Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T23:42:41.330Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2016

Gary W. Cox
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Marketing Sovereign Promises
Monopoly Brokerage and the Growth of the English State
, pp. 189 - 204
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. 2005. Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. 2012. Why nations fail. New York: Crown.
Aghion, Philippe, Alesina, Alberto, and Trebbi, Francesco. 2004. “Endogenous Political Institutions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(2): 565–611.Google Scholar
Albert, W. 1972. The turnpike road system in England, 1663–1840. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Allen, Robert. 2009. The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
“An essay on the sinking fund; wherein the nature thereof is fully explained; and the right of the publick to that fund asserted and maintained. The second edition, corrected and much enlarged.” 1737. Printed for J Peele, at Locke's Head, in Amen-Corner.
Anderson, Clifford B. 1962. “Ministerial Responsibility in the 1620s.” The Journal of Modern History 34(4): 381–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansell, Benjamin, and Samuels, David. 2014. Inequality and democratization. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Aylmer, G. E. 1957. “The Last Years of Purveyance, 1610–1660.” Economic History Review 10(1): 81–93.Google Scholar
Azariadis, Costas, and Stachurski, John. 2005. “Poverty traps.” Handbook of economic growth, Volume 1A. Edited by Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven N.. London: Elsevier.
Baldez, Lisa, and Carey, John. 1999. “Presidential Agenda Control and Spending Policy: Lessons from General Pinochet's Constitution.” American Journal of Political Science 43(1): 29–55.Google Scholar
Banks, Arthur S., and Wilson, Kenneth A.. 2013. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive. Databanks International. Jerusalem, Israel.
Baron, David, and Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83(4): 1181–1206.Google Scholar
Barzel, Yoram, and Kiser, Edgar. 2002. “Taxation and Voting Rights in Medieval England and France.” Rationality and Society 14(4): 473–507.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H., and Lien, Da-Hsiang Donald. 1985. “A Note on Taxation, Development, and Representative Government.” Politics & Society 14(1): 53–70.Google Scholar
Bawn, Kathy, and Rosenbluth, Frances. 2006. “Short versus Long Coalitions: Electoral Accountability and the Size of the Public Sector.” American Journal of Political Science 50(2): 251–265.Google Scholar
Baxter, Stephen. 1957. The development of the Treasury, 1660–1702. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Beaulieu, Emily, Cox, Gary W., and Saiegh, Sebastian. 2012. “Sovereign Debt and Regime Type: Re-considering the Democratic Advantage.” International Organization 66(4): 709–738.Google Scholar
Beck, Neal, and Katz, Jonathan. 1995. “What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data.” American Political Science Review 89(3): 634–647.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. 1983. “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371–400.Google Scholar
Beckett, John. 2014. “The Glorious Revolution, Parliament, and the Making of the First Industrial Nation.” Parliamentary History 33(1): 36–53.Google Scholar
Berman, Sheri. 2001. “Modernization in Historical Perspective: The Case of Imperial Germany.” World Politics 53(3): 431–462.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy. 2005. “Political Selection.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(3): 43–60.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy. 2006. Principled agents? The political economy of good government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Binney, J. E. D. 1958. Public finance and administration, 1774–92. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bismarck, Prince Otto von. 1899. Bismarck: The man and the statesman. Trans. Butler, A. J.. New York: Harper and Bros.
Blackstone, William. 1979. Commentaries on the laws of England: A facsimile of the first edition of 1765–1769. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Blossfeld, Hans-Peter, Golsch, Katrin, and Rohwer, Götz. 2007. Techniques of event history modeling using Stata. Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.
Bogart, Dan. 2005. “Did Turnpike Trusts Increase Transport Investment in Eighteenth Century England?Journal of Economic History 65 (June): 439–468.Google Scholar
Bogart, Dan. 2011a. “Did the Glorious Revolution Contribute to the Transport Revolution?Economic History Review 64(4): 1073–1112.Google Scholar
Bogart, Dan. 2011b. “British legal institutions and transaction costs in the early Transport Revolution.” In Law and long-term economic change. Edited by Ma, Debin and van Zanden, Jan Luiten. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Bogart, D., Drelichman, M., Gelderblom, O., and Rosenthal, J. L.. 2010. “State and private institutions.” In The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe, Volume 1: 1700–1870. Edited by S. Broadberry and K. O'Rourke. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bogart, D., and Richardson, G. 2011. “Property Rights and Parliament in Industrializing Britain.” Journal of Law and Economics 54(2): 241–274.Google Scholar
Boix, Carles, Miller, Michael, and Rosato, Sebastian. 2012. “A Complete Data Set of Political Regimes, 1800–2007.” Comparative Political Studies 46(12): 1523–1554.Google Scholar
Bolton, Patrick, and Dewatripont, Mathias. 2005. Contract theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Borchard, Edwin, and Stumberg, George. 1931. Guide to the law and legal literature of France. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
Bowen, H. V. 1995. “The Bank of England during the long eighteenth century, 1694–1820.” In The Bank of England: Money, power and influence 1694–1994. Edited by Richard Roberts and David Kynaston. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Braddick, M. J. 1996. The nerves of state: Taxation and the financing of the English state, 1558–1714. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Brewer, John. 1988. The sinews of power: War, money, and the English state, 1688–1783. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Broz, J. L. 1998. The Origins of Central Banking: Solutions to the Free-Rider Problem. International Organization 52(2): 231–268.Google Scholar
Broz, J. L., and Grossman, R.. 2004. “Paying for Privilege: The Political Economy of Bank of England Charters, 1694–1844.” Explorations in Economic History 41: 48–72.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, et al. 2003. The logic of political survival. MIT Press.
Burg, David. 2004. A world history of tax rebellions. New York: Routledge.
Carlos, Ann, et al. 2013. “Financing and refinancing the War of the Spanish Succession, and then refinancing the South Sea Company.” In Questioning credible commitment. Edited by Coffman, D'Maris, Leonard, Adrian, and Neal, Larry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Carruthers, Bruce. 1996. City of capital: Politics and markets in the English financial revolution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Chandaman, C. D. 1975. The English public revenue 1660–1688. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Chapham, Sir John. 1945. The Bank of England: A history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cheibub, Jose Antonio. 2007. Presidentialism, parliamentarism and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cheyney, E. P. 1897. Translations and reprints from the original sources of European history, Vol. 1, No. 6. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Clark, Gregory. 1996. “The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth: England, 1540–1800.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 26: 563–588.Google Scholar
Clark, Gregory. 2007. A farewell to alms. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Clark, Gregory. 2009. “The macroeconomic aggregates for England, 1209–2008.” Working Papers, University of California, Department of Economics, No. 09,19.
Coase, Ronald. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3(1): 1–44.Google Scholar
Coffman, D'Maris. 2013. “Credibility, transparency, accountability, and the public credit under the Long Parliament and Commonwealth, 1643–1653.” In Questioning credible commitment: Perspectives on the rise of financial capitalism. Edited by Coffman, D'Maris, Leonard, Adrian, and Neal, Larry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cole, Daniel H. 2007. “Political Institutions, Judicial Review, and Private Property: A Comparative Institutional Analysis.” Supreme Court Economic Review 15(1): 141–182.Google Scholar
Comín, Francisco. 2010. “Public finance and the rise of the liberal state in Spain, 1808–1914.” In Paying for the liberal state. Edited by Cardoso, José Luís and Lains, Pedro. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Commons, John R. 1968. Legal foundations of capitalism. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
Congleton, Roger. 2011. Perfecting parliament. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, Gary W. 1987. The efficient secret. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, Gary W. 2011. “War, Moral Hazard and Ministerial Responsibility: England after the Glorious Revolution.” Journal of Economic History 71(1): 120–148.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 2012. “Was the Glorious Revolution a Constitutional Watershed?Journal of Economic History 72(3): 567–600.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 2001. “The institutional determinants of economic policy outcomes.” In Presidents, parliaments and policy. Edited by McCubbins, Mathew D. and Haggard, Stephan. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 21–63.
Crawford, Vincent. 1987. “International lending, long-term credit relationships and dynamic contract theory.” Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 59. Princeton, NJ: Department of Economics, Princeton University.
Cusack, Tom, Iversen, Torben, and Soskice, David. 2007. “Economic Interests and the Origins of Political Systems.” American Political Science Review 101: 372–391.Google Scholar
De Krey, Gary. 2007. Restoration and revolution in Britain. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Debré, Michel. 1957. Ces Princes qui nous gouvernent. Paris: Librairie Plon.
Debre, Michel 1959. “La Nouvelle Constitution.” Revue Française de science politique 9: 7–29.Google Scholar
Defoe, Daniel. 1710. “An essay upon publick credit, & c.” Printed and sold by the book-sellers.
Desan, Christine. 1998. “Remaking Constitutional Tradition at the Margin of the Empire: The Creation of Legislative Adjudication in Colonial New York.” Law and History Review 16(2): 257–317.Google Scholar
Devine, Tom. 2005. The transformation of Scotland: The economy since 1700. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
Dickson, P. G. M. 1967. The financial revolution in England. London: Macmillan.
Diermeier, Daniel, and Feddersen, Timothy. 1998. “Cohesion in Legislatures and the Vote of Confidence Procedure.” American Political Science Review 92(3): 611–621.Google Scholar
Dincecco, Mark. 2009. “Fiscal Centralization, Limited Government, and Public Revenues in Europe, 1650–1913.” Journal of Economic History 69: 48–103.Google Scholar
Dincecco, Mark. 2011. Political transformations and public finances: Europe, 1650–1913. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dincecco, Mark, Federico, Giovanni, and Vindigni, Andrea. 2011. “Warfare, Taxation, and Political Change: Evidence from the Italian Risorgimento.” Journal of Economic History 71(4): 887–914.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash. 2009. “Governance institutions and economic activity.” Delivered as the presidential address at the American Economic Association meetings on January 4, 2009.
Dixit, Avinash, and Londregan, John. 2000. “Political Power and the Credibility of Government Debt.” Journal of Economic Theory 94: 80–105.Google Scholar
Drelichman, Mauricio, and Voth, Hans-Joachim. 2011. “Lending to the Borrower from Hell: Debt and Default in the Age of Philip II.” The Economic Journal 121(557): 1205–1227.Google Scholar
Eaton, Jonathan, and Gersovitz, Mark. 1981. “Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.” Review of Economic Studies 48(2): 289–309.Google Scholar
Eggers, Andrew, and Hainmueller, Jens. 2009. “MPs for Sale: Estimating Returns to Office in Post-War British Politics.” American Political Science Review 103(4): 513–533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einzig, Paul. 1959. The control of the purse. London: Secker & Warburg.
Epstein, Stephan. 2000. Freedom and growth: The rise of states and markets in Europe, 1300–1750. London: Routledge.
Epstein, S. R. 2005. “The rise of the West.” In An anatomy of power: The social theory of Michael Mann. Edited by J. Hall and R. Schroeder. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fearon, James. 1995a. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49(Summer): 379–414.Google Scholar
Fearon, James. 1995b. “Bargaining over Objects that Influence Future Bargaining Power.” Chicago Center on Democracy. Working Paper, University of Chicago.
Ferejohn, John. 1999. “Accountability and authority: Towards a model of political accountability.” In Democracy, accountability, and representation. Edited by Przeworski, Adam, Manin, Bernard, and Stokes, Susan C.. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ferejohn, John, and Rosenbluth, Frances. 2008. “Warlike Democracies.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(1): 3–38.Google Scholar
Findlay, Ronald, and O'Rourke, Kevin. 2007. Power and plenty: Trade, war and the world economy in the second millennium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Finer, S. E. 1999. The history of government from the earliest times, vol. III. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Fish, M. Steven, and Kroenig, Matthew. 2011. The handbook of national legislatures: A global survey. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Flynn, John. 1988. “At the Threshold of Dissolution: The National Liberals and Bismarck 1877/1878.” Historical Journal 31(2): 319–340.Google Scholar
Foord, A. S. 1947. “The Waning of ‘The Influence of the Crown.’English Historical Review 62: 484–507.Google Scholar
George, Robert H. 1940. “The Charters Granted to English Parliamentary Corporations in 1688.” English Historical Review 55(217): 15–46.Google Scholar
Getzler, Joshua. 1996. “Theories of Property and Economic Development.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 26: 639–669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goemans, Henk, Gleditsch, Kristian, and Chiozza, Giacomo. 2009. “Introducing Archigos: A Dataset of Political Leaders.” Journal of Peace Research 46(2): 269–283.Google Scholar
Gregg, Pauline. 1984. King Charles I. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Greif, Avner. 2007. “Toward political economy of implementation: The impact of administrative power on institutional and economic development.” Unpublished typescript, Stanford University.
Groseclose, Timothy, and Snyder, James. 1996. “Buying Supermajorities.” American Political Science Review 90(2): 303–315.Google Scholar
Grotius, Hugo. 1949[1625]. The law of war and peace. New York: W J Black.
Guembel, Alexander, and Sussman, Oren. 2009. “Sovereign Debt without Default Penalties.” Review of Economic Studies 76: 1297–1320.Google Scholar
Guerra, José Guillermo. 1929. La Constitución de 1925. Santiago: Balcells & Co.
Guicciardini, Nicoló. 2005. “Isaac Newton, Philosophiae Naturalis Principia Mathematica, First Edition (1687).” In Landmark Writings in Western Mathematics 1640–1940. Edited by Grattan-Guiness, Ivor. London: Elsevier.
Haber, Stephen, Maurer, Noel, and Razo, Armando. 2003. The politics of property rights: Political instability, credible commitments, and economic growth in Mexico, 1876–1929. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hahn, Erich. 1977. “Ministerial Responsibility and Impeachment in Prussia 1848–63.” Central European History 10(1): 3–27.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, Mark, Strauch, Rolf, and Hagen, Jürgen von. 2010. Fiscal governance in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Harling, Philip. 1996. The waning of “old corruption”: The politics of economical reform in Britain, 1779–1846. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Harling, Philip. 2001. The modern British state: An historical introduction. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Harris, Ron. 2000. Industrializing English law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Harris, Ron. 2004. “Government and the economy.” In The Cambridge economic history of modern Britain, vol. 1. Edited by Roderick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Harris, Ron. 2013. “Could the crown credibly commit to respect its charters? England 1558–1640.” In Questioning credible commitment: Perspectives on the rise of financial capitalism. Edited by Coffman, D'Maris, Leonard, Adrian, and Neal, Larry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hayton, D. W. 2002. The House of Commons 1690–1715. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hayton, David. 1995. “Constitutional experiments and political expediency, 1689–1725.” In Conquest and Union. Edited by Steven Ellis and Sarah Barber. London: Longman.
Hill, B. W. 1971. “The Change of Government and the ‘Loss of the City’, 1710–1711.” Economic History Review 24(3): 395–413.Google Scholar
Hill, Brian W. 1976. The growth of parliamentary parties 1689–1742. London: George Allen and Unwin.
Hirschman, Albert. 1977. The Passions and the Interests. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Hirst, Derek. 1986. Authority and conflict: England 1603–1658. London: Edward Arnold.
Hoffman, Philip T. 2009. “Why was it that Europeans conquered the world?” Unpublished typescript, California Institute of Technology.
Hoffman, Philip T. 2015. Why did Europe conquer the world?Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Hoffman, Philip T., and Norberg, Kathryn, eds. 1994. Fiscal crises, liberty and representative government, 1450–1789. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Hoffman, Philip T., Postel-Vinay, Gilles, and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 2000. Priceless markets: The political economy of credit in Paris, 1660–1870. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hoffman, Philip T., and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1997. “The political economy of warfare and taxation in early modern Europe: Historical lessons for economic development.” In The frontiers of the new institutional economics. Edited by Drobak, John N. and Nye, John. New York: Academic Press, 31–35.
Homer, Sidney. 1963. A History of Interest Rates. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.
Hoppit, Julian. 1997. Failed Legislation 1660–1800. London: Hambledon Press.
Hoppit, Julian. 2000. A land of liberty? England 1689–1727. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hoppit, Julian. 2002. “Checking the Leviathan, 1688–1832.” In The political economy of British historical experience, 1688–1914. Edited by Winch, Donald and O'Brien, Patrick K.. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hoppit, Julian. 2011. “Compulsion, Compensation and Property Rights in Britain, 1688–1833.” Past and Present 210: 93–128.Google Scholar
Horsefield, J. Keith. 1982. “The ‘Stop of the Exchequer’ Revisited.” Economic History Review 35(4): 511–528.Google Scholar
Horwitz, Henry. 1977. Parliament, policy and politics in the reign of William III. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Huber, John. 1996. Rationalizing parliament: Legislative institutions and party politics in France. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Jackson, Matthew, and Morelli, Massimo. 2011. “The reasons for wars – an updated survey.” In The handbook on the political economy of war. Edited by Coyne, Christopher and Mathers, Rachel. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
James, Herman. 1913. Principles of Prussian administration. New York: Macmillan.
Jha, Saumitra. 2008. “Shares, coalition formation and political development: Evidence from seventeenth century England.” Stanford Graduate School of Business, Research Paper No. 2005.
Jha, Saumitra. 2012. “Financial innovations and political development: Evidence from Revolutionary England.” Unpublished typescript, Stanford University.
John, A. H. 1955. “War and the English Economy, 1700–1763.” Economic History Review 7(3): 329–344.Google Scholar
Johnson, Noel, and Koyama, Mark. 2014. “Tax Farming and the Origins of State Capacity in England and France.” Explorations in Economic History 51: 1–20.Google Scholar
Jones, Eric. 2013. “Economics without History: Objections to the Rights Hypothesis.” Continuity and Change 28(3): 323–346.Google Scholar
Jones, J. R. 1994. “Fiscal policies, liberties and representative government during the reigns of the last Stuarts.” In Fiscal crises, liberty, and representative government 1450–1789. Edited by Hoffman, Philip T. and Norberg, Kathryn. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Jones, J. R. 1996. The Anglo-Dutch wars of the seventeenth century. London: Longman.
Jones, W. R. 1975. “Purveyance for War and the Community of the Realm in Late Medieval England.” Albion 7(4): 300–316.Google Scholar
Katzenstein, Peter. 1985. Small states in world markets. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Kelly, Morgan, Mokyr, Joel, and Gráda, Cormac Ó. 2014. “Precocious Albion: A New Interpretation of the British Industrial Revolution.” Annual Review of Economics 6: 363–389.Google Scholar
Kemp, Betty. 1957. King and Commons, 1660–1832. London: Macmillan.
Kiser, Edgar, and Linton, April. 2001. “Determinants of the Growth of the State: War and Taxation in Early Modern France and England.” Social Forces 80(2): 411–448.Google Scholar
Kiser, Edgar, and Linton, April. 2002. “The Hinges of History: State-making and Revolt in Early Modern France.” American Sociological Review 67(6): 889–910.Google Scholar
Klerman, Daniel, and Mahoney, Paul. 2005. “The Value of Judicial Independence: Evidence from Eighteenth Century England.” American Law and Economics Review 7: 1–27.Google Scholar
Kletzer, Kenneth M., and Wright, Brian D.. 2000. “Sovereign Debt as Intertemporal Barter.” American Economic Review 90(3): 621–639.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2011. The long divergence: How Islamic law held back the Middle East. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Lake, David. 1992. “Powerful Pacifists: Democratic States and War.” American Political Science Review 86(1): 24–37.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi. 2009. “Scylla or Charybdis? Historical Reflections on Two Basic Problems of Corporate Governance.” Business History Review 83(Spring): 9–34.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi. 2011. “The Mystery of Property Rights: A U.S. Perspective.” Journal of Economic History 71(2): 275–306.Google Scholar
Landes, David S. 1983. Revolution in time: Clocks and the making of the modern world. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Lavaux, Phillippe. 1988. Parliamentarisme rationalize et stabilité du pouvoir executif. Bruxelles: Bruylant.
Lemire, Beverly. 1997. Dress, culture and commerce: The English clothing trade before the factory, 1660–1800. New York: St Martin's Press.
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Linz, Juan. 1990. “The Perils of Presidentialism.” Journal of Democracy 1(1): 51–69.Google Scholar
Little, David. 1969. Religion, order and law: A study in pre-Revolutionary England. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Londregan, John, and Poole, Keith. 1990. “Poverty, the Coup Trap, and the Seizure of Executive Power.” World Politics 42(2): 151–183.Google Scholar
Loveman, Brian. 1993. The constitution of tyranny. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Macaulay, Thomas. 1848. The history of England from the accession of James II. Philadelphia, PA: Porter and Coates.
MacDonald, James. 2013. “The importance of not defaulting: The significance of the election of 1710.” In Questioning credible commitment: Perspectives on the rise of financial capitalism. Edited by Coffman, D'Maris, Leonard, Adrian, and Neal, Larry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Machiavelli, Niccolò. 1979[1513]. The prince. In The portable Machiavelli. Edited by Bondanella, Peter and Musa, Mark. New York: Penguin.
Madison, James. 2009[1788]. The Federalist papers. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Maeda, Ko. 2010. “Two Modes of Democratic Breakdown: A Competing Risks Analysis of Democratic Durability.” Journal of Politics 72(4): 1129–1143.Google Scholar
Maitland, F. W. 1908. The constitutional history of England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Major, J. Russell. 1960. Representative institutions in Renaissance France, 1421–1559. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
Marongiu, Antonio. 1968. Medieval parliaments: A comparative study. London: Eyre and Spottiswoode.
Marshall, Monty, Gurr, Ted Robert, and Jaggers, Keith. 2014. “Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2013: Dataset users’ manual.” Center for Systemic Peace.
McCarty, Nolan. 2004. “The Appointments Dilemma.” American Journal of Political Science 48(3): 413–428.Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan, and Razaghian, Rose. 1999. “Advice and Consent: Senate Responses to Executive Branch Nominations 1885–1999.” American Journal of Political Science 43(4): 1122–1143.Google Scholar
McGuire, Martin, and Olson, Mancur. 1996. “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force.” Journal of Economic Literature 34(1): 72–96.Google Scholar
McNeill, William H. 1982. The pursuit of power. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
McNulty, William. 1912. “Eminent Domain in Continental Europe.” Yale Law Journal 21(7): 555–570.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Alan, and Richard, Scott. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy 89(5): 914–927.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, North, Douglass, and Weingast, Barry. 1990. “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1–23.Google Scholar
Mitchell, B. R. 1962. Abstract of British historical statistics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mitchell, B. R. 1988. British historical statistics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Moe, Terry, and Caldwell, Michael. 1994. “The Institutional Foundations of Democratic Government: A Comparison of Presidential and Parliamentary Systems.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150(1): 171–195.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The gifts of Athena. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2008. “The institutional origins of the Industrial Revolution.” In Institutions and economic performance. Edited by Elhanan Helpman. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2009. The enlightened economy: An economic history of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Mokyr, Joel, and Nye, John. 2007. “Distributional Coalitions, the Industrial Revolution, and the Origins of Economic Growth in Britain.” Southern Economic Journal 74(1): 50–70.Google Scholar
Montesquieu, Charles de Secondat. 1989[1748]. Spirit of the laws. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mork, Gordon R. 1971. “Bismarck and the Capitulation of German Liberalism.” Journal of Modern History 43(1): 59–75.Google Scholar
Morrill, John Stephen. 1974. Cheshire 1630–1660: County government and society during the English revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mundill, Robin R. 2010. The king's Jews: Money, massacre, and exodus in medieval England. New York: Continuum.
Murphy, Anne L. 2012. The origins of English financial markets: Investment and speculation before the South Sea Bubble. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Murphy, Anne L. 2013. “Demanding ‘Credible Commitment’: Public Reactions to the Failures of the Early Financial Revolution.” Economic History Review 66(1): 178–197.Google Scholar
Murrell, Peter. 2009. “Design and evolution in institutional development: The insignificance of the English Bill of Rights.” Unpublished Typescript, University of Maryland.
Muthoo, Abhinay. 1999. Bargaining theory with applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Myerson, Roger. 2008. “The Autocrat's Credibility Problem and Foundations of the Constitutional State.” American Political Science Review 102(1): 125–140.Google Scholar
Neal, Larry. 1990. The rise of financial capitalism: International capital markets in the age of reason. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. 1981. Growth and structural change. New York: Norton.
North, Douglass, Wallis, John Joseph, and Weingast, Barry R.. 2009. Violence and Social Orders. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass, and Weingast, Barry. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century Britain.” Journal of Economic History 49(4): 803–832.Google Scholar
Nye, John. 2007. War, wine, and taxes: The political economy of Anglo-French trade 1689–1900. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
O'Brien, Patrick. 1988. “The Political Economy of British Taxation, 1660–1815.” Economic History Review 2d series 41(1): 1–32.Google Scholar
O'Brien, Patrick. 2002. “Fiscal exceptionalism: Great Britain and its European rivals from civil war to triumph at Trafalgar and Waterloo.” In The political economy of British historical experience, 1688–1914. Edited by Winch, Donald and O'Brien, Patrick K.. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
O'Brien, Patrick. 2005. “Fiscal and financial preconditions for the rise of British naval hegemony 1485–1815.” Working Paper No. 91/05. Department of Economic History, London School of Economics.
O'Donnell, Guillermo. 1994. “Delegative Democracy.” Journal of Democracy 5(1): 55–69.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy and Development.” American Political Science Review 87(3): 567–576.Google Scholar
Parthasarathi, Prasannan. 2011. Why Europe grew rich and Asia did not. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Payling, Simon. 2009. “The House of Commons, 1307–1529.” In A short history of Parliament. Edited by Jones, Clyve. Woodbridge: The Boydell Press.
Peck, Linda Levy. 1990. Court patronage and corruption in early Stuart England. Boston, MA: Unwin Hyman.
Pelizzo, Riccardo, and Stapenhurst, Rick, eds. 2004. Legislatures and oversight. Washington, DC: IBRD/World Bank.
Perotti, R. and Kontopoulos, Y.. 2002. “Fragmented Fiscal Policy.” Journal of Public Economics 86(2): 191–222.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, Roland, Gerard, and Tabellini, Guido. 1997. “Separation of Powers and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 1163–1202.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, Roland, Gerard, and Tabellini, Guido. 2000. “Comparative Politics and Public Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 108(6): 1121–1161.Google Scholar
Pincus, Steve. 2009. 1688: The first modern revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Pincus, Steve, and Robinson, James. 2011a. “What really happened during the Glorious Revolution?” NBER Working Paper 17206.
Pincus, Steve, and Robinson, James. 2011b. “What really happened during the Glorious Revolution – and why it matters for current fiscal crises.” Posted on www.voxeu.org August 7, 2011.
Pincus, Steve, and Robinson, James. 2014. “Wars and state-making reconsidered: The rise of the interventionist state.” Unpublished typescript, Yale University.
Pintilie, Melania. 2007. “Analysing and Interpreting Competing Risk Data.” Statistics in Medicine 26: 1360–1367.Google Scholar
Pool, Bernard. 1966. Navy Board contracts 1660–1832. Hamden, CT: Archon Books.
Poole, Keith B., and Londregan, John. 1990. “Poverty, the Coup Trap, and the Seizure of Executive Power.” World Politics 42(2): 151–183.Google Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1999. In the shadow of power. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Power, Eileen. 1942. The wool trade in English medieval history, being the Ford Lectures. London: Oxford University Press.
Przeworski, Adam, and Wallerstein, Michael. 1982. “The Structure of Class Conflict in Democratic Capitalist Societies.” American Political Science Review 75: 215–238.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam et al. 2000. Democracy and development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Przeworski, Adam 2013. Political Institutions and Political Events (PIPE) Dataset. Department of Politics, New York University.
Quinn, Stephen. 2001. “The Glorious Revolution's Effect on English Private Finance: A Microhistory, 1680–1705.” Journal of Economic History 61(3): 593–615.Google Scholar
Quinn, Stephen. 2004. “Questioning a stylized fact: When did the Bank of England become a delegated bureaucrat?” Unpublished typescript, Texas Christian University.
Quinn, Stephen. 2008. “Securitization of sovereign debt: Corporations as a sovereign debt restructuring mechanism in Britain, 1694 to 1750.” Unpublished typescript, Texas Christian University.
Ramey, Garey, and Watson, Joel. 2002. “Contractual Intermediaries.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 18(2): 362–384.Google Scholar
Redlich, Josef. 1908. The procedure of the House of Commons: A study of its history and present form. Translated by Steinthal, A. E.. London: Archibald Constable & Co.
Reenock, Christopher, Staton, Jeffrey, and Radean, Marius. 2013. “Legal Institutions and Democratic Survival.” Journal of Politics 75(2): 491–505.Google Scholar
Reitan, E. A. 1970. “From Revenue to Civil List, 1689–1702: The Revolution Settlement and the ‘Mixed and Balanced’ Constitution.” Historical Journal 13(4): 571–588.Google Scholar
Reiter, Dan, and Stam, Allan. 1998. “Democracy, War Initiation, and Victory.” American Political Science Review 92(2): 377–389.Google Scholar
Reynolds, Susan. 2010. Before eminent domain. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
Roberts, Clayton. 1956. “The Growth of Ministerial Responsibility to Parliament in Later Stuart England.” Journal of Modern History 28(3): 215–233.Google Scholar
Roberts, Clayton. 1959. “Privy Council Schemes and Ministerial Responsibility in Later Stuart England.” American Historical Review 64(3): 564–582.Google Scholar
Roberts, Clayton. 1966. The growth of responsible government in Stuart England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Roberts, Clayton. 1977. “The Constitutional Significance of the Financial Settlement of 1690.” Historical Journal 20(1): 59–76.Google Scholar
Robinson, James. 2006. “Debt repudiation and risk premia: The North-Weingast thesis revisited.” Unpublished typescript, Harvard University.
Rodger, N. A. M. 2004. The command of the ocean: A naval history of Britain, 1649–1815. New York: W. W. Norton.
Rodger, N. A. M. 2010. “War as an Economic Activity in the ‘Long’ Eighteenth Century.” International Journal of Maritime History 22(2): 1–18.Google Scholar
Roeder, Philip G. 2001. “Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization (ELF) Indices, 1961 and 1985.” http://weber.ucsd.edu\~proeder\elf.htm.
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1978. “Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas and the Status Quo.” Public Choice 33(4): 27–43.Google Scholar
Root, H. L. 1989. “Tying the King's Hands: Credible Commitment and Royal Fiscal Policy During the Old Regime.” Rationality and Society 1(2):240–58.Google Scholar
Root, H. L. 1994. The fountain of privilege: Political foundations of markets in Old Regime France and England. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1990. “The Development of Irrigation in Provence, 1700–1860: The French Revolution and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic History 50(3): 615–638.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1992. The fruits of revolution: Property rights, litigation, and French agriculture, 1700–1860. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1998. “The political economy of absolutism reconsidered.” In Analytic narratives. Edited by Robert Bates et al. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 64–108.
Roseveare, Henry. 1973. The Treasury, 1660–1870. London: George Allen and Unwin.
Rydz, D. L. 1979. The parliamentary agents. London: Royal Historical Society.
Sacks, David Harris. 1994. “The paradox of taxation: Fiscal crises, parliament, and liberty in England, 1450–1640.” In Fiscal crises, liberty, and representative covernment 1450–1789. Edited by Hoffman, Philip T. and Norberg, Kathryn. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Saiegh, Sebastián. 2011. Ruling by statute. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Saiegh, Sebastián. 2012. “Political institutions and sovereign borrowing: Evidence from nineteenth- century Argentina.” Public Choice.
Santiso, Carlos. 2004. “Legislatures and Budget Oversight in Latin America.” OECD Journal on Budgeting 4(2): 47–76.Google Scholar
Schedler, Andreas. 2002. “The Menu of Manipulation.” Journal of Democracy 13(2): 36–50.Google Scholar
Schedler, Andreas. 2006. Electoral authoritarianism. New York: Lynne Rienner.
Schultz, Kenneth, and Weingast, Barry R.. 2003. “The Democratic Advantage: The Institutional Sources of State Power in International Competition.” International Organization 57: 3–42.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1918[1954]. “The crisis of the tax state.” In International economic papers: Translations prepared for the International Economic Association. Edited by Peacock, Allan et al. New York: MacMillan.
Scott, William Robert. 1912. The constitution and finance of English, Scottish and Irish joint-stock companies to 1720: Companies for foreign trade, colonization, fishing and mining, Vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Shaw, William A., ed. 1931. Calendar of Treasury books, Volume 9. London: Printed for Her Majesty's Stationery Office.
Shaw, William A., ed. 1952. Calendar of Treasury books, Volume 21. London: Printed for Her Majesty's Stationery Office.
Shugart, Matthew. 1998. “The Inverse Relationship between Party Strength and Executive Strength: A Theory of Politicians’ Constitutional Choices.” British Journal of Political Science 28(1): 1–29.Google Scholar
Siavelis, Peter. 2002. “Exaggerated presidentialism and moderate presidents: Executive-legislative relations in Chile.” In Legislative politics in Latin America. Edited by Scott Morgenstern and Benito Nacif. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Stasavage, David. 2003. Public debt and the birth of the democratic state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stasavage, David. 2007. “Partisan Politics and Public Debt: The Importance of the ‘Whig Supremacy’ for Britain's Financial Revolution.” European Review of Economic History 11: 123–153.Google Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2011. States of credit: Size, power and the development of European politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Stith, Kate 1988. “Congress’ Power of the Purse.” Yale Law Journal 97: 1343–1396.Google Scholar
Stoebuck, W. B. 1972. “A General Theory of Eminent Domain.” Washington Law Review 47: 553–608.Google Scholar
Stourm, Rene. 1917. The budget. New York: D. Appleton and Company.
Sussman, Nathan, and Yafeh, Yishay. 2006. “Institutional Reforms, Financial Developments and Sovereign Debt: Britain 1690–1790.” Journal of Economic History 66(3): 906–935.Google Scholar
Sussman, Nathan, and Yafeh, Yishay. 2013. “Institutions, deficits, and wars: The determinants of British government borrowing costs from the end of the seventeenth century to 1850.” In Questioning credible commitment: Perspectives on the rise of financial capitalism. Edited by D'Maris Coffman, Adrian Leonard, and Larry Neal. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Sutherland, Donald. 1973. The Assize of Novel Disseisin. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Svolik, Milan. 2008. “Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation.” American Political Science Review 102: 153–168.Google Scholar
Szostak, Rick. 1991. The role of transportation in the Industrial Revolution. Montreal: McGill-Queens University Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1966. “The Political Economy of Public Finance and the Industrialization of Prussia, 1815–1866.” Journal of Economic History 26(4): 484–497.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, capital and European states, AD 990–1990. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.
Tilly, Charles. 1995. Popular Contention in Great Britain, 1758–1834. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Todd, Alpheus. 1867. On parliamentary government in England. London: Longmans, Green and Co.
Tomz, Michael. 2007. Reputation and international cooperation: Sovereign debt across three centuries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Tsebelis, George. 2002. Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
van Caenegem, R. C. 1973. The birth of the English common law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
van Zanden, Jan Luiten, Buringh, Eltjo, and Bosker, Maarten. 2012. “The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188–1789.” Economic History Review 65(3): 835–861.Google Scholar
Waugh, Scott L. 1991. England in the reign of Edward III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wehner, Joachim. 2010. “Cabinet Structure and Fiscal Policy Outcomes.” European Journal of Political Research 49(5): 631–653.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1997. “The political foundations of limited government: Parliament and sovereign debt in seventeenth- and eighteenth-century England.” In The frontiers of the new institutional economics. Edited by Brobak, J. N. and Nye, J. V. C.. San Diego, CA: Academic Press.
Weiser, Brian. 2003. Charles II and the politics of access. Woodbridge and Suffolk: Boydell Press.
Wells, John, and Wills, Douglas. 2000. “Revolution, Restoration, and Debt Repudiation: The Jacobite Threat to Britain's Institutions and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic History 60(2) (2000): 418–441.Google Scholar
Wheeler, J. S. 1996. “Navy Finance, 1649–1660.” Historical Journal 39(2): 457–466.Google Scholar
Whipple, Edwin P. 1879. The great speeches and orations of Daniel Webster. Boston, MA: Little and Brown.
Wiener, Frederick. 1972. “The Register of Writs: Seed-Bed of the Common Law.” American Bar Association Journal 58: 498–504.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1983. “Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange.” American Economic Review 73(4): 519–540.Google Scholar
Wilmerding, Lucius. 1943. The spending power. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Woodhouse, Caleb. 1974. “The Defense Question and Danish Politics, 1864– 1914.” Scandinavian Studies 46(3): 201–228.Google Scholar
Zahedieh, Nuala. 2010. “Regulation, Rent-Seeking, and the Glorious Revolution in the English Atlantic Economy.” Economic History Review 63(4): 865–890.Google Scholar
Ziblatt, Daniel. 2006. Structuring the state: The formation of Italy and Germany and the puzzle of federalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Gary W. Cox, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Marketing Sovereign Promises
  • Online publication: 05 May 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316493007.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Gary W. Cox, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Marketing Sovereign Promises
  • Online publication: 05 May 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316493007.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Gary W. Cox, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Marketing Sovereign Promises
  • Online publication: 05 May 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316493007.014
Available formats
×