Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T05:21:45.226Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

In medio stat virtus: Theoretical and methodological extremes regarding reciprocity will not explain complex social behaviors

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 January 2012

Claudia Civai
Affiliation:
SISSA/ISAS–International School for Advanced Studies, via Bonomea, 265, 34136 Trieste, Italy. [email protected]://www.sissa.it/cns/[email protected]
Alan Langus
Affiliation:
SISSA/ISAS–International School for Advanced Studies, via Bonomea, 265, 34136 Trieste, Italy. [email protected]://www.sissa.it/cns/[email protected]

Abstract

Guala contests the validity of strong reciprocity as a key element in shaping social behavior by contrasting evidence from experimental games to that of natural and historic data. He suggests that in order to understand the evolution of social behavior researchers should focus on natural data and weak reciprocity. We disagree with Guala's proposal to shift the focus of the study from one extreme of the spectrum (strong reciprocity) to the other extreme (weak reciprocity). We argue that the study of the evolution of social behavior must be comparative in nature, and we point out experimental evidence that shows that social behavior is not cooperation determined by a set of fixed factors. We argue for a model that sees social behavior as a dynamic interaction of genetic and environmental factors.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bicchieri, C. (2006) The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C. & Zhang, J. (2010) An embarrassment of riches: Modeling social preferences in Ultimatum Game. In: Handbook of the philosophy of economics, ed. Maki, U., pp. 119. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Blount, S. (1995) When social outcomes aren't fair: The effect of causal attributions on preferences. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 63:131–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brosnan, S. F. & de Waal, F. B. M. (2003) Monkeys reject unequal pay. Nature 143:297–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Civai, C., Corradi-Dell'Acqua, C., Gamer, M. & Rumiati, R. I. (2010a) Are irrational reactions to unfairness truly emotionally-driven? Dissociated behavioral and emotional responses in the Ultimatum Game task. Cognition 114:8995.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Civai, C., Corradi-Dell'Acqua, C., Rumiati, R. I. & Fink, G. R. (2010b) Disentangling between self- and fairness-related mechanisms in the Ultimatum Game: An fMRI study. Paper presented at the Second Meeting of the Federation of European Societies of Neuropsychology (ESN), September 22–24, 2010, Amsterdam, The Netherlands.Google Scholar
Dana, J., Weber, A. W. & Kuang, J. X. (2007) Exploiting moral wiggle room: Experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Economic Theory 33:6780.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufour, C., Pele, M., Neumann, M., Thierry, B. & Call, J. (2009) Calculated reciprocity after all: Computation behind token transfers in orang-utans. Biology Letters 5:172–75.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dufwenberg, M. & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004) A theory of sequential reciprocity Games and Economic Behavior 47:268–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A. & Fischbacher, U. (2006) A theory of reciprocity Games and Economic Behavior 54:293315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. & Schmidt, K. M. (1999) A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114:817–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fruteau, C., Voelkl, B., Damme, E. & Noe, R. (2009) Supply and demand determine the market value of food providers in wild vervet monkeys. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA 106:2007–12.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M. & the ABC Research Group (1999) Simple heuristics that make us smart. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gneezy, U. & Rustichini, A. (2000) Pay enough or don't pay at all. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115:791810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güroğlu, B., van den Bos, W., Rombouts, S. A. R. B. & Crone, E. A. (2010) Unfair? It depends: Neural correlates of fairness in social context. Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience 4:414–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertwig, R. & Herzog, S. (2009) Fast and frugal heuristics: Tools of social rationality. Social Cognition 27:661–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K. & Smith, V.L. (1996) Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games.American Economic Review. 86, 653–60.Google Scholar
Krieger, M. J. B. & Ross, K. G. (2002) Identification of a major gene regulating complex social behavior. Science 295:328–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langus, A., Petri, J., Nespor, M. & Scharff, C. (in press) The evolutionary emergence of human language. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pillutla, M. M. & Murnighan, J. K. (1996) Unfairness, anger, and spite: Emotional rejections of Ultimatum offers. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 68:208–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, G. E., Fernald, R. D. & Clayton, D. F. (2008) Genes and social behavior. Science 322:896900.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sanfey, A. G., Rilling, J. K., Aaronson, J. A., Nystrom, L. E. & Cohen, J. D. (2003) The neural basis of economic decision-making in the Ultimatum Game. Science 300:1755–58. Available at: http://www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/abstract/300/5626/1755.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Van't Wout, M., Kahn, R. S., Sanfey, A. G. & Aleman, A. (2006) Affective state and decision-making in the Ultimatum Game. Experimental Brain Research 169:564–68.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed