Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T03:36:29.692Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

8 - Firms, entry and hysteresis in the Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson model of production and trade

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 March 2010

Wilfred J. Ethier
Affiliation:
University of Pennsylvania
Elhanan Helpman
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
J. Peter Neary
Affiliation:
University College Dublin
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Simple general equilibrium models of production have been used extensively in the theory of international trade to study the determinants of comparative advantage and to explore the effects of various disturbances such as technological changes, factor growth and policy rearrangements on the structure of international trade and the distribution of income. The standard Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson model of two factors is the most popular of all although there are different possibilities such as the Ricardian model of a single factor and that of three or more factors. They commonly assume that technology of each sector exhibits constant returns to scale and that perfect competition prevails in all markets with the profits of firms being driven to zero in equilibrium. An extremely useful method to analyze these models was developed by Jones (1965, 1971) and has been applied to a wide range of problems.

The common assumptions of the models are, however, rather restrictive. The assumption of constant-returns-to-scale technology, together with the assumption of perfect competition, implies that the size of firms in each industry is indeterminate. It obscures the identity of firms since they could be infinitesimally small. Admittedly, it agrees completely well with perfectly competitive markets, but it is often at variance with monopolistic or oligopolistic markets. The recently developed models of international trade under imperfect competition usually specify the identity of firms by introducing product differentiation and/or increasing returns to scale in technology (see Helpman 1983, Helpman and Krugman 1985, 1989 for instance). The assumption of zero profits is equally restrictive. It implicitly assumes away interindustry differentials in mark-up ratios, a possibly important source of domestic distortions.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×