Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-ndw9j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-12T19:48:39.471Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Average Value-at-Risk Minimizing Reinsurance Under Wang's Premium Principle with Constraints

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 August 2013

F. Liu
Affiliation:
Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Waterloo, Waterloo, N2L 3G1, Canada
S.C.P. Yam
Affiliation:
Department of Statistics, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, N.T., Hong Kong

Abstract

In the present work, we study the optimal reinsurance decision problem in which the Average Value-at-Risk of the retained loss is minimized under Wang's premium principle and is also subject to either (1) a budget constraint on reinsurance premium, or (2) a reinsurer's probabilistic benchmark constraint of his potential loss. We show that the optimal reinsurance is a single-insurance layer under Constraint (1), and a cap insurance or a double-insurance layer under Constraint (2); moreover, under Constraint (2), we further establish that under most common circumstances (see Remark after Theorem 3), a cap insurance will suffice to be optimal. Finally, some numerical illustrations will be provided.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © International Actuarial Association 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

[1] Acerbi, C. and Tasche, D. (2002) On the coherence of expected shortfall. Journal of Banking and Finance 26(7), 14871503.Google Scholar
[2] Arrow, K.J. (1963) Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care. American Economic Review 53, 941973.Google Scholar
[3] Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.M. and Heath, D. (1999) Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance 9(3), 203228.Google Scholar
[4] Balbás, A., Balbás, B. and Heras, A. (2009) Optimal reinsurance with general risk measures. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 44(3), 374384.Google Scholar
[5] Basak, S. and Shapiro, A. (2001) Value-at-Risk based risk management: Optimal policies and asset prices. The Review of Financial Studies 14, 371405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6] Blazenko, G. (1985) The design of an optimal insurance policy: Note. The American Economic Review 75, 253255.Google Scholar
[7] Borch, K. (1960) An attempt to determine the optimum amount of stop loss reinsurance. Transactions of the 16th International Congress of Actuaries, 597610.Google Scholar
[8] Borch, K. (1975) Optimal insurance arrangements. ASTIN Bulletin 8, 284290.Google Scholar
[9] Buhlmann, H. and Jewell, W.S. (1979) Optimal risk exchange. ASTIN Bulletin 10, 243262.Google Scholar
[10] Cai, J. and Tan, K.S. (2007) Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance under the VaR and CTE risk measures. ASTIN Bulletin 37(1), 93112.Google Scholar
[11] Cai, J., Tan, K.S., Weng, C. and Zhang, Y. (2008) Optimal reinsurance under VaR and CTE risk measures. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 43(1), 185196.Google Scholar
[12] Cheung, K.C. (2010) Optimal reinsurance revisited – geometric approach. ASTIN Bulletin 40(1), 221239.Google Scholar
[13] Cheung, K.C., Sung, K.C.J., Yam, S.C.P. and Yung, S.P. (2010) Optimal reinsurance under general law-invariant risk measures. To appear in Scandinavian Actuarial Journal.Google Scholar
[14] Delbaen, F. (2000) Coherent risk measures. Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Cattedra.Google Scholar
[15] Delbaen, F. (2002) Coherent risk measures on general probability spaces. Advances in Finance and Stochastics, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 137.Google Scholar
[16] Denuit, M. and Vermandele, C. (1998) Optimal reinsurance and stop-loss order. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 22, 229233.Google Scholar
[17] Dhaene, J., Vanduffel, S., Tang, Q., Goovaerts, M., Kaas, R. and Vyncke, D. (2006) Risk measures and comonotonicity: a review. Stochastic Models 22, 573606.Google Scholar
[18] Embrechts, P. (2000) Extreme value theory: Potential and limitations as an integrated risk management tool. Derivatives Use, Trading and Regulation 6, 449456.Google Scholar
[19] Föllmer, H. and Schied, A. (2002) Convex measures of risk and trading constraints. Finance and Stochastics 6(4), 429447.Google Scholar
[20] Föllmer, H. and Schied, A. (2004) Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time. Walter de Gruyter, Berlin.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[21] Frittelli, M. and Rossaza Gianin, E. (2002) Putting order in risk measures. Journal of Banking and Finance 26, 14731486.Google Scholar
[22] Gerber, H.U. (1979) An Introduction to Mathematical Risk Theory. S.S. Huebner Foundation for Insurance Education, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.Google Scholar
[23] Guerra, M. and Centeno, M.L. (2008) Optimal reinsurance policy: The adjustment coefficient and the expected utility criteria. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 42(2), 529539.Google Scholar
[24] Gollier, C. (1987) The design of optimal insurance contracts without the nonnegativity constraint on claims. The Journal of Risk and Insurance 54, 314324.Google Scholar
[25] Heath, D. and Ku, H. (2004) Pareto equilibria with coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance 14(2), 163172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[26] Hull, J.C. (2010) Risk Management and Financial Institutions. Pearson, U.S.A. Google Scholar
[27] Kaluszka, M. (2004a) Mean-variance optimal reinsurance arrangements. Scandinarian Actuarial Journal 1, 2841.Google Scholar
[28] Kaluszka, M. (2004b) An extension of Arrow's result on optimality of a stop loss contract. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 35(3), 527536.Google Scholar
[29] Kaluszka, M. (2005) Optimal reinsurance under convex principles of premium calculation. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 36(3), 375398.Google Scholar
[30] Moore, K.S. and Young, V.R. (2006) Optimal insurance in a continuous-time model. Insurance Mathematics and Economics 39, 4768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[31] von Neumann, J. and Morgenstern, O. (1944) Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
[32] Raviv, A. (1979) The design of an optimal insurance policy. The American Economic Review 69, 8496.Google Scholar
[33] Rockafellar, R.T. and Uryasev, S. (2001) Conditional Value-at-Risk for general loss distributions. ISE Dept., University of Florida.Google Scholar
[34] Sung, K.C.J., Yam, S.C.P., Yung, S.P. and Zhou, J.H. (2011) Behavioral Optimal Insurance. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 49(3), 418428.Google Scholar
[35] Tan, K.S., Weng, C. and Zhang, Y. (2009) VaR and CTE Criteria for optimal quota-share and stop-loss reinsurance. North American Actuarial Journal 13(4), 459482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[36] Wang, S. (1996) Premium calculation by transforming the layer premium density. ASTIN Bulletin 26, 7192.Google Scholar
[37] Wang, S., Young, V.R. and Panjer, H.H. (1997) Axiomatic characterization of insurance prices. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 21(2), 173183.Google Scholar
[38] Yaari, M.E. (1987) The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 55, 95115.Google Scholar
[39] Yaari, S., Young V.R. and Panjer, H.H. (1997) Axiomatic characterization of insurance prices. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 21(2), 173183.Google Scholar
[40] Young, V. R. (1999) Optimal insurance under Wang's premium principle. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 25, 109122.Google Scholar