Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-8bljj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-05T19:39:17.920Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Public Debt as a Form of Public Finance

Overcoming a Category Mistake and its Vices

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2019

Richard E. Wagner
Affiliation:
George Mason University, Virginia

Summary

Economists commit a category mistake when they treat democratic governments as indebted. Monarchs can be indebted, as can individuals. In contrast, democracies can't truly be indebted. They are financial intermediaries that form a bridge between what are often willing borrowers and forced lenders. The language of public debt is an ideological language that promotes politically expressed desires and is not a scientific language that clarifies the practice of public finance. Economists have gone astray by assuming that a government is just another person whose impulses toward prudent action will restrict recourse to public debt and induce rational political action.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781108696050
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 30 May 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alexander, J. C. (2006). The Civil Sphere. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Backhaus, J. G. and Wagner, R. E. (1987). The Cameralists: A public choice perspective. Public Choice 53: 320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhause, R. E. and Medema, S. G. (2012). Economists and the analysis of government failure: fallacies in the interpretations of Cambridge welfare economics. Cambridge Journal of Economics 36: 981–94.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. (1974). Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy 82: 10951118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, D. (1958). The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Blaug, M. (1996). Economic Theory in Retrospect, 5th ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. J. (2001). Calculation and Coordination. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. J. (2007). Liberty vs. power in economic policy in the 20th and 21st centuries. Journal of Private Enterprise 22: 736.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. J. (2018). F. A. Hayek: Economics, Political Economy, and Social Philosophy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, K. E. (1956). The Image: Knowledge in Life and Society. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, G. and Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brubaker, E. R. (1997). The tragedy of the public budgetary commons. The Independent Review 1: 353–70.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of public finance: a suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy 57: 496505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1958). Public Principles of Public Debt. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1960). The Italian tradition in fiscal theory. In Buchanan, J. M., ed., Fiscal Theory and Political Economy. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, pp. 2474.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1967). Public Finance in Democratic Process. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1968). The Demand and Supply of Public Goods. Chicago: Rand McNally.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1969). Cost and Choice. Chicago: Markham.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. (1962). The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Wagner, R. E. (1977). Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. M., et al. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulow, J. and Rogoff, K. (1988). Sovereign debt: is to forgive to forget? American Economic Review 79: 4350.Google Scholar
Bulow, J. and Rogoff, K. (1989). A constant recontracting model of sovereign debt. Journal of Political Economy 97: 155–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, G. (1988). Servicing public debt: the role of expectations. American Economic Review 78: 647–61.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. (2007). The Myth of the Rational Voter. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting Parliament: Constitutional Reform, Liberalism, and the Rise of Western Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Coyne, C. and Hall, A. (2018). Tyranny Comes Home: The Domestic Fate of U.S. Militarism. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cruces, J. and Trebesch, C. (2013). Sovereign defaults: the price of haircuts. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5: 85117.Google Scholar
De Jouvenel, B. (1993 [1948]). On Power: The Natural History of its Growth. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
De Jouvenel, B. (1961). The chairman’s problem. American Political Science Review 55: 368–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Viti de Marco, A. (1888). Il carattere teorico dell’economia finanziaria. Rome: Pasqualucci.Google Scholar
De Viti de Marco, A. (1930). Un trentennio di lotte politiche. Roma: Collezione Meridionale Editrice.Google Scholar
De Viti de Marco, A. (1936). First Principles of Public Finance. London: Jonathan Cape.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. (1897). The pure theory of taxation. Economic Journal 7: 100–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elias, N. (1982 [1939a]). The Civilizing Process. New York: Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
Elias, N. (1991 [1939b]). The Society of Individuals. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Emmett, R. N. (2006). De gustibus est disputandum: Frank H. Knight’s response to George Stigler and Gary Becker’s “De gustibus non est disputandum.” Journal of Economic Methodology 13: 97111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, R. A. 1995. Simple Rules for a Complex World. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eucken, W. (1952). Grundsätze der Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.Google Scholar
Eusepi, G. and Wagner, R. E. (2013). Tax prices in a democratic polity: The continuing relevance of Antonio de Viti de Marco. History of Political Economy 45: 99121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eusepi, G. and Wagner, R. E. (2017). Public Debt: An Illusion of Democratic Political Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fried, C. (1981). Contract as Promise: A Theory of Contractual Obligation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Garrison, R. (2001). Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of Capital Structure. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. 2008. Rationality for Mortals. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldscheid, R. 1917. Staatssozialismus oder Staatskapitalismus. Vienna: Brüder Suschitzky.Google Scholar
Greve, M. (2012). The Upside-Down Constitution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, H. and Van Huyck, J. (1988). Sovereign debt as a contingent claim: excusable default, repudiation, and reputation. American Economic Review 78: 1088–97.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. (1951). The Life of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1932). Monetary Policy and the Trade Cycle. London: Jonathan Capel.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1935). Prices and Production, 2nd ed. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1937). Economics and knowledge. Economica 4: 3354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35: 519–30.Google Scholar
Hickel, R., ed. 1976. Die Finanzkrise der Steuerstaats. Frankfurt: Suhrkamp.Google Scholar
Higgs, R. (1997). Regime uncertainty: why the Great Depression lasted so long and why prosperity resumed after the war. The Independent Review 1: 561–90.Google Scholar
Holcombe, R. G. (2002). From Liberty to Democracy: The Transformation of American Government. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, J. R. T. (1977). The Governmental Habit. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Jacobs, J. (1992). Systems of Survival. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Justi, J. H. G. (1771 [1969]). Natur und Wesen der Staaten. Darmstadt: Scientia Verlag Aalen.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Koppl, R. (2002). Big Players and the Economic Theory of Expectations. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koppl, R. (2018). Expert Failure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lachmann, L. (1977). Capital, Expectations, and the Market Process. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel.Google Scholar
Levine, M. E. and Plott, C. R. 1977. Agenda influence and its implications. Virginia Law Review 63: 561604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, P. A. and Wagner, R. E. (2017). New Austrian macro theory: a call for inquiry. Review of Austrian Economics 30: 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindahl, E. (1958 [1919]). Just taxation: a positive solution. In Musgrave, R. A. and Peacock, A. T., eds., Classics in the Theory of Public Finance. London: Macmillan, pp. 168–76.Google Scholar
Lippmann, W. (1922). Public Opinion. New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Lippmann, W. (1937). The Good Society. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Lovejoy., A. O. 1936. The Great Chain of Being. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Machlup, F. 1935. The consumption of capital in Austria. Review of Economics and Statistics 17: 1319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maine, H. (1861). Ancient Law. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Martinez-Vasquez, J. and Winer, S. L., eds. (2014). Coercion and Social Welfare in Public Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
May, J. D. (1965). Democracy, organization, and Michels. American Political Science Review 59: 417–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLure, M. (2007). The Paretian School and Italian Fiscal Sociology. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Medema, S. G. (1996). Of Pangloss, Pigouvians, and pragmatism: Ronald Coase and social cost analysis. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 18: 96114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michels, R. (1915 [1962]). Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the Oligarchic Tendencies of Modern Democracy. New York: Collier Books.Google Scholar
Miller, J. C. III. 1994. Fix the US Budget! Urgings of an Abominable No-Man. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.Google Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. 1994. Optimal taxation and government finance. In Quigley, J. M. and Smolensky, E., eds. Modern Public Finance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 213–31.Google Scholar
Mosca, M. 2016. Antonio de Viti de Marco: a story worth remembering. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. (1939). The voluntary exchange theory of public economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 53: 213–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odom, J. (2019). Public Debt and the Common Good: Philosophical and Institutional Implications of Fiscal Imbalance. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
O’Driscoll, G. (1977). Economics as a Coordination Problem. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1987). The Political Theory of a Compound Republic, 2nd ed. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1997). The Meaning of Democracy and the Vulnerability of Democracies: A Response to Tocqueville’s Challenge. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pantaleoni, M. (1911). Considerazioni dulle proprieta di un sistema di prezzi politici. Giornale degli Economisti 42: 929, 114–33.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1915 [1935]). The Mind and Society. New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Patrick, M. and Wagner, R. E. (2015). From mixed economy to entangled political economy: a Paretian social-theoretic orientation. Public Choice 164: 10316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1920). The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1928). A Study in Public Finance. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Plott, C. R. and Levine, M. E. (1978). A model of agenda influence on committee decisions. American Economic Review 68: 146–60.Google Scholar
Podemska-Mikluch, M. and Wagner, R. E. 2013. Dyads, triads, and the theory of exchange. Review of Austrian Economics 26: 171–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polanyi, M. 1958. Personal Knowledge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Primo, D. 2007. Rules and Restraint: Government Spending and the Design of Institutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Puviani, A. (1903). Teoria della illusion finanziaria. Palermo: Sandron.Google Scholar
Puviani, A. (1960). Die Illusionen in der öffentlichen Finanzwirtschaft. Translated by Hartmann, M. and Rexhausen, F.. Berlin: Duncker and Humblot.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. (1927). A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal 37: 4761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raudla, R. (2010). Governing the budgetary commons: what can we learn from Elinor Ostrom? European Journal of Law and Economics 30: 201–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Resnick, M. (1994). Turtles, Termites, and Traffic Jams. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1962). The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agenda, and the status quo. Public Choice 33: 2743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, K. 1996. Keynes’s General Theory: a look at the criss-cross of reviews. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics 18: 533–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salsman, R. M. (2017). The Political Economy of Public Debt. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics 36: 387–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1955). Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics 37: 350–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmölders, G. (1959). Fiscal psychology: a new branch of public finance. National Tax Journal 12: 340–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmölders, G. (1960). Das Irrationale in der öffentlichen Finanzwirtschaft: Probleme der Finanzpsychologie. Hamburg: Rowahlt.Google Scholar
Schmookler, A. B. (1984). The Parable of the Tribes: The Problem of Power in Social Evolution. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Schoeck, H. (1969). Envy: A Theory of Social Behavior. New York: Van Nostrand.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1954 [1918]). The crisis of the tax state. International Economic Papers 4: 538. Reprinted in Hickel (1976).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1944). Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Seater, J. J. (1993). Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Economic Literature 31: 142–90.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1968). Uncertainty in Economics and Other Essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1972). Epistemics and Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (1981). Structure induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice 37: 503–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. (1976 [1759]). The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1937 [1776]). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Sterpan, I. and Wagner, R. E. (2017). The autonomy of the political in political economy. Advances in Austrian Economics 22: 133–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. J. and Becker, G. S. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. American Economic Review 67: 7690.Google Scholar
Stringham, E. (2015). Private Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Telser, L. (1994). The usefulness of core theory in economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 151–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomz, M. (2007). Reputation and International Cooperation: Sovereign Debt across Three Centuries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tribe, K. (1984). Cameralism and the science of government. Journal of Modern History 56: 263–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veetil, V. and Wagner, R. E. (2018). Nominal GDP stabilization: chasing a mirage. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 67: 227–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (1986). Liability rules, fiscal institutions, and the debt. In Rowley, C. K. and Tollison, R. D., eds. Deficits. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 374–90.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (1988). The Calculus of Consent: a Wicksellian retrospective. Public Choice 56: 153–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (1992). Grazing the federal budgetary commons: the rational politics of budgetary irresponsibility. Journal of Law and Politics 9: 105–19.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2007). Fiscal Sociology and the Theory of Public Finance. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2012a). The Cameralists: fertile sources for a new science of public finance. In Backhaus, J. G., ed., Handbook of the History of Economic Thought. New York: Springer, pp. 123–35.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2012b). A macro economy as an ecology of plans. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 82: 433–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2012c). Viennese kaleidics: why it’s liberty more than policy that calms turbulence. Review of Austrian Economics 25: 283–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2012d). Deficits, Debt, and Democracy: Wrestling with Tragedy on the Fiscal Commons. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2016). Politics as a Peculiar Business: Insights from a Theory of Entangled Political Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2017a). James M. Buchanan and Liberal Political Economy: A Rational Reconstruction. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2017b). Public Debt and the Corruption of Contract; published simultaneously as Il debito pubblico e la corruzione delle promesee. Milan: Bruno Leoni Institute.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. and Yazigi, D. (2014). Form vs. substance in selection through competition: elections, markets, and political economy. Public Choice 159: 503–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weaver, C. L. 1982. The Crisis in Social Security: Economic and Political Origins. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1896). Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen. Jena: Gustav Fischer.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1958). A new principle of just taxation. In Musgrave, R. A. and Peacock, A. T., eds., Classics in the Theory of Public Finance. London: Macmillan, pp. 72118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wieser, F. (1926). Das Gesetz der Macht. Vienna: Julius Springer.Google Scholar
Witt, U. (1997). The Hayekian puzzle: spontaneous order and the business cycle. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 44: 4458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Public Debt as a Form of Public Finance
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Public Debt as a Form of Public Finance
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Public Debt as a Form of Public Finance
Available formats
×