Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T03:35:51.890Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

15 - Long-run production frontiers for the Jones specific-factors model with optimal capital accumulation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 March 2010

Wilfred J. Ethier
Affiliation:
University of Pennsylvania
Elhanan Helpman
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
J. Peter Neary
Affiliation:
University College Dublin
Get access

Summary

Introduction

For those of us who received our classroom instruction in international trade theory prior to 1971, the 2 × 2 Heckscher-Ohlin model of trade constituted our “basic training.” The two-good, two-factor model with both factors perfectly mobile between the two sectors was the simple general-equilibrium model of factor proportions trade (simple one-factor Ricardian models constituted a technology-based explanation of trade). It is not clear what the justification for this exclusive focus was, but it is certainly true that the four theorems derived from that model constitute an elegant statement of theory: the Heckscher–Ohlin theorem, the factorprice- equalization theorem, the Rybczynski theorem, and the Stolper- Samuelson theorem.

In 1971, Ronald Jones published his paper, “A Three Factor Model in Theory, Trade, and History,” in which two goods are produced with three factors, two of which are sector specific and one of which is mobile between sectors. Jones expressed several motivations for this model. First, it removed the “straightjacket” of factor-price equalization, in that factor prices now depend on factor supplies as well as on commodity prices. Second, Jones found the model consistent with recent articles (at the time) in economic history and the theory of capital and international trade.

Gradually, the Jones specific-factors model has become more and more popular, both for pedagogic and for research purposes. The model in my opinion is now used at least as often as the Heckscher–Ohlin model to teach the simple general-equilibrium theory of trade. Several reasons for this popularity are found in later papers by Mayer (1974), Mussa (1974), and Neary (1978).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×