Introduction
Farm policy in the United States has increasingly emphasized crop insurance as the main risk-management option for farmers. To this end, the Federal Crop Insurance Corporation (FCIC) subsidizes crop insurance premiums so farmers do not bear the full cost of insurance. Program participation has increased rapidly in recent decades. The percentage of crop acres insured under the program grew from 36 percent in 1990 to 73 percent in 2000 and has since risen above 80 percent of all cropland. Program costs have also grown substantially. In 2012, the federal government spent over $14 billion on the crop insurance program, up from $1.4 billion in 1995 (USDA RMA 2016).
The Conservation Reserve Program (CRP) is America's largest voluntary conservation program. CRP pays farmers to remove environmentally sensitive cropland from production and plant resource-conserving covers such as grasses and trees. As of 2017, 23.4 million acres were enrolled in the program nationwide, costing the government $1.8 billion (USDA FSA 2018). CRP has been touted for producing environmental and wildlife benefits that more than offset its cost to taxpayers (Wu and Weber Reference Wu and Weber2012). Wildlife and recreation amenities conferred by conserving cropland generate positive spillover effects. Gleason et al. (2008) estimate that CRP helped restore 5.4 million acres of migratory bird habitat in the Prairie Pothole Region of the Northern Great Plains.
The purpose of this paper is to examine the acreage effects of crop insurance on CRP. Crop insurance subsidies may affect CRP participation by altering the expected returns associated with marginal cropland. Crop insurance subsidies lower the out-of-pocket expense of insurance relative to potential losses, making environmentally sensitive cropland more attractive for planting insurable crops. The government may be effectively competing with itself over sensitive cropland by sponsoring conflicting interests.
I hypothesize that additional acreage insured under federal crop insurance draws down the amount of land enrolled in CRP. Displacement can be at most one-for-one (i.e., an acre taken out of CRP cannot increase production by more than one acre). Therefore, I predict the crowding-out effect to be between zero and one and small. The effect is also likely to vary geographically. In homogenous parts of the country where land eligible for CRP is plentiful and the margin between production and retirement is thin, such as the Upper Midwest and the Corn Belt, crowding out will be more pronounced. In areas where CPR-eligible land is scarce and crop production competes with many land use practices, such as haying or livestock grazing, the effect will be less detectable or nonexistent.
Land on the extensive margin of production can be more erodible and prone to nutrient runoff, and it may require greater application of chemical fertilizers. Hence, government policies that reduce the economic vulnerability of land could encourage negative environmental outcomes (Lubowski et al. 2006). In their seminal paper, Goodwin, Vandeveer, and Deal (Reference Goodwin, Vandeveer and Deal2004) show small but statistically significant increases in acreage planted to insured crops. Young, Vandeveer, and Schnepf (Reference Young, Vandeveer and Schnepf2001) find similarly small acreage effects. They simulate the complete elimination of all crop-insurance subsidies, finding that total acres in production would shrink by a mere 0.4 percent.
Though small, acreage effects may imply larger environmental damage if occurring at the extensive margin. Areas likely to shift into production due to crop insurance are more susceptible to environmental damage (Wu and Adams Reference Wu and Adams2001). Wu (Reference Wu1999) demonstrates that crop insurance encourages the conversion of land from low-impact pasture and hay to chemically intensive corn production. Environmental effects also vary regionally. As many as 157,900 acres of grassland in the Prairie Pothole Region were converted to crop production as a direct result of crop-insurance subsidies, according to Miao, Hennessy, and Feng (Reference Miao, Hennessy and Feng2016), while Walters et al. (Reference Walters, Shumway, Chouinard and Wandschneider2012) show both negative and positive environmental effects attributable to crop insurance, depending on geography.
Several papers examine the factors that influence CRP enrollment and re-enrollment. High commodity prices are found to draw acreage out of CRP (Secchi et al. Reference Secchi, Gassman, Williams and Babcock2009; Rashford, Walker, and Bastian Reference Rashford, Walker and Bastian2010; Stubbs 2014; Wachenheim, Lesch, and Dhingra Reference Wachenheim, Lesch and Dhingra2014), while Ifft, Rajagopal, and Weldzuis (2018) find that proximity to ethanol production facilities actually increased CRP re-enrollment rates in the Upper Great Plains and Corn Belt. Participants also have non-financial motives, including preferences for wildlife habitat and environmental amenities (Lambert et al. 2006). Hendricks and Er (Reference Hendricks and Er2018) point out the importance of government policy in shaping CRP enrollment over time. They show that program administrators exert influence by adjusting the national enrollment cap and setting maximum acceptable bids for land offered through the General Sign-up convention. These mechanisms are at least partly informed by supply management concerns (e.g., the enrollment cap typically falls [rises] following periods of high [low] commodity prices).
The influence of subsidized crop insurance on the CRP has important policy implications but has not been addressed extensively in the literature. Miao et al. (2016) show that, because it ignores savings from avoided crop insurance subsidies, the current CRP enrollment mechanism is inefficient. Miao et al. (2016) propose an alternative mechanism that both increases enrollment in CRP and generates environmental benefits without altering total government outlays.
Lubowski et al. (2006) simulate what would have happened to various types of land had subsidy increases brought about by the Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994 (FCIRA) not occurred. They estimate that the FCIRA reduced acreage in CRP by only 0.11 percent. Claassen, Langpap, and Wu (Reference Claassen, Langpap and Wu2017) examine how federal crop insurance influences land use and cropping patterns in the Corn Belt states. Using parcel-level data, they simulate the introduction of revenue crop insurance, showing a decline of 0.23 percent in CRP acreage. Feng, Hennessy, and Miao (Reference Feng, Hennessy and Miao2013) find that increasing crop insurance subsidies by one dollar per acre would reduce the amount of land offered for CRP enrollment by about 6,000 acres in the Dakotas.
The aforementioned studies generally show that crop insurance has a small effect on the conversion of land out of CRP and into crop production. Any environmental consequences that follow are found to be small or negligible. Both Lubowski et al. (2006) and Claassen, Langpap, and Wu (Reference Claassen, Langpap and Wu2017), however, rely on simulations and do not make the acreage effects of insurance on CRP the focus of their analysis, while Feng, Hennessy, and Miao (Reference Feng, Hennessy and Miao2013) examine a single geographic region.
I extend the work of Miao et al. (2016), Lubowski et al. (2006), Claassen, Langpap, and Wu (Reference Claassen, Langpap and Wu2017), and Feng, Hennessy, and Miao (Reference Feng, Hennessy and Miao2013) on the extensive margin by directly estimating the acre-for-acre impact of subsidized crop insurance on CRP enrollment over an extensive period. I examine the relationship between insurance and CRP regionally, giving results greater external validity. Previous studies either consider the national level or specific sub-regional geographic areas. Using a comprehensive dataset spanning 25 years, I estimate the change in CRP acreage resulting from an additional acre insured under federal crop insurance.
Results indicate that crop insurance crowds out a small but statistically significant amount of CRP land (an average of three acres removed for every 1,000 additional acres insured) and that effect sizes vary by region. Regions with both high row-crop production and CRP participation such as the Corn Belt, Great Lakes, and Northern Plains are the most susceptible to crowd out, while I detect little or no crowd out in other parts of the country. Two forces may be driving regional differences: variation in the amount and type of land eligible for CRP and land use heterogeneity. Because the analysis is performed at the county level, aggregating individual farms with positive CRP enrollment together with ineligible farms may introduce an aggregation bias that underreports the true effect. Regions with high CRP eligibility, such as the Corn Belt, will be less affected by this type of bias than regions where CRP-eligible land is sparse (e.g., states in the Southwest). Secondly, the effect of crop insurance on CRP depends on the number of alternative land uses for crop production to displace. Though small, the effects detected in this paper are consistent with the existing literature.
In the following section, I present a theoretical framework to model the trade-off between crop production and land retirement. From there I describe the data used for this analysis and discuss the empirical strategy, results, and potential policy implications.
Theoretical Model of Crop Insurance and CRP Trade-Off
A representative producer faces a trade-off between production and participation in CRP. The relative costs and benefits of each option determine how much of the producer's total land holdings he or she devotes to each. The availability of government subsidized crop insurance may change the size of these relative benefits in favor of production over conservation.
I model the behavior of the representative producer following Chang and Boisvert (Reference Chang and Boisvert2009), who offer a household production model approach.Footnote 1 The producer allocates his or her total endowment of land, $\bar{A}$, between crop production, A p, and CRP enrollment, A c. Though the entire endowment of land may be planted to crops, soil productivity varies within the field. A portion of land, A m(q), is considered marginal cropland characterized by poor soil productivity (e.g., highly erodible land [HEL]). The amount of marginal cropland is exogenously determined by q, the soil characteristics of the farm which vary across geographic regions. The amount of marginal cropland eligible for enrollment into CRP is $\bar{A}_c\equiv t\cdot A_m\lpar q\rpar $, where t ∈ [0, 1] reflects national and regional acreage caps set by government policy.Footnote 2 Limits on enrollment vary over time (national cap) and across regions (county cap).Footnote 3 Given there are only two land use choices, the amount of marginal cropland in production is defined as $A_p^m \equiv A_m\lpar q\rpar -A_c$, the difference between marginal land and the portion of marginal land enrolled in CRP.
I employ a Just and Pope (Reference Just and Pope1979) production function where output (yield per acre harvested) is a function of both a deterministic component and a stochastic shock.
The deterministic component,f( · ), depends on the average soil quality of land in production, represented by the term Γ( · ).Footnote 4 Average soil quality itself depends on two factors: an exogenous soil quality index q, which varies regionally and across farms, and $A_p^m $, the amount of marginal cropland placed in production. The former captures regional heterogeneity in cropping capability, where Γq >0. For example, a well-drained farm in Iowa will be endowed with a higher q than a typical farm in the arid West. The latter incorporates the effect of intra-field land allocation choices on crop yields. The average quality of soil in production will fall as additional marginal acres are brought into production (“fence to fence” planting), making the partial ${\rm \Gamma} _{A_p^m} $ negative.
The stochastic portion of yield is captured by the termε, which represents negative production shocks such as drought, hail, or flooding. Yield risk is assumed to be i.i.d. distributed, where ε ≤ 0, ${{\open E}}\lpar {\rm \varepsilon} \rpar = {\bar{\rm \varepsilon}} \lt 0$, and$\; {\rm VAR\lpar \varepsilon \rpar } = {\rm \sigma} _{\rm \varepsilon} ^2 $. Production shocks are mitigated by the average soil quality of planted land. Higher values of Γ( · ), due either to superior regional soil characteristics or a smaller amount of marginal land in production, attenuates the negative effect of ε on yields toward zero.Footnote 5 The output price per unit of yield, p, is assumed to be exogenous to the producer and independent of land-use decisions.
The farmer purchases federal crop insurance on planted acres, which triggers an indemnity payment, $I\lpar {\rm \varepsilon}\comma \; {\rm \Gamma} \lpar q\comma \; A_p^m \rpar \rpar $, per acre in the event of a loss caused by the random shock,ε. Higher values of ε and lower values of Γ( · ) raise the frequency and size of insurance indemnities. The total premium cost per acre, $\nu \lpar {\bar{\rm \varepsilon}}\comma \; q\rpar $, is made to be actuarially fair for a given region based on expected losses, $\bar{\varepsilon} $, and regional soil characteristics.Footnote 6 The government subsidizes premiums at rate s ∈ (0, 1), so the per-acre insurance cost to the producer is$\; \lpar 1-s\rpar \cdot \nu \lpar {\bar{\rm \varepsilon}}\comma \; q\rpar $.
The producer receives an annual rental payment, r(q, t), for each acre enrolled in CRP. Rental rates are determined by the USDA Farm Service Agency (FSA) according to the soil properties of the region and prevailing cropland rent but are also influenced by government policy which sets maximum rates participants may receive during a given period.Footnote 7
The producer allocates land to maximize expected utility from farm profits, π(A p, A c), and environmental amenities generated by land enrolled in CRP, e(A c). Environmental amenities include recreation and wildlife viewing and capture the non-monetary motivations for enrolling in the program. The importance of environmental amenities in the producer's utility likely vary according to demographics and farm type (Lambert et al. 2006).
The producer's constrained optimization problem is as follows:
subject to:
Constraint equation 4 assumes the producer can only allocate land between crop production and retirement. This is most representative of regions such as the Corn Belt, where soil productivity restricts the number of competing land uses, but is less representative of areas such as the West and Southern Plains, where crop production must compete with grassland pasture and forest (Bigelow and Borchers 2017). Constraint equation 5 defines the CRP eligibility limit as a function of the amount of marginal land, determined by regional soil characteristics, and government policy. Note that equation 5 may not be binding. In such a case, part or all the land eligible for CRP is put into production. Non-negativity constraints for the choice variables are stated in equation 6.
Substituting equation 4 into the objective function and using the definition of marginal cropland makes the constrained optimization problem a function of only A c.Footnote 8
Kuhn Tucker conditions defining an optimum are as follows:
where ${{\open U}}_\pi $ and ${{\open U}}_e$ represent marginal utility from farm profit and environmental amenities, respectively. Equation 8 shows that the optimal land allocation equates the expected marginal utility of crop production profit with the expected marginal utility of CRP revenue plus the marginal utility of environmental amenities generated by land in CRP minus λ, the shadow price of CRP eligibility. The shadow price represents the marginal utility of increasing the amount of land eligible for CRP, either by changing the endowment of marginal cropland or by raising the number of acres the government allows to enter the program. If the producer derives a large amount of utility from CRP's environmental benefits and would like to enroll more than is allowed by the cap (i.e., if constraint equation 5 is binding, a higher enrollment cap would cause him or her to put more land in CRP and increase their optimal utility). Lambda is then positive if A c = tA m(q) and zero if A c <tA m(q).
The optimal choice of A c is found by simultaneously satisfying equations 8–11, which I express in reduced form as a function of exogenous variables.
The relationship of interest is the effect of decreasing the out-of-pocket cost of insurance, which increases the returns to production (including on marginal cropland) on the amount of acreage retired into CRP. Provided actuarially fair premiums remain constant, the per-acre cost of insurance to the producer will fall due to an increase in the government-determined subsidy rates. The sign and size of the relationship between subsidy rates and CRP are a function of the exogenous covariates of the model: output price, weather shocks, regional soil characteristics, and the enrollment cap.
Importantly, the relationship at the farm level depends on the degree to which land can come in and out of the program (i.e., how limited CRP enrollment is by constraint equation 5). If regional soil properties, q, and the government enrollment cap, t, are such that little or no land is eligible for CRP to begin with, any change in insurance subsidies (or any other variable) will have little or no impact on CRP enrollment. Conversely, if tA m(q) is positive but constraint equation 5 is binding, then all eligible land that can be enrolled in CRP is enrolled. The amount of land the producer would like to enroll may greatly exceed eligibility. CRP will again be unresponsive to changes in crop insurance. This example reflects a farm in a county at or near its CRP acreage cap.
The effect of insurance subsidization on CRP is best observed in farms where $\bar{A}_c\lpar q\rpar \gt 0$ and 0 <A c <tA m(q). Such cases allow CRP participation to respond positively and negatively to variations in insurance subsidies. Insurance effects will be most evident on farms that closely reflect the model's assumption that land uses are limited to production and conservation. Farms in the Corn Belt, for example, embody the insurance-conservation trade-off because the margin between crop production and CRP is thin relative to regions with more land-use heterogeneity. In other words, the true effect of insurance on CRP participation will appear in areas plentiful in CRP-eligible land, having direct competition between CRP and row-crop production, and where the CRP enrollment constraint is non-binding.
In general, the eligibility constraint creates a limited dependent variable problem that one would ideally estimate with a censored regression model at the farm level. Because I estimate the CRP-insurance relationship using county-level data, however, the above conditions introduce the possibility of aggregation bias. Aggregating farms that are constrained in their CRP participation together with unconstrained farms may give the appearance of sufficient CRP engagement at the county level but will not take into consideration the limited responses that can be made on-farm. The true effect of insurance will emerge in counties where farms are homogenous in their ability to increase or decrease enrollment in CRP (i.e., where both CRP-eligible land is plentiful and crop production competes directly with it for land use). In the Results section, I discuss how this type of aggregation bias may partially explain differences in effect sizes observed across U.S. farm production regions.Footnote 9
Data
Data for this project come from the USDA Risk Management Agency, the USDA Farm Service Agency, the Chicago Board of Trade, the USDA National Agricultural Statistical Service, and the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. Data are observed at the county level for the years 1989 to 2013. The chosen years span the enactment of four major crop-insurance policies that exogenously increased insurance participation (FCIRA of 1994, ad hoc rate increases, ARPA of 2000, and the 2008 Farm Bill) as well as 14 separate CRP General Sign-ups and four different national enrollment caps. The geographic scope of the study includes all 48 contiguous states. The USDA Risk Management Agency (RMA) operates the federal crop-insurance program and maintains thorough records of all crop-insurance policies sold since 1981. RMA reports these data at the county level and makes them publicly available through an online database. From RMA, I collected the number of acres insured, total premiums charged, and total government subsidies paid in each county by policy type.Footnote 10
County-level CRP enrollment data come from the USDA Farm Service Agency (FSA), which provides county totals for acres retired and total rental fees paid every year. To determine the average CRP rental fee per acre, I simply divide total payments made in a county by the number of acres enrolled. I correct CRP rental rates for inflation using the Producer Price Index (PPI). I also observe the years in which a General Sign-up or Continuous Sign-up was offered between 1989 and 2013.Footnote 11 Continuous Sign-up was made available in every year after 1996, while General Sign-ups occurred in 1989, 1991, 1992, 1995, 1997, 1998, 2000, 2003, 2004, 2006, and 2010–2013. The relevant measure of CRP participation over time is the total CRP acreage enrolled in a county. This number includes both acres enrolled through General and Continuous Sign-up conventions. I exclude counties from the dataset that have no CRP enrollment in any of the 25 years examined.Footnote 12
Commodity prices play a key role in both land retirement and crop-insurance choices. Harvest prices are not known when crop-insurance policies and CRP contracts are established, so landowner decisions in each year are based on expectations. For insurance, RMA uses averages of December corn, November soybeans, and September wheat futures prices traded during the month of February to determine premiums and guarantees.Footnote 13 I collect futures prices for corn, soybeans, and wheat from the Chicago Board of Trade through an online database made available by Quandl Inc.Footnote 14 I take the average February settlement price for each futures contract for the years 1989 to 2013 and adjust for inflation using the PPI for each commodity.Footnote 15 From the USDA National Agricultural Statistical Service (NASS) I collect the number of acres harvested of corn, soybeans, and wheat in each observed county from 1979 to 2013. From this I calculate a measure of each commodity's importance based on its percentage of total acres harvested over the previous 10 years. I then create a weighted average of all three futures prices as follows:
where
The term H jiτ represents the total acres harvested of crop j in county i during yearτ for j = corn, soybeans, and wheat. Missing values for crop production weights are replaced with averages for the state in which the county resides.
The National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) publishes the Palmer Drought Severity Index (PDSI) at the state level for all contiguous states. The PDSI measures soil moisture levels using both current and previous conditions, making the PDSI a good indicator of long-run trends in precipitation. Positive values indicate wet conditions, while negative values correspond to drought. From annual average PDSI values I create an indicator variable equal to one in years when states experienced moderate-to-extreme drought conditions.Footnote 16
The compiled dataset includes 2,756 counties observed between 1989 and 2013, for a total of 68,900 observations. Table 1 summarizes the variables described above for each of the relevant crop-insurance policy periods. The important policy changes that occurred during the observation period included the Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994 (FCIRA), ad hoc subsidy rate increases in 1998 and 1999, the Agricultural Risk Protection Act of 2000 (ARPA), and the 2008 Farm Bill. Each policy made meaningful changes to the schedule of crop-insurance subsidy rates for the purpose of increasing participation. Figures 1 and 2 depict the impact of these policy changes on different crop-insurance types, and Figure 3 shows the commensurate trend in overall crop-insurance participation between 1989 and 2013. The vertical dashed lines correspond to the passage of each of the four major policies. I consider a policy period the years between the passing of a given crop-insurance law and the enactment of a new policy.
Notes: CRP rental rates are adjusted for inflation using annual averages of the Producer Price Index for all goods. Commodity futures prices are adjusted for inflation using the Producer Price Index specific to each commodity for the month of February.
Sources: CRP data come from USDA FSA statistics on CRP enrollment. Crop insurance data provided by USDA RMA data files. PDSI generated by state specific queries on NOAA Climate Monitoring website. Futures prices from the Chicago Board of Trade are made available by Quandl Inc. Crop harvest data downloaded from USDA NASS Quick Stats online database. Producer Price Indices for each commodity were retrieved from the St. Louis Fed FRED online database.
Total acreage under federal crop insurance exhibits a general upward trend throughout the observation period, with large jumps occurring after FCIRA in 1994, ARPA of 2000, and the Farm Bill of 2008. Acres insured more than doubled after passage of the 1994 Act to over 70,000 acres per county. Trends in subsidy rates for various policy types illustrate the differential effects of the four policy changes. For example, because catastrophic insurance (CAT) carries a 50 percent coverage level, changes in subsidy rates for 50 and 55 percent policies reflect the full subsidization of CAT insurance brought about by FCIRA in 1994. Similarly, buy-up policies experience their largest increases in subsidy rates during the ad hoc and ARPA policy periods. Note that 80 percent policies and revenue-based policies do not enter the market until 1993 and 1996, respectively, so their subsidy rates are zero prior to the FCIRA policy period.
Average CRP enrollment rises and falls between 11,000 and 13,000 acres per county during the study period. National CRP enrollment was originally capped at 45 million acres but has changed over time to reflect budgetary conditions and policy goals. Figure 4 illustrates the trend in CRP participation and the total enrollment caps from 1989 to 2013. Enrollment increased gradually until 1996 thanks to successful early General Sign-ups in 1989, 1991, and 1992, but suffered throughout the late 1990s despite the introduction of the Continuous Sign-up convention. Changes in total enrollment over time generally reflect the national enrollment cap, commodity prices, and climate (Claassen and Hellerstein 2008; Secchi et al. Reference Secchi, Gassman, Williams and Babcock2009; Rashford, Walker, and Bastian Reference Rashford, Walker and Bastian2010; Hendricks and Er Reference Hendricks and Er2018).
Drought conditions are most widespread in 1999 and 2000 and from 2009 to 2013.Footnote 17 Inflation adjusted futures prices for corn, soybeans, and wheat are also presented in Table 1 along with the historical proportion of acres harvested of each crop. Expected price refers to the production weighted average futures price as described above.
Estimating the Impact of Crop Insurance on CRP
The total number of CRP acres in any given year can be modeled as previous acres enrolled less exiting acreage plus new acres entering the program. The number of acres leaving the program can be expressed as a proportion of the total acres enrolled the year prior. Initially, I assume there is an average annual exit rate ofδ, which is constant over time and across counties.Footnote 18 I test this assumption in Appendix B, showing that the exit (re-enrollment) rate is significantly higher (lower) during years when the national enrollment cap is low.
The total number of acres enrolled in CRP in county i during year t can be expressed as follows:Footnote 19
Net new acres entering CRP in each year, represented byηit, is a function of the number of acres insured under federal crop insurance, Acres Insuredit, a vector of exogenous control variables that affect both insurance and conservation behavior, Xit, county fixed effects, αi, and year fixed effects, τt.Footnote 20 The vector Xit includes CRP rental rates, expectations of drought, and expected commodity prices. County fixed effects control for regional characteristics such as soil quality and preferences for environmental amenities. Policy changes that impact all counties in each year, namely, the national CRP enrollment cap, are captured by year fixed effects. Assuming linear relationships between CRP participation and all explanatory variables, I estimate the following panel data fixed effects regression:
I first estimate a model without time controls as a baseline to compare with year fixed effects.
A primary incentive for producers to enter CRP is the per-acre rental rate, represented in the model by the variableRentit, which should have a positive and significant impact on CRP participation.Footnote 21 The estimate of the average CRP exit rate δ can be calculated by subtracting the estimated coefficient on lagged CRP acreage from one. To control for climate shocks that impact both CRP and crop-insurance decisions, I include a drought indicator. The variableDroughtst−1 is a dummy variable equal to one if the county located in state s has an average Palmer Drought Severity Index (PDSI) of negative two or below in year t − 1.Footnote 22 Lagged drought conditions represent expectations of future droughts which may positively or negatively affect CRP acreage, as poor growing conditions make risk-free CRP rental fees more attractive while at the same time increasing expected payouts from insurance. Weighted average commodity futures prices are represented by the variableP it. As CRP rental payments are fixed for the duration of the contract, high crop prices raise the opportunity cost of CRP. I expect futures prices to negatively impact CRP enrollment.
The right-hand side variable of interest is the total number of acres insured in county i during year t. I predict that land insured under federal crop insurance crowds out potential new acres entering CRP and causes existing acres to exit the program. The magnitude of the effect, however, should be small, in accordance with previous literature (Young, Vandeveer, and Schnepf Reference Young, Vandeveer and Schnepf2001; Goodwin, Vandeveer, and Deal Reference Goodwin, Vandeveer and Deal2004; Lubowski et al. 2006; Claassen, Langpap, and Wu Reference Claassen, Langpap and Wu2017)
Endogeneity between insurance activity and CRP complicates the above specification. Producers make crop-insurance and land-retirement decisions jointly. Without an exogenous source of variation in insurance use, the estimated impact of insured acres on CRP will reflect this joint determination. Specifically, $\hat{\beta} $ may capture how CRP participation influences planting and insurance decisions. Moreover, equation 15 does not incorporate subsidies for crop insurance but only the total amount of insured acreage. The number of insured acres within a county may vary for many reasons unrelated to subsidization which are not the focus of this paper. An endogeneity issue also emerges in the CRP rental rate variable. Because the rental rate variable is calculated as an average for each county-year, acres enrolled in CRP enters both sides of the regression equation. If estimated as written, the relationship between acres enrolled and program compensation will be biased (likely in the downward direction).
I address these issues by employing an instrumental variables approach. Government policy exclusively sets the subsidy rates applied to each type of crop-insurance policy and coverage level. This schedule of subsidy rates has changed over time to encourage greater participation in the program and reduce the need for disaster assistance. I exploit increases in subsidy rates resulting from four major crop-insurance policy changes, the Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994 (FCIRA), ad hoc subsidy rate increases in 1998 and 1999, the Agricultural Risk Protection Act of 2000 (ARPA), and the 2008 Farm Bill. Figures 1 and 2 illustrate the impact of government policy changes (denoted by vertical dashed lines) on subsidy rates of different types of crop insurance.Footnote 23 The impact of these policy changes can be seen clearly in Figure 3. A marked increase in acres insured follows the enactment of each piece of legislation, with the exception of the 2008 Farm Bill, which appears to have had a delayed effect on participation.Footnote 24
I use dummy variables for each policy period (FCIRA, ad hoc, ARPA, and the 2008 Farm Bill) to instrument for changes in the number of acres insured. Policy indicators can explain within-county variation in acres insured over time but do not provide the spatial (between-county) variation necessary for proper instrumentation. Crop-insurance legislation is set at the national level, meaning every county in the dataset receives the policy “treatment” at the same time but may not receive it in the same way. A measure of the degree to which various policies affect a county is required. To do this, I measure preferences for different types of insurance prior to the enactment of each legislative change.
From Figure 1 we see that FCIRA of 1994 dramatically impacts subsidy rates for 50 and 55 percent policies, while “buy-up” plans (60 percent coverage and above) experience smaller but meaningful increases in subsidy rates. The large change in subsidy rates for low-coverage plans reflects the introduction of fully subsidized catastrophic coverage (CAT). To measure the extent to which the 1994 Act impacts a county, I calculate the percent of total cropland insured at each coverage level category (50–55 percent, 60–65 percent, 70–75 percent, and 80–85 percent) in the period prior to the enactment of FCIRA (1989 to 1994).Footnote 25 This approach generates between-county variation in exposure to FCIRA subsidy rate increases that is unrelated to CRP decisions.
Ad hoc subsidy increases passed in 1998 and 1999 raise subsidy rates for buy-up and revenue plans (see Figures 1 and 2) but leave low-coverage and yield-based policies relatively unaffected. ARPA of 2000 added to these changes, and the Farm Bill of 2008 further increases rates for high-coverage products. I capture a county's exposure to these policy changes by calculating the percentage of cropland insured under each coverage level in the periods directly preceding the passage of each legislative change.
Insurance participation prior to each policy change is measured as a percentage of total cropland to control for the scale of production capacity in each county. The USDA calculates total cropland for each county as part of the Census of Agriculture every five years. I use acres of cropland in 1992 to calculate percentages of insured acres during the pre-FCIRA period, cropland in 1997 to calculate insurance percentages in the FCIRA and ad hoc policy periods, and cropland in 2002 for the ARPA period.Footnote 26
To generate instruments for insured acres, I interact these policy-exposure measures with dummy variables representing each of the four policy change periods.Footnote 27 These interactions can be used to determine how much a county sees its effective subsidy rates increase and can be used to estimate the variation in insured acreage due only to changes in government policy and not to contemporaneous land-use decisions. Pre-policy exposure measures reflect a county's entrenched preferences for certain types of insurance. Therefore, when new legislation acts on these preexisting preferences, causing insurance participation to rise or fall, we can be confident that the resulting variation in acres insured is attributed only to exogenous government policy and not jointly determined CRP enrollment.
To provide further spatial variation in insurance use that is uncorrelated with conservation decisions, I include a one-year lag of acres insured as an additional instrument. While the policy-change instruments measure the impact of subsidy rate increases on insurance participation (demand response), lagged insurance use measures of a county's preference for crop insurance more generally. Lagged insured acres are highly predictive of future insurance use within a county but are predetermined with respect to current CRP enrollment (or exit) decisions.
Following a similar approach, I use a one-year lag of the county CRP rental rate to address the endogeneity between current rental rates and acres enrolled in CRP. This strategy resolves the downward bias in estimated rental rate effects that result from averaging total payments over the number of acres in CRP. CRP rental rates are made to reflect prevailing cash rental rates for non-irrigated farmland of different soil types. Because soil types are unchanged from year to year, lagged rates serve as strong predictors of future rates. Any remaining year-to-year fluctuations in CRP rent reflect changes in farm profitability (price and yield shocks) and government policy (maximum acceptable bids), which independently affect current CRP acreage decisions. Conditional on lagged CRP enrollment, drought expectations, commodity futures prices, and government policy (year fixed effects), prior CRP rental rates will be correlated with current rental rates but uncorrelated with the error term in equation 15. Lagged CRP rental rates are therefore a valid IV for present rental rates.
I perform a two-stage least squares (2SLS) regression using Stata's XTIVREG2 command, which accommodates both instrumental variables and clustering of standard errors. First-stage regression equations predict current insurance participation and CRP rental rates using policy-period dummies, policy-exposure measures, lagged-acres insured, lagged-CRP rental rates, and all exogenous covariates shown in equation 15. In the second-stage regression, predicted values for acres insured and rental rates take the place of the endogenous regressors. See Appendix A for a detailed explanation of the instrumental variables calculation and first-stage regression for insured acreage. Standard errors are clustered at the state level as opposed to the county level following Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (Reference Cameron, Gelbach and Miller2011).Footnote 28
Results
Regression results with county fixed effects and instrumental variables are reported in Table 2.Footnote 29 Specification (1) of Table 2 does not include time controls, while (2) applies year fixed effects to capture the impact of changes in the national enrollment cap. R2 values in both specifications indicate the models fit the data well overall, and first stage F-statistics show strong relevance of instruments to endogenous variables.
Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Estimates generated using Two Stage Least Squares regressions with county fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the state level are shown in parenthesis. Drought is an indicator equal to 1 if the PDSI was less than −2 in the previous year to reflect producer expectations. CRP rental payments are expressed in real terms using the PPI. Futures prices for corn (Dec.), soybeans (Nov.), and wheat (Sep.) are converted to real terms and weighted by historical production of each commodity over the previous 10 years.
As expected, the estimated effect of CRP rent is positive and highly significant in both specifications. A one-dollar increase in real CRP rental rates boosts CRP participation by 25 to 33 acres per county. At the median, this effect implies an elasticity of 0.37 to 0.49 percent.Footnote 30 The model indicates that, on average, 88 percent of existing CRP acres in a county remain in the program from year to year, implying an average exit rate of 12 percent per year.
Enrollment in CRP increases substantially if a drought was present in the previous year, though the estimated coefficient is not statistically significant when year fixed effects are applied. Column (1) of Table 2 shows that a statewide drought increases CRP enrollment by an estimated 314 acres per county. The effect of drought expectations remains positive after including temporal controls but becomes statistically insignificant. Drought conditions are spatially correlated across large parts of the United States during the study period. Because I measure drought as a zero-one dummy variable, year fixed effects absorb much of the variation in the drought variable, leading to the lack of statistical significance in specification (2).Footnote 31
The first specification of Table 2 reports a positive and statistically significant coefficient for commodity futures prices but a negative and significant coefficient when year fixed effects are introduced. Specification (1) contradicts much of the literature showing that high commodity prices raise the opportunity cost of land retirement and remove acreage from programs like CRP. The way futures prices are weighted may explain the discrepancy. The mix of corn, soybeans, and wheat production does not vary drastically over time within counties (see commodity harvest percentages in Table 2). Because futures prices on the Chicago Board of Trade apply to all counties nationwide, the price variable could be picking up non-price-related factors that vary across time but not between counties. Specifically, as pointed out by Roberts and Schlenker (Reference Roberts and Schlenker2013), unobserved shifts in anticipated production can influence commodity price futures, which can bias estimated supply elasticities. The inclusion of year fixed effects captures unobserved, large-scale shifts in retired cropland that affect harvest-time futures prices.Footnote 32 Once yearly fixed effects are applied, the true effect of price expectations can come through. According to column (2) of Table 2, a one-dollar increase in average futures prices removes 234 acres per county from CRP, suggesting a median elasticity of −0.36 percent.
The estimated coefficients on insured acres are statistically significant at the 0.05 significance level under both specification strategies. Instrumental variable results suggest that an additional acre insured in response to higher subsidies decreases the number of acres enrolled in CRP by between 0.003 and 0.004. Put another way, a 1,000-acre increase in the number of acres insured in a county will reduce the number of acres enrolled in CRP in that county by three to four acres. The estimated effects of most explanatory variables in the model are sensitive to the inclusion of year fixed effects which capture CRP policy changes at the national level. Without year fixed effects, the impact of national administrative decisions are channeled indirectly through the covariates of the model. Examining the coefficients on each year dummy variable (suppressed in results tables) confirms work by Hendricks and Er (Reference Hendricks and Er2018), who show that government policy, specifically changes in the national enrollment cap, exerts significant influence over CRP participation over time. Year dummy coefficients generally reflect the trend in the national cap.
Given the impact of year fixed effects on model estimates, I consider the −0.003 insurance effect to be the more reliable of the two estimates. I base all further applications of the estimated crowding out effect on this value. Computed at the median of insured acres and CRP enrollment, the associated elasticity implies that a one percent increase in acres insured under federally subsidized crop insurance reduces the number of acres in CRP by 0.03 percent.Footnote 33
To check for regional differences in crowding out effects, I estimate the IV model with year fixed effects separately for each of the ten farm production regions (see Figure 5). Table 3 displays the point estimates for the effect of acres insured on CRP enrollment and their associated elasticities by farm production region. Standard errors are clustered at the county level as opposed to the state level due to a limited number of states in several of the production regions.
Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Point estimates of the effect of insured acres on acres enrolled in CRP were generated using Two Stage Least Squares regressions with county and year fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the county level as opposed to the state level due to the small number of states in several of the farm production regions. Associated elasticities are computed at the 25th, 50th, and 75th percentiles of insured acreage and the median CRP enrollment for each region.
Crop insurance acreage effects are negative and statistically significant in five of the 10 production regions (Northern Plains, Great Lakes, Corn Belt, Appalachia, and the Southeast) but vary in magnitude from −0.006 to −0.019. Evaluated at the median of the data for each region, these effects translate into losses of between 0.05 and 0.13 percent of CRP acres resulting from a one-percent increase in insurance participation. Large commodity-producing states in the Midwest and Northern Plains have elasticities at or near 0.10 percent at the median, while Appalachian and Southeastern states are closer to 0.05.
Elasticities vary greatly over the distribution of insurance acreage within regions. In the Great Lakes region, for example, a one-percent increase in insured acres reduces CRP acreage by 0.35 percent for a county at the 75th percentile of insurance use and the median for CRP enrollment vs. 0.03 percent for a county at the 25th percentile of insurance use. CRP losses range from 0.03 percent in the lower tail of the insurance distribution to 0.2 percent in the upper tail for counties in the Corn Belt. These estimates are significantly larger than those found by Claassen, Langpap, and Wu (Reference Claassen, Langpap and Wu2017), who predict that the presence of crop insurance in the Corn Belt reduces acreage in CRP by a mere 0.42 percent compared to a no-insurance baseline but are more in line with recent work by Yu, Smith, and Sumner (Reference Yu, Smith and Sumner2018), who find larger acreage responses to crop-insurance subsidization than previous literature.
Relative to the upper Midwest, Appalachian and Southeastern states display lower crowding-out elasticities at the median but have similarly varied effect sizes across their respective insurance acreage distributions. The relationship between insurance and CRP is the least varied in the Northern Plains. However, CRP enrollment in the Northern Plains has declined significantly in recent years, while insurance use has remained high, making potential losses in CRP due to even small increases in insurance larger in percentage terms than are implied by Table 3. Using the most recent data available for Northern Plains counties in 2017, a one-percent increase in insured acres would reduce CRP by 0.2 percent per county.Footnote 34 Crop insurance participation does not appear to crowd out CRP in the Pacific, Mountain West, Southern Plains, Mississippi Delta, or Northeastern farm production regions.
Discussion
I find that expanding crop insurance use by 1,000 acres via government policy reduces CRP enrollment by about three acres on average. A one-percent increase in insurance use draws down CRP participation by a modest 0.03 percent. Goodwin, Vandeveer, and Deal (Reference Goodwin, Vandeveer and Deal2004) predict that an additional acre insured brings between 0.09 and 0.6 acres into production, depending on the crop being insured. My results indicate that a portion of this expansion, between 0.5 and three percent depending on crop type, occurs on land eligible for, or currently in, CRP.
According to the Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute (FAPRI), soil runoff falls by 99 percent when land enters CRP compared to crop production. Enrollment in CRP reduces water erosion of soils by 2.13 tons per acre, nitrogen runoff by 7.73 lbs. per acre, and phosphorus runoff by 1.67 lbs. per acre (FAPRI 2007). Based on my estimates, a one-percent increase in national crop insurance use would increase soil erosion by nearly 20,000 tons, nitrogen loss by over 72,000 lbs, and phosphorus loss by about 16,000 lbs. per year nationwide.Footnote 35 For context, these losses only represent about 0.03 percent of the erosion and nutrient runoff benefits conferred by CRP nationally.Footnote 36 Put another way, a doubling of total insured acreage nationwide would only offset about three percent of the annual water-quality improvements generated by CRP.
The broader environmental costs implied in this study are small but consistent with existing research. Nevertheless, policymakers should be aware of all potential environmental consequences associated with subsidizing crop insurance. Soil erosion creates nutrient runoff which contaminates downstream water sources (e.g., Lake Erie and the Gulf of Mexico) and generates an externality in agricultural input use not borne by producers. Conservation requirements tied to farm support programs have been effective tools for dealing with this issue (Claassen et al. Reference Claassen, Langpap and Wu2017). Since the passage of the 1985 Food Security Act, producers growing on highly erodible land must implement a conservation system to maintain eligibility for federal programs such as price support and disaster payments. Crop insurance premium subsidies were recently added to the list of support programs lost if found in violation of conservation requirements.
Compliance requirements could be extended to specifically target acreage exiting CRP to be planted and insured under federal crop insurance. Because CRP soil characteristics and practices vary by region, conservation requirements are best determined at the state or local level. In this way, I echo the conclusion arrived at by Walters et al. (Reference Walters, Shumway, Chouinard and Wandschneider2012) that uniform national policy recommendations are not an appropriate prescription. States could offer insurance premium cost-shares for producers that retain their most environmentally sensitive cropland in retirement. This could be done through a Continuous CRP Sign-up or by enrolling in the Conservation Reserve Enhancement Program (CREP) which partners with state governments. Furthermore, when insuring land that has been out of production for an extended period, producers use transitional yields (T-yields) equal to a percentage of the historical county average to define policy guarantees. T-yields used for land coming out of CRP could be adjusted further to reflect local productivity expectations, as detailed in the expiring CRP contract.Footnote 37
I find that the impact of crop insurance on CRP varies by U.S. farm production region (see Table 3). As such, the consequences of CRP crowd-out will be regionally heterogeneous. For example, the Northern Great Plains contains much of the Prairie Pothole Region, an area where CRP contributes greatly to waterfowl habitat. Nielson et al. (Reference Nielson, McDonald, Sullivan, Burgess, Johnson, Johnson, Bucholtz, Hyberg and Howlin2008) estimate that a mere four percent increase in CRP acreage leads to a 22 percent rise in pheasant counts, suggesting that even small changes in CRP due to crop insurance can have large impacts on wildlife. Financial consequences may also follow given the economic importance of recreational bird hunting in the Prairie Pothole Region. Hunting on CRP land contributes $99 million to the economies of North and South Dakota annually. A 50 percent reduction in CRP enrollment in the Dakotas would cut the economic contribution of hunting by an estimated $39 million (Loomis, Haefele, and Hill Reference Loomis, Haefele and Hill2015). However, increased economic activity resulting from greater crop production would likely offset some losses in hunting revenue (Bangsund, Leistritz, and Hodur Reference Bangsund, Leistritz and Hodur2002).
Encroachment of insured land into CRP is most pronounced in the Northern Plains, Great Lakes states, and the Corn Belt, with more modest crowding out detected in Appalachia and the Southeast. Two forces may be driving the regional differences in effect sizes. First, aggregation bias could attenuate effects in regions where CRP eligibility is exogenously low. In addition to government policy, regional heterogeneity in land type and quality determines the amount of land eligible for retirement into CRP. Where eligibility is low, such as in Pacific and Northeastern states, a limited subset of producers is eligible for and participates in CRP. The negative effect of insurance on CRP will be present only among this limited subset of participants. The overall effect will be biased toward zero, however, as it is averaged over all insured producers in the county, many of whom have no acreage in CRP to begin with. A producer or farm-level analysis that controls for the limited dependent variable nature of CRP enrollment could improve regional precision in these estimates.Footnote 38 I consider this a direction for future work.
The second factor is land-use heterogeneity. Because the program specifically targets marginal cropland, expansion of crop production in regions with multiple competing land uses may occur at the expense of practices other than conservation (e.g., grassland pasture). We would not expect to find large effects in livestock grazing regions such as the Mountain West or Southern Plains. Conversely, we should expect insurance to impact CRP in regions where land retirement presents an immediate trade-off with crop production. High soil productivity, favorable climate, and topography make crop production highly profitable in the Northern Plains, the Great Lakes states, and the Corn Belt. As a result, cropland is the dominant land use in these regions (Bigelow and Borchers 2017).Footnote 39
Conclusion
Much of the literature on federal crop insurance shows that greater participation leads to small positive effects on acreage planted to insured crops. Environmental consequences could follow if land brought under cultivation is environmentally sensitive. Crop-insurance subsidies reduce the cost of insurance to producers, thereby increasing the expected returns from insurance and encouraging production on marginal farmland. While many papers address the environmental effects of crop insurance, less attention has been paid to the relationship between federally subsidized crop insurance and the Conservation Reserve Program (CRP).
As America's largest and most successful land retirement program, CRP prevents soil erosion and chemical runoff, enhances wildlife habitat, and contributes recreational amenities enjoyed by the public. Government policies may come into conflict, however, if subsidies for crop insurance deter enrollment in conservation programs. I directly estimate this crowding out of CRP by crop insurance using a comprehensive panel dataset covering over 2,700 counties and spanning 25 years.
To contend with the inherent endogeneity between crop insurance and land-retirement decisions, I exploit four major changes in government policy toward crop insurance during the 1990s and 2000s and apply a Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS) approach. Results indicate that a 1,000-acre increase in crop-insurance participation due to government policy crowds out about three acres from CRP on average. This translates to a −0.03 percent decrease in CRP for every one percent increase in insured acres (evaluated at the median).
Estimated effects are generally robust to various specifications and time periods but vary substantially by region. Heterogeneity in land quality and use determines regional effects. High field crop production areas of the Northern Great Plains, Great Lakes states, and the Corn Belt are susceptible to the largest crowding-out effects. Combining the instrumental variables technique used in this study with a farm-level model that corrects for the limited dependent variable nature of CRP enrollment may improve estimate precision. Such an approach would correct for any aggregation-bias attenuating effects in areas with low CRP eligibility.
While the environmental consequences of converting land from CRP to insured crop production may be large at a local level (enrolling land in CRP reduces soil runoff by 99 percent), the overall environmental effects appear small. I estimate that a one-percent increase in crop-insurance acreage nationwide would reduce the benefits generated by CRP by a mere 0.03 percent annually. Regional heterogeneity in effect sizes implies policy interventions are best designed at the state or local level.
Supplementary material
The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/age.2019.9