Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T22:50:54.641Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part I - Plurality of Welfare in the Making of Welfare Economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 March 2021

Roger E. Backhouse
Affiliation:
University of Birmingham and Erasmus University Rotterdam
Antoinette Baujard
Affiliation:
Université de Lyon et Université Jean Monnet à Saint-Étienne
Tamotsu Nishizawa
Affiliation:
Teikyo University Japan
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Welfare Theory, Public Action, and Ethical Values
Revisiting the History of Welfare Economics
, pp. 19 - 156
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References

Bate, W. J. 1946, From Classic to Romantic: Premises of Taste in Eighteenth-Century England, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Berlin, I. 1999, The Roots of Romanticism, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Carlyle, T. 1987 [1833], Sartor Resartus, ed. McSweeney, K. and Sabor, P., Oxford, Oxford University Press (Oxford World’s Classics).Google Scholar
Cook, E. T. and Wedderburn, A. (eds.) 1903–12, The Works of John Ruskin, 39 vols., London, George Allen.Google Scholar
Furst, L. R. 1979, Romanticism in Perspective: A Comparative Study of Aspects of the Romantic Movements in England, France and Germany, 2nd ed., London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Le Quesne, A. L. 1998, ‘Thomas Carlyle’, in Craig, E. (ed.), Routledge Encyclopedia of Philosophy, London, Routledge, Vol. 2, 205–6.Google Scholar
Lovejoy, A. O. 1941, ‘The Meaning of Romanticism for the Historian of Ideas’, Journal of the History of Ideas, 2, 3, 257–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peckham, M. 1974 [1951], ‘Toward a Theory of Romanticism’, in Gleckner, R. F. and Enscoe, G. E. (eds.), Romanticism: Points of View, 2nd ed., Detroit, Wayne State University Press, 231–57.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, J. D. 1986, The Darkening Glass: A Portrait of Ruskin’s Genius, New York, Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1843, 1846, 1856, 1856, 1860, Modern Painters, 5 vols. (Cook and Wedderburn, vols. 3–7).Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1849, The Seven Lamps of Architecture (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 8).Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1851, Pre-Raphaelitism (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 12), 338–93.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1851, 1853, 1853, The Stones of Venice, 3 vols. (Cook and Wedderburn, vols. 9–11).Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1853a, ‘Architecture’, in Lectures on Architecture and Painting (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 12), 5380.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1853b, ‘Pre-Raphaelitism’, in Lectures on Architecture and Painting (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 12), 134–64.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1854, Lectures on Architecture and Painting (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 12), 5164.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1857, The Political Economy of Art [included as A Joy for Ever (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16)], 5169.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1858a, ‘Education in Art’ [supplementary additional papers to A Joy for Ever (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16)], 143–52.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1858b, ‘Inaugural Address at the Cambridge School of Art’ (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16), 175201.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1858c, ‘The Deteriorative Power of Conventional Art over Nations’, in The Two Paths (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16), 259–92.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1859a, The Two Paths (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16), 245424.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1859b, ‘The Unity of Art’, in The Two Paths (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16), 293318.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1859c, ‘Modern Manufacture and Design’, in The Two Paths (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 16), 319–45.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1862, Unto This Last (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 17), 5114.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1865, Sesame and Lilies (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 18), 5187.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1866, The Ethics of the Dust: Ten Lectures to Little Housewives on the Elements of Crystallisation (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 18), 193368.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1867, Time and Tide (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 17), 299482.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1870, ‘Inaugural’, in Lectures on Art (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 20), 1744.Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1871–3, 1874–6, 1877–84, Fors Clavigera, 3 vols. (Cook and Wedderburn, vols. 27–9).Google Scholar
Ruskin, J. 1872, Munera Pulveris (Cook and Wedderburn, vol. 17), 119298.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1985, Commodities and Capabilities, Amsterdam, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 2005, Economy and Morality: The Philosophy of the Welfare State, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 2010, ‘The Oxford Approach to the Philosophical Foundations of the Welfare State’, in Backhouse, R. E. and Nishizawa, T. (eds.), No Wealth but Life: Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in Britain, 1880–1947, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 91113.Google Scholar
Smith, L. P. 1925, ‘Four Romantic Words’, in Words and Idioms: Studies in the English Language, London, Constable, 66134.Google Scholar
Wellek, R. 1974 [1949], ‘The Concept of Romanticism in Literary History’, in Gleckner, R. F. and Enscoe, G. E. (eds.), Romanticism: Points of View, 2nd ed., Detroit, Wayne State University Press, 181205.Google Scholar
Wordsworth, W. and Coleridge, S. T. 2006 [1798], Lyrical Ballads, ed. De Piro, C., Oxford, Oxford University Press (Oxford Student Texts).Google Scholar

References

Allett, John. 1981. New Liberalism: The Political Economy of J. A. Hobson. Toronto: Toronto University Press.Google Scholar
Allett, John. 1990. ‘The Conservative Aspect of Hobson’s New Liberalism’, in Freeden, Michael, ed. Reappraising J. A. Hobson: Humanism and Welfare. London: Unwin Hyman, 7499.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2002. The Penguin History of Economics. London: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2010. ‘J. A. Hobson as a Welfare Economist’, in Backhouse, Roger E. and Nishizawa, Tamotsu, eds. No Wealth but Life: Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in Britain, 1880–1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 114–35.Google Scholar
Berlin, Isaiah. 1969; 1958. ‘Two Concepts of Liberty’, in Four Essays on Liberty. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 118–72.Google Scholar
Cain, Peter J. 1985. ‘Hobson, Wilshire and the Capitalist Theory of Capitalist Imperialism’, History of Political Economy 17, 455–60.Google Scholar
Cain, Peter. 2002. Hobson and Imperialism: Radicalism, New Liberalism and Finance, 1887–1938. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cockram, Gill G. 2007. Ruskin and Social Reform: Ethics and Economics in the Victorian Age. London: I. B. Taurus.Google Scholar
Collini, Stefan. 1979. Liberalism and Sociology: L. T. Hobhouse and Political Argument in England, 1880–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Collini, Stefan. 1991. Public Moralists: Political Thought and Intellectual Life in Modern Britain, 1850–1930. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eagles, Stuart. 2011. After Ruskin: The Social and Political Legacies of a Victorian Prophet, 1870–1920. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Freeden, Michael. 1976. ‘Biological and Evolutionary Roots of the New Liberalism in England’. Political Theory 4, 471–90.Google Scholar
Freeden, Michael, ed. 1988. J. A. Hobson: A Reader. London: Unwin Hyman.Google Scholar
Hewison, Robert. 2018. Ruskin and His Contemporaries. London: Pallas Athene.Google Scholar
Hobhouse, L. T. 1964; 1911. Liberalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1891. ‘The Law of the Three Rents’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 5, 263–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1894. ‘The Subjective and the Objective View of Distribution’, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 4, 378403.Google Scholar
Hobson., J. A. 1895. ‘Mr. Kidd’s “Social Evolution”’, American Journal of Sociology 2, 299312.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1902; 1901. The Social Problem: Life and Work. London: James Nisbet.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1904; 1898. John Ruskin: Social Reformer. London: James Nisbet.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1910a; 1909. The Industrial System: An Inquiry into Earned and Unearned Income. London: Longman, Green.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1910b. The Modern Outlook: Studies of English and American Tendencies. London: Herbert and Daniel.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1911. The Science of Wealth. London: Williams and Norgate.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1914. Work and Wealth: A Human Valuation. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1918. Richard Cobden: The International Man. New York: Henry Holt.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1930. Wealth and Life: A Human Valuation. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1976; 1938. Confessions of an Economic Heretic. Brighton: Harvester Press.Google Scholar
Macpherson, C. B. 1962. The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Matthew, H. G. C. 1990. ‘Hobson, Ruskin and Cobden’, in Freeden, Michael, ed. Reappraising J. A. Hobson: Humanism and Welfare. London: Unwin Hyman, 1130.Google Scholar
O’Gorman, Francis. 2001. Late Ruskin: New Contexts. Aldershot: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Paine, Thomas. 1987. The Thomas Paine Reader. Foot, M. and Kramnick, I., eds. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Philp, Mark. 1989. Paine. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rainbow Circle. 1989. Minutes of the Rainbow Circle, 1894–1924. Freeden, M., ed. London: Royal Historical Society.Google Scholar
Ruskin, John. 1903–12. The Works of John Ruskin. Cook, E. T. and Wedderburn, A., eds. 39 vols. London: George Allen.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Yiuchi. 2010. ‘The Oxford Approach to the Philosophical Foundations of the Welfare State’, in Backhouse, Roger E. and Nishizawa, Tamotsu, eds. No Wealth but Life: Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in Britain, 1880–1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 91113.Google Scholar
Spencer, Herbert. 1972. On Social Evolution. Peel, J. Y. D., ed. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, Michael W. 1992. Men versus the State: Herbert Spencer and Late Victorian Individualism. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Thompson, Noel. 1994. ‘Hobson and the Fabians: Two Roads to Socialism in the 1920s’, History of Political Economy 26, 203–20.Google Scholar
Thompson, Noel. 1998. The Real Rights of Man: Political Economies for the Working Class, 1775–1850. London: Pluto Press.Google Scholar
Winch, Donald. 2009. Wealth and Life: Essays on the Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1848–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Xenophon. 1994. Oeconomicus: A Social and Historical Commentary. Pomeroy, Sarah, ed. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar

References

Ashley, W. J. 1891. ‘The Rehabilitation of Ricardo’, Economic Journal, 13, 474–89.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. E. 2006. ‘Sidgwick, Marshall and the Cambridge School of Economics’, History of Political Economy, 381, 1544.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. E. and Nishizawa, T., eds. 2010. No Wealth but Life: Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in Britain, 1880–1945, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bateman, B. W. 2006. ‘Wants and Activities’, in Raffaelli, T., Becattini, G., Dardi, M., eds., The Elgar Companion of Alfred Marshall, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 288–92.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. and Nishizawa, T. 2011. ‘Marshall’s Ideas on Progress: Roots and Diffusion’, in Kurz, H., Nishizawa, T., Tribe, K., eds., The Dissemination of Economic Ideas, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 125–57.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. and Nishizawa, T. 2014. ‘Marshall’s “Welfare Economics” and “Welfare”: A Reappraisal Based on His Unpublished Manuscript on Progress’, History of Economic Ideas, XXII1, 5167.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. and Nishizawa, T. 2016. ‘Progress beyond Growth: Some Insights from Marshall’s Final Book’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 231, 226–43.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. and Nishizawa, T. 2020a. Alfred Marshall’s Last Challenge: His Book on Economic Progress, Newcastle: Cambridge Scholars Publishing.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. and Nishizawa, T. 2020b. ‘Economic and Moral Wellbeing and Efficiency: Some Marshallian Insights from His Book on “Progress”’, Dardi, M., Medema, S., Caldari, K., eds., Marshall and the Marshallian Heritage: Essays in Honour of Tiziano Raffaelli, London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Collini, S., Winch, D., Burrow, J. 1983. That Noble Science of Politics: A Study in Nineteenth-Century Intellectual History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cook, S. J. 2009. The Intellectual Foundations of Alfred Marshall’s Economic Science, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dardi, M. 2010. ‘Marshall on Welfare, or: the “Utilitarian” Meets the “Evolver”’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 173, 405–37.Google Scholar
Dardi, M. 2011. ‘Ideal Social Orders’, in Raffaelli, T., Nishizawa, T., Cook, S., eds., Marshall, Marshallians and Industrial Economics, London: Routledge, 100–32.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, P. D., ed. 1998. Alfred Marshall: Critical Responses, Vol. II, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, P. D. 2005. ‘A Book That Never Was: Marshall’s Final Volume on Progress’, History of Economic Review, 42, 2944.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, P. D. 2010. ‘Marshall on Welfare Economics and the Welfare State’, in Backhouse, and Nishizawa, , eds., 2010, 2541.Google Scholar
Guillebaud, C. M. 1971. ‘Some Personal Reminiscences of Alfred Marshall’, reprinted in Alfred Marshall Critical Assessments, Vol. 1, London: Croom Helm, 1982, 91–7.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1959. ‘Preface – and a Manifesto’, Essays in World Economics, Oxford: Clarendon Press, vxv.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1914. Work and Wealth: A Human Valuation, with a new introduction by Cain, P., London: Routledge/Thoemmes Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. A. 1929. Wealth and Life: A Study in Values, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. 1964. ‘Positive’ Economics and Policy Objectives, London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Jones, G. S. 1971. Outcast London: A Study in Relationship between Classes in Victorian Society, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1924. ‘Alfred Marshall’, in the Collected Writings, X: Essays in Biography, London: Macmillan, 1972.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1930. ‘Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren’, in the Collected Writings, IX: Essays in Persuasion, London: Macmillan, 1972.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1873a. ‘The Future of the Working Classes’, in Pigou, , ed., 1925.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1873b. ‘Lectures to Women’, in Raffaelli, T., Biagini, E., Tullberg, R. M., eds., Alfred Marshall’s Lectures to Women, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1995, 85155.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1883. ‘Three Lectures on Progress and Poverty’, Collected Essays, Vol. 1, Bristol: Overstone Press, 1997.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1885a. ‘How Far Do Remediable Causes Influence Prejudicially (a) the Continuity of Employment, (b) the Rates of Wages?’ in Industrial Remuneration Conference (1885), reprinted in Alfred Marshall: Critical Responses, ed. Groenewegen, P., Vol. 1, London: Routledge, 1998, 5966.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1885b. The Present Position of Economics, London: Macmillan, in Pigou, , ed., 1925.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1889. ‘Co-operation’, in Pigou, , ed., 1925.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1897. ‘The Old Generation of Economists and the New’, in Pigou, , ed., 1925.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1898. Principles of Economics, 4th ed., London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1907. ‘Social Possibilities of Economic Chivalry’, in Pigou, , ed., 1925.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1917. ‘National Taxation after the War’, in Dawson, W. H., ed., After-War Problems, New York: Macmillan, 313–45.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1919. Industry and Trade: A Study of Industrial Technique and Business Organization; and of Their Influences on the Conditions of Various Classes and Nations, London: Macmillan, 4th ed., 1923.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1923. Money, Credit & Commerce, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1961a. Principles of Economics (1890); 9th (variorum) ed. with annotations, by Guillebaud, C. W., Vol. I Text, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1961b. Principles of Economics (1890); 9th (variorum) ed. with annotations, by Guillebaud, C. W., Vol. II Notes, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and Marshall, M. 1879. The Economics of Industry, with a new introduction by O’Brien, D., Bristol: Thoemmes Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Medema, S. 2006. ‘Welfare Economics: Marshallian Welfare Economics and the Economic Welfare of Marshall’, in Raffaelli, T., Becattini, G., Dardi, M., eds., The Elgar Companion of Alfred Marshall, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 634–47.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, M. C. and Sen, A., eds. 1993. The Quality of Life, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Parsons, T. 1932. ‘Wants and Activities in Marshall’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 461, 101–40.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare, London: Macmillan; 4th ed., 1932.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C., ed. 1925. Memorials of Alfred Marshall, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Raffaelli, T. 2003. Marshall’s Evolutionary Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Raffaelli, T., Becattini, G., Dardi, M., eds. 2006. The Elgar Companion of Alfred Marshall, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Raffaelli, T., Biagini, E., Tullberg, R. M., eds. 1995. Alfred Marshall’s Lectures to Women: Some Economic Questions Directly Connected to the Welfare of the Labourer, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. 1951. Ten Great Economists from Marx to Keynes, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis, London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 2005. Economy and Morality: The Philosophy of the Welfare State, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 2012. Economic Thought of Romanticism: Arts, Ethics, and History (in Japanese), Tokyo: Tokyo University Press.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 2018. ‘Philosophy, Arts, Economics of Keynes – in the Light of Enlightenment versus Romanticism’, in Nishizawa, T. and Hirai, T., eds., Cambridge, Pursuit of Wisdom: Economics, Philosophy, and Literature (in Japanese), Kyoto: Minerva-shobo, 261–80.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. and Nishizawa, T., eds. 2008. Marshall and Schumpeter on Evolution: Economic Sociology of Capitalist Development, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Suzumura, K. 2013. ‘Foundations of “Non-welfaristic” and “Non-consequential” Normative Economics: What Are the Connecting Links between Pigou, Hicks, and Sen’, in Nishizawa, T. and Komine, A., eds., Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in the Formative Age (in Japanese), Kyoto: Minerva-shobo, 339–64.Google Scholar
Whitaker, J. K., ed. 1975. The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall, 1867–1890, 2 vols., London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Whitaker, J. K., ed. 1996. The Correspondence of Alfred Marshall, Economist, 3 vols., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Winch, D. 2009. Wealth and Life: Essays on the Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1848–1914, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

References

Backhouse, R. E. and Nishizawa, T., eds. 2010. No Wealth but Life: Welfare Economics and the Welfare State in Britain, 1880–1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, T. 1990. G.E. Moore. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Collard, D. 1981. A. C. Pigou, 1877–1959, in O’Brien, D. P. and Presley, John R., eds., Pioneers of Modern Economics in Britain. London: Macmillan, 105–39.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1879. The Hedonical Calculus, Mind, 4 (15), 394408.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1881. Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. London: Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1913. Wealth and Welfare by A. C. Pigou, Economic Journal, 23 (89), 6270.Google Scholar
Gaertner, W. and Pattanaik, P. K.. 1988. An Interview with Amartya Sen, Social Choice and Welfare, 5, 6979.Google Scholar
Griffin, J. 1986. Well-Being. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hongo, R. 2007. The Philosophy and Economics of A. C. Pigou: In the Intellectual Milieu of Cambridge [in Japanese]. Nagoya: The University of Nagoya Press.Google Scholar
McLure, M. 2013. Assessments of A. C. Pigou’s Fellowship Theses, History of Political Economy, 45 (2), 255–85.Google Scholar
Moore, G. E. 1903. Principia Ethica. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
O’Donnell, M. G. 1979. Pigou: An Extension of Sidgwickian Thought, History of Political Economy, 11 (4), 588605.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1901a. Robert Browning as a Religious Teacher. London: C.J. Clay and Sons.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1901b. Some Aspects of the Problem of Charity, Masterman, C. F. G. et al., eds., The Heart of the Empire: Discussions of Problems of Modern City Life in England, with an Essay on Imperialism. London: T. Fisher Unwin, 236–61.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1903. Some Remarks on Utility, Economic Journal, 13 (49), 5868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1906. The Unity of Political and Economic Science, Economic Journal, 16 (63), 372–80.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1907 (1910). Memorandum on Some Economic Aspects and Effects of Poor Law Relief in Appendix Vol. 9. Minutes of Evidence, Royal Commission on the Poor Laws and Relief of Distress, Cd.5068. London: His Majesty’s Stationery Office and Wyman and Sons Ltd, 9811000.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1912. Wealth and Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1913. The Principle of the Minimum Wage, The Nineteenth Century, 73, 644–58.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1914. Some Aspects of the Housing Problems, in Rowntree, B. and Pigou, A. C., Lectures on Housing. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 3566.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1920, The Economics of Welfare, 1st ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1922. The Private Use of Money, The Contemporary Review, 121, 452–60.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1923. Essays in Applied Economics. London: P. S. King.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1924. The Economics of Welfare, 2nd ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1928. A Study in Public Finance, 1st ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1929a. The Economics of Welfare, 3rd ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1929b. A Study in Public Finance, 2nd ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1932. The Economics of Welfare, 4th ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1935. Economics in Practice. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1937. Socialism versus Capitalism. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1944. The Road to Serfdom by F. A. Hayek, Economic Journal, 54, 217–19.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1947. A Study in Public Finance, 3rd ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1951. Some Aspects of Welfare Economics, American Economic Review, 41 (3), 287302.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1952. Essays in Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1953. Alfred Marshall and Current Thought. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1955. Income Revisited: Being a Sequel to Income. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. 1997. On Economic Inequality, expanded ed., with a substantial annexe by Foster, J. E. and Sen, A. K.. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. and Williams, B., eds. 1982. Utilitarianism and Beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 1984. The Structure of the Value Idea [in Japanese]. Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Inc.Google Scholar
Shionoya, Y. 1993. A Non-utilitarian Interpretation of Pigou’s Welfare Economics, in Koslowski, P. and Shionoya, Y., eds., The Good and the Economical. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 724.Google Scholar
Singer, P. 2011. Practical Ethics, 3rd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sumner, L. W. 1996. Welfare, Happiness, and Ethics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Suzumura, K. 1999. Welfare Economics and the Welfare State, Review of Population and Social Policy, 8, 119–38.Google Scholar
Suzumura, K. 2000. Welfare Economics beyond Welfarist-Consequentialism, Japanese Economic Review, 51 (1), 132.Google Scholar
Suzumura, K. 2002. Introduction to Social Choice and Welfare, in Arrow, K. J., Sen, A. K., and Suzumura, K., eds., Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare, Vol. I. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 133.Google Scholar
Suzumura, K. 2007. On the Non-welfaristic and Non-consequential Foundations of Normative Economics – Or, What Is the Connecting Link between Pigou and Sen via Hicks? [in Japanese], Economic Review, 58 (2), 97109.Google Scholar
Suzumura, K. 2010. Shigeto Tsuru as the Practitioner of Welfare Economics [in Japanese], in Odaka, K. and Nishizawa, T., eds., The Retrospection of Shigeto Tsuru: Capitalism, Socialism, and Environment. Tokyo: Keiso Shobo, 99114.Google Scholar
Yamazaki, S. 2011. Pigou’s Ethical Thought and Welfare Economics: Well-Being, Justice, and Eugenics [in Japanese]. Kyoto: Showado.Google Scholar
Yamazaki, S. 2012. Need and Distribution in Pigou’s Economic Thinking. Paper presented at 12th Conference of International Society for Utilitarian Studies, New York, 9–11 August 2012.Google Scholar
Yamazaki, S. and Takami, N.. 2018. The Cambridge Welfare Economics, in Nishizawa, T. and Hirai, T., eds., Cambridge Pursuit of Wisdom: Economics, Philosophy, and Literature [in Japanese]. Kyoto: Minerva, 89132.Google Scholar

References

Arena, R., 2002. “Organisation and knowledge in Alfred Marshall’s economics,” in Arena, R. and Queré, M. (eds.), The economics of Alfred Marshall: Evolution and the organisation of industry, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 221239.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. and Hahn, F., 1971. General competitive analysis, North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Baumol, W., 1952. Welfare economics and the theory of the state, LSE, G. Bell and Sons, London.Google Scholar
Beraud, A., 2011. “Walras et l’économie publique,” Oeconomia History/Methodology/Philosophy, 1(3), September, 351392.Google Scholar
Bortkiewicz, L., 1889. Correspondence with Walras, in Walras, , 1965.Google Scholar
Breton, Y. and Lutfalla, M., 1991. L’économie politique en France au XIX ieme siècle, Economica, Paris.Google Scholar
Dockès, P., 1996. La société n’est pas un pique-nique – Léon Walras et l’économie sociale, Economica, Paris.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. 1889. Correspondence with Walras, in Walras, , 1965.Google Scholar
Guesnerie, R., 1995/1997. “La modélisation en économie théorique,” in Cartelier, J. (ed.), L’économie deviant-elle une science dure?, Economica, Paris, 1995, pp. 9298; English ed. and trans.: “Modelling and economic theory: Evolution and problems,” in d’Autume, A. and Cartelier, J. (eds.), Is Economics Becoming a Hard Science?, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 1997, pp. 8591.Google Scholar
Jaffé, W., 1977/1983. “The normative bias of the Walrasian model: Walras versus Gossen,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, no. 91, August 1977, in Walker, D. (ed.),William Jaffé’s Essays on Walras, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1983, pp. 371387.Google Scholar
Launhardt, W., 1885. Mathematical principles of economics, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 1993, English translation from the German first edition.Google Scholar
Mouchot, C., 1994. “L’impossible théorème de l’utilite maxima des capitaux neufs,” Economie et Sociétés, series Histoire de la pensée économique, no. 10–11.Google Scholar
Potier, J.-P., 2011. “Marché du travail et législation sociale dans la pensée de Léon Walras,” Oeconomia, no. 1–3, 437458.Google Scholar
Reyberol, A., 1999. La pensée économique de Walras, series “Théories Economiques,” Dunod, Paris.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P., 1947. Foundations of economic analysis, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Steiner, P., 1994. “Pareto contre Walras: le problème de l’économie sociale,” Economies et Sociétés – Cahiers de l’ISMEA, XXVIII, no. 10–11, 5373.Google Scholar
Van Daal, J. and Jolink, A., 1993. The equilibrium economics of Léon Walras, ch. 12, Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Walras, L., 1886/1996. Cours d’Economie Sociale, in Dockès, P., Goutte, P.-H., Hébert, C., Mouchot, C., Potier, J. P. and Servet, J.-M., Oeuvres Economiques Complètes, volume XII, Economica, Paris, 1996.Google Scholar
Walras, L., 1896/1990. Etudes d’Economie Sociale, in Dockès, P., Goutte, P. H., Hébert, C., Mouchot, C., Potier, J. P. and Servet, J. M., Oeuvres Economiques Complètes, volume IX, Economica, Paris, 1990.Google Scholar
Walras, L., 1900/1976. Eléments d’Economie Politique Pure ou Théorie de la Richesse Sociale, Librairie Générale de Droit et de Jurisprudence, Paris, 1952, first publication and 1976, new printing; Pichon, R. and Durand-Auzias, R. (eds.), Paris, 1900, final version revised by the author.Google Scholar
Walras, L., 1965. Correspondence of Leon Walras and related papers, volume II, edited by Jaffé, W., North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Walras, L. and Walras, A. L., 1870/1996, Oeuvres économiques complètes, Tome 12, (Cours d’économie sociale; Cours d’économie politique appliquée; Matériaux du cours d’économie politique pure), Economica, Paris.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K., 1899. “Leon Walras. Etudes d’économie sociale appliquée: théorie de la production de la richesse sociale,” Jahrbucher fur Nationalokonomie und Statistik, in Wicksell, K., Selected essays in economics, edited by Sandelin, B., Routledge, London, 1999.Google Scholar

References

Allais, Maurice. 1975. The General Theory of Surplus and Pareto’s Fundamental Contribution, Convegno Internazionale Vilfredo Pareto (Roma 25–27 ottobre 1973), Atti dei Convegni Lincie 9, Rome: Accademia Nazionale Dei Lincei, 109–63; Reprinted in J. C. Wood and M. McLure, eds., 1999. Vilfredo Pareto: Critical Assessments, London: Routledge, Vol. 1, 428–73.Google Scholar
Chipman, John S. 1976. The Paretian Heritage, Revue Européene des Sciences Sociales, no. 37, 65173; Reprinted in J. C. Wood and M. McLure, eds., 1999. Vilfredo Pareto: Critical Assessments, London: Routledge, Vol. 2, 157–257.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1939. Value and Capital, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1975. Pareto and the Economic Optimum, Convegno Internazionale Vilfredo Pareto (Rome 25–27 October 1973), Atti dei Convegni Lincie 9, Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, 1928; Reprinted in J. C. Wood and M. McLure, eds., 1999. Vilfredo Pareto: Critical Assessments, London: Routledge, Vol. 1, 417–27.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. and Allen, Roy G. D. 1934. A Reconsideration of the Theory of Value, Parts 1 and 2, Economica, 11, 5276 and 1–2, 196219.Google Scholar
McLure, Michael. 2000. The Pareto-Scorza Polemic on Collective Economic Welfare, Australian Economic Papers, 393, 345–69.Google Scholar
McLure, Michael. 2001. Pareto, Economics and Society, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
McLure, Michael and Montesano, Aldo. 2019. Thinking Outside the Box: Edgeworth, Pareto and the Early History of the Box Diagram, Economic Record, 95310, 301–11.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1894. Il Massimo di Utilità dato dalla Libera Concorenza, Giornale degli Economisti, 49, 4866; English translation in John Chipman, ed., 2008. The Maximum of Utility Given by Free Competition, Giornali degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 67–3, 387–403.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1896–7. Cours d’Économie Politique, Lausanne: Rouge; Italian translation, 1971. Corso di Economia Politica, Torino: Unione Tipographico-Editrice Torinese.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1900. Sunto di Alcuni Capitoli di un Nuovo Trattato di Economia Pura del Prof. Pareto, Giornali degli Economisti, 2–20, March and June, 216–35 and 511–49; English translation in John Chipman, ed., 2008. Summary of Some Chapters of a New Treatise on Pure Economics by Professor Pareto, Giornali degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 67–3, 453504.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1902. Di un Nuovo Errore nello Interpretare le Teorie dell’Economia Matematica, Giornale degli Economisti, 1215, 401–33; English translation in John Chipman, ed., 2008. On a New Error in the Interpretation of the Theories of Mathematical Economics, Giornali degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 67–3, 515–44.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1906. Manuale di Economia Politica, Milan: Società Editrice Libraria; Revised French translation, 1909. Manuel d’Économie Politique, Paris; English variorum translation in A. Montesano, A. Zanni, L. Bruni, J. S. Chipman and M. McLure, eds., 2014. Manual of Political Economy: A Critical and Variorum Edition, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1910. Le Azioni Non Logiche, Rivista Italiana di Sociologia, May–August, 305–64; Reprinted in Giovanni Busino, ed., 1980. Vilfredo Pareto Œuvres Complètes 22: Écrits Sociologiques Mineurs, Genéve: Librairie Droz, 345408.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1913. Il Massimo di Utilità per una Collettività in Sociologia, Giornale degli Economisti e Rivista di Statistica, 2346, 337–41; English translation reprinted in J. C. Wood and M. McLure, eds., 1999. Vilfredo Pareto: Critical Assessments, London: Routledge, Vol. 3, 307–10.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1916. Trattato di Sociologia Generale, Florence: Barbara; English translation, 1935. The Mind and Society, New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Suzumura, Kotaro. 2016. Pigou’s ‘Old’ Welfare Economics, Hicks’s Farewell to Welfarism, and Sen’s Non-consequentialist Economics of Well-Being and Freedom, International Workshop on Economic Thought of Cambridge, Oxford, LSE, and the Transformation of the Welfare State, 5–7 September 2016, Sano Shoin, Hitotsubashi University, Kunitachi, Tokyo, Japan.Google Scholar
Tarascio, Vincent J. 1968. Pareto’s Methodological Approach to Economics, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Tarascio, Vincent J. 1969. Paretian Welfare Theory: Some Neglected Aspects, Journal of Political Economy, 771, 120.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×