Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T19:09:24.840Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal stopping with random intervention times

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 February 2016

Paul Dupuis*
Affiliation:
Brown University
Hui Wang*
Affiliation:
Brown University
*
Postal address: Division of Applied Mathematics, Brown University, Box F, Providence, RI 02912, USA.
Postal address: Division of Applied Mathematics, Brown University, Box F, Providence, RI 02912, USA.

Abstract

We consider a class of optimal stopping problems where the ability to stop depends on an exogenous Poisson signal process - we can only stop at the Poisson jump times. Even though the time variable in these problems has a discrete aspect, a variational inequality can be obtained by considering an underlying continuous-time structure. Depending on whether stopping is allowed at t = 0, the value function exhibits different properties across the optimal exercise boundary. Indeed, the value function is only 𝒞0 across the optimal boundary when stopping is allowed at t = 0 and 𝒞2 otherwise, both contradicting the usual 𝒞1 smoothness that is necessary and sufficient for the application of the principle of smooth fit. Also discussed is an equivalent stochastic control formulation for these stopping problems. Finally, we derive the asymptotic behaviour of the value functions and optimal exercise boundaries as the intensity of the Poisson process goes to infinity or, roughly speaking, as the problems converge to the classical continuous-time optimal stopping problems.

Type
General Applied Probability
Copyright
Copyright © Applied Probability Trust 2002 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Research supported in part by the National Science Foundation (NSF-DMS-0072004) and the Army Research Office (ARO-DAAD19-99-1-0223).

References

Bather, J. A. and Chernoff, H. (1966). Sequential decisions in the control of a spaceship. In Proc. 5th Berkeley Symp. Math. Statist. Prob., Vol. III, University of California Press, Berkeley, pp. 181207.Google Scholar
Bensoussan, A. (1984). On the theory of option pricing. Acta Appl. Math. 2, 139158.Google Scholar
Brémaud, P., (1981). Point Processes and Queues: Martingale Dynamics. Springer, New York.Google Scholar
Brennan, M. J. and Schwartz, E. S. (1985). Evaluating natural resource investments. J. Business 58, 135157.Google Scholar
Broadie, M. and Glasserman, P. (1997). Pricing American-style securities using simulation. J. Econom. Dynam. Control 21, 13231352.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. K. and Pindyck, R. S. (1994). Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jacka, S. D. (1991). Optimal stopping and the American put. Math. Finance 1, 114.Google Scholar
Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S. E. (1991). Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus. Springer, New York.Google Scholar
McDonald, R. and Siegel, D. (1986). The value of waiting to invest. Quart. J. Econom. 101, 707728.Google Scholar
Merton, R. C. (1990). Continuous-Time Finance. Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Myneni, R. (1992). The pricing of the American option. Ann. Appl. Prob. 2, 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogers, L. C. G. (2000). A simple model of liquidity effects. Submitted.Google Scholar
Wang, H. (2001). Some control problems with random intervention times. Adv. Appl. Prob. 33, 404422.Google Scholar