 Kalecki, M., The Last Phase in the Transformation of Capitalism (New York and London: Monthly Review Press, 1943, 1972), p. 75.Google Scholar

15 Korpi, W., ‘Power Resources Approach vs Action and Conflict: On Causal and Intentional Explanation in the Study of Power’, Sociological Theory, 3 (1985), 3145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Kirschen, E. S., Benard, J., Besters, H., Blackaby, F., Eckstein, O., Faaland, J., Hartog, F., Morissens, L. and Tosco, E., Economic Policy in Our Time, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1964), pp. 224–9.Google Scholar The study included Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, the United Kingdom and the United States.

17 For a discussion of causal and intentional explanations see Elster, J., Explaining Technical Change (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).Google Scholar

18 Downs, A., An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper, 1957).Google Scholar

19 Alt, , ‘Political Parties, World Demand, and Unemployment: Domestic and International Sources of Economic Activity’Google Scholar; Alesina, A., ‘Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Democracies’, Economic Policy (1989), 5798Google Scholar; and Alesina, A., ‘Macroeconomics and Politics’, NBER Macroeconomic Annual (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1988).Google Scholar

20 Boltho, A., ‘Did Policy Activism Work?’, European Economic Review, 33 (1989), 1709–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shonfield, A., Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (London: Oxford University Press, 1965), p. 63.Google Scholar See also Maddison, A., Phases of Capitalist Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1982), chaps 5 and 6.Google Scholar

21 Duverger, M., Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State (New York: Wiley, 1958), p. xxvii.Google Scholar

22 For each country the average percentage of votes for the Left from 1919 to 1959 and the percentage of time with at least one left-wing party represented in the government are given in the Appendix. To adjust left-wing strength for the severe splits among left-wing parties in Finland, France and Italy, only one-third of the time with left-wing government participation is taken into account in these countries. Left-wing parties are here defined as the traditional social democratic parties and the parties to their left.

23 Weir, M., ‘Full Employment as a Political Issue in the United States’, Social Research, 54 (1987), 377402.Google Scholar

24 Hirsch, F., ‘The Ideological Underlay of Inflation’, in Hirsch, F. and Goldthorpe, J. H., eds, The Political Economy of Inflation (London: Martin Robertson, 1978), pp. 263–84Google Scholar; Goldthorpe, J. H., ‘The Current Inflation: Towards a Sociological Account’Google Scholar, in Hirsch, and Goldthorpe, , eds, The Political Economy of Inflation, pp. 186216Google Scholar; Hirschman, A. O., ‘Reflection on the Latin American Experience’, in Lindberg, L. N. and Maier, C. S., eds, The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation: Theoretical Approaches and International Case Studies (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1985), pp. 5377.Google Scholar

25 Korpi, W. and Shalev, M., ‘Strikes, Power, and Politics in the Western Nations, 1900–1976’, in Zeitlin, Maurice, ed., Political Power and Social Theory: A Research Annual, vol. 1 (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1980), pp. 301–34.Google Scholar

26 Cf. also Korpi, W., The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge, 1983), pp. 182–3.Google Scholar

27 OECD, Inflation: The Present Problem. Report by the Secretary General (Paris, OECD, 1970), pp. 63–6.Google Scholar

28 OECD, Inflation: The Present Problem, pp. 810.Google Scholar

29 OECD, Inflation: The Present Problem, p. 35.Google Scholar

30 Rehn, G., ‘State, Economic Policy and Industrial Relations in the 1980s: Problems and Trends’, Economic and Industrial Democracy, 8 (1987), 6179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

31 OECD, Towards Full Employment and Price Stability (Paris: OECD, 1977), p. 26.Google Scholar

32 Katzenstein, P. J., ‘Capitalism in One Country? Switzerland in the International Economy’, International Organization, 34 (1980), 507–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lehner, F., ‘Consociational Democracy in Switzerland: A Political-Economic Explanation and Some Empirical Evidence’, European Journal of Political Research, 12 (1984), 2542CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kriesi, H., Entscheidungsstrukturen und Entscheidungs-prozesse in der Schweizer Politik (Frankfurt: Campus, 1980).Google Scholar

33 Nousiainen, J., The Finnish Political System (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971).CrossRefGoogle Scholar Up to 1987, the Conservative party in Finland was considered unfit to participate in the government because of its previous stands in relation to the Soviet Union, something which weakened the bourgeois side. Up to the end of the 1960s, however, Finland appears to have largely followed the pluralistic pattern of conflict settlements. Concerning incomes policies see Armingeon, K., ‘Formation and Stability of Neo-Corporatist Incomes Policies: A Comparative Analysis’, European Sociological Review, 2 (1986), 138–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

34 Pempel, T. J., Policy and Politics in Japan: Creative Conservatism (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1982)Google Scholar; Pempel, T. J. and Tsunekawa, K., ‘Corporatism Without Labor? The Japanese Anomaly’, in Schmitter, P. C. and Lehmbruch, G., eds, Trends Toward Corporatist Intermediation (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1979), pp. 231–70Google Scholar; Shalev, M., ‘Class Conflict, Corporatism and Comparison: A Japanese Enigma’, in Eisenstadt, S. N. and Ben-Ari, E., eds, Japanese Models on Conflict Resolution (London: Kegan Paul, 1989).Google Scholar

35 Messner, J., Die Soziale Frage im Blickfeld der Irrwege von Gestern, der Sozialkämpfe von Heute, der Weltentscheidung von Morgen, 7th revised edn (Innsbruck: Tyrolia Verlag, 1964).Google Scholar

36 Martin, B., ‘Japans Weg in die Moderne und das deutsche Vorbild: Historische Gemeinsamkeiten zweier “verspäteter Nationen” (1860–1960)’, in Martin, Bernd, ed., Japans Weg in die Moderne: Ein Sonderweg nach deutschem Vorbild? (Frankfurt/New York: Campus, 1986), pp. 1744.Google Scholar

37 Ernst, A., ‘Arbeitslosigkeit und Unterbeschäftigung in Japan. Eine Übersicht zum Stand der Empirischen Forschung’, Mitteilungen aus der Arbeitsmarkt und Berufsforschung, 11 (1978), 3449Google Scholar; Taira, K., ‘Japan's Low Unemployment: Economic Miracle or Statistical Artifact’, Monthly Labor Review, 106 (1983), 310Google Scholar; Sorrentino, C., ‘Japan's Low Unemployment: An In-Depth Analysis’, Monthly Labor Review, 107 (1984), 1827.Google Scholar

38 Up to the early 1970s, relatively short industrial disputes with a wide participation (the shunto) were important in Japan.

39 Scharpf, F., Sozialdemokratische Krisenpolitik in Europa (Frankfurt/New York: Campus, 1987).Google Scholar

40 From 1973 to 1977 the immigrant proportion of the labour force in Switzerland declined by 5.3 per cent. Cf. Schmidt, M. G., Der Schweizerische Weg zur Vollbeschäftigung: Eine Bilanz der Beschäftigung, der Arbeitslosigkeit und der Arbeitsmarktpolitik (Frankfurt: Campus, 1985), p. 30.Google Scholar Note that in Switzerland a large number of ‘guest workers’ are not registered as inhabitants and therefore before 1973 the labour force participation rate exceeded 100 per cent among men.

41 Between 1973 and 1978 the decrease of the immigrant proportion of the labour force amounted to roughly 1·5 per cent in Austria and somewhat above 2 per cent in Germany (cf. data in Scharpf, , Sozialdemokratische Krisenpolitik in Europa, p. 72).Google Scholar

42 Yamamura, K., ‘The Cost of Rapid Growth and Capitalist Democracy in Japan’, in Lindberg, Leon N. and Majer, Charles S., eds, The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation: Theoretical Approaches and International Case Studies (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1985), pp. 467508.Google Scholar

43 For a discussion of the concept of the intervening variable, cf. Hirschi, Travis and Selvin, Hanan C., ‘Principles of Causal Analysis’, in Lazarsfeld, Paul F., Pasanella, Ann K. and Rosenberg, Morris, eds, Continuities in the Language of Social Research (New York: The Free Press, 1972).Google Scholar

44 For example, Crouch, C., ‘Conditions for Trade Union Wage Restraint’Google Scholar, in Lindberg, and Maier, , eds, The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation: Theoretical Approaches and international Case Studies, pp. 105–39Google Scholar; Bruno, and Sachs, , Economics of Worldwide StagflationGoogle Scholar; Callum, J. M., ‘Unemployment in OECD Countries in the 1980s’, Economic Journal, 96 (1986), 942–60.Google Scholar For definitions of ‘neo-corporatism’ see, for example, Schmitter, P. C., ‘Interest Intermediation and Regime Governability in Contemporary Western Europe and North America’, in Berger, S., ed., Organizing interests in Western Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981)Google Scholar; Lehmbruch, G., ‘Concertation and the Structure of Corporatist Networks’, in Goldthorpe, J. H., ed., Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism: Studies in the Political Economy of Western European Nations (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984), pp. 6080.Google Scholar For a discussion of the role of encompassing unions, cf. Olson, M., The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1982).Google Scholar

45 For the historically informed, however, the recent use of the term corporatism to refer to broad, class-based collective action involving encompassing unions appears as a misnomer, which stands the original concept of corporatism on its head. Up to the Second World War the theory of corporatism was in fact used to counteract this type of broadly based collective action via encompassing unions and to hinder the organization of workers' interests on the basis of class. The classical corporatist model prescribed, instead, the creation of segmented, much more narrow bases for collective action and organization of workers' interests, primarily occupations (corporations) or the enterprise. Cf. Messner, , Die Soziale Frage im Blickfeld der Irrwege von Gestern, der Sozialkämpfe von Heute, der Weltentscheidung von Morgen.Google Scholar

46 Rank correlations between average unemployment levels in 1985–86 and ‘neo-corporatism’, according to Bruno and Sachs, Lehmbruch and Schmitter are –0.37, –0.29, and –0.60, respectively, while the corresponding correlations for increases in unemployment are –0.11, –0.14, and –0.33, respectively.

47 Shalev, , ‘Class Conflict, Corporatism and Comparison: A Japanese Enigma’.Google Scholar

48 As Therborn, G. (Why Some Peoples Are More Unemployed Than Others)Google Scholar has pointed out, the societal bargaining countries are outside the EEC and have therefore had more room for economic-political manoeuvering.

49 It is striking that in the early 1980s the Reagan administration was much more daring in its use of expansionary measures than the conservative governments in Germany and also in Britain, although the latter country did not suffer from the second oil shock. See Tobin, J., ‘Impasse of the 1980s: Locomotives who Can't or Won't’, The World Economy, 7 (1984), 522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar