Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T07:13:08.090Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part II - Post-Performative Approaches to Studying Markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 November 2024

Susi Geiger
Affiliation:
University College Dublin
Katy Mason
Affiliation:
Lancaster University
Neil Pollock
Affiliation:
University of Edinburgh
Philip Roscoe
Affiliation:
University of St Andrews, Scotland
Annmarie Ryan
Affiliation:
University of Limerick
Stefan Schwarzkopf
Affiliation:
Copenhagen Business School
Pascale Trompette
Affiliation:
Université de Grenoble
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Market Studies
Mapping, Theorizing and Impacting Market Action
, pp. 97 - 160
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References

Callon, M. (1998) The embeddedness of economic markets in economics, in Callon, M. (ed.), The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell, 158.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (2007) What does it mean to say that economics is performative?, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 311357.Google Scholar
Callon, M., and Muniesa, F. (2005) Peripheral vision: economic markets as calculative collective devices. Organization Studies, 26(8), 12291250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Çalışkan, K., and Callon, M. (2010) Economization, part 2: a research programme for the study of markets. Economy and Society, 39(1), 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D’Adderio, L., Glaser, V., and Pollock, N. (2019) Performing theories, transforming organizations: a reply to Marti and Gond. Academy of Management Review, 44(3), 676679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D’Adderio, L., and Pollock, N. (2014) Performing modularity: competing rules, performative struggles and the effect of organizational theories on the organization. Organization Studies, 35(12), 18131843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J., and Sutton, R. I. (2005) Economic language and assumptions: how theories can become self-fulfilling. Academy of Management Review, 30(1), 824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2006) Is economics performative? Option theory and the construction of derivatives markets. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(1), 2955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2009) Material Markets: How Economic Agents Are Constructed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D., and Millo, Y. (2003) Constructing a market, performing theory: the historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 109(1), 107145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marti, E., and Gond, J. P. (2018) When do theories become self-fulfilling? Exploring the boundary conditions of performativity. Academy of Management Review, 43(3), 487508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., and Rowan, B. (1977) Institutionalized organizations: formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, P. (2008) Calculating economic life. Journal of Cultural Economy, 1(1), 5164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellandini-Simányi, L. (2016) Non-marketizing agents in the study of markets: competing legacies of performativity and actor-network-theory in the marketization research program. Journal of Cultural Economy, 9(6), 570586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollock, N., and Williams, R. (2016) How Industry Analysts Shape the Digital Future. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tellmann, U. (2020) Beyond performativity: material futures of finance. Economy and Society, 49(3), 345363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

References

Asdal, K. (2011) The office: the weakness of numbers and the production of non-authority. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 36(1), 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asdal, K. (2014) From climate issue to oil issue: offices of public administration, versions of economics, and the ordinary technologies of politics. Environment and Planning A, 46(9), 21102114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asdal, K., Brenna, B., and Moser, I. (eds.) (2007) Technoscience: The Politics of Intervention. Oslo: Oslo Academic Press.Google Scholar
Asdal, K., and Cointe, B. (2021) Experiments in co-modification: a relational take on the becoming of commodities and the making of market value. Journal of Cultural Economy, 14(3), 280292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asdal, K., and Cointe, B. (2022) Writing good economics: how texts ‘on the move’ perform the lab and discipline of experimental economics. Social Studies of Science, 52(3), 376398.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Asdal, K., and Huse, T. (2023) Nature-Made Economy: Cod, Capital, and the Great Economization of the Ocean. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austin, J. L. (1962) How to Do Things with Words. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Barry, A., and Slater, D. (2002) Introduction: the technological economy. Economy and Society, 31(2), 175193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Böhme, J. (2016) ‘Doing’ laboratory experiments: an ethnomethodological study of the performative practice in behavioral economic research, in Boldyrev, I., and Svetlova, E. (eds.), Enacting Dismal Science: New Perspectives on the Performativity of Economics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 87108.Google Scholar
Butler, J. (2010) Performative agency. Journal of Cultural Economy, 3(2), 147161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Çalışkan, K., and Callon, M. (2010) Economization, part 2: a research programme for the study of markets. Economy and Society, 39(1), 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M. (ed.) (1998) The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (1999) Actor network theory: the market test, in Law, J., and Hassard, J. (eds.), Actor Network Theory and After. Oxford: Blackwell, 181195.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (2007) What does it mean to say that economics is performative?, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 311357.Google Scholar
Fourcade, M. (2011) Price and prejudice: on economics and the enchantment (and disenchantment) of Nature, in Beckert, J., and Aspers, P. (eds.), The Worth of Goods: Valuation and Pricing in the Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 4162.Google Scholar
Frankel, C., Ossandón, J., and Pallesen, T. (2019) The organization of markets for collective concerns and their failures. Economy and Society, 48(2), 153174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grandclément, C., and Gaglio, G. (2011) Convoking the consumer in person: the focus group effect, in Zwick, D., and Cayla, J. (eds.), Inside Marketing: Practices, Ideologies, Devices. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 87114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guala, F. (2007) How to do things with experimental economics?, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 128162.Google Scholar
Harrison, G. W., and List, J. (2005) Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 10091055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ISO (2007) ISO 8589:2007. Sensory analysis: general guidance for the design of test rooms, 2nd ed. Geneva: ISO.Google Scholar
Lezaun, J. (2007) A market of opinion: the political epistemology of focus groups, in Callon, M., Millo, Y., and Munesia, F. (eds.), Market Devices. Oxford: Blackwell, 130151.Google Scholar
Lezaun, J., Muniesa, F., and Vikkelsø, S. (2013) Provocative containment and the drift of socio-scientific realism. Journal of Cultural Economy, 6(3), 278293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2006) Is economics performative? Option theory and the construction of derivatives markets. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(1), 2955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.) (2007) Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P., and Nik-Khah, E. (2007) Markets made flesh: performativity, and a problem in science studies, augmented with a consideration of the FCC auctions, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L.-S. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 190224.Google Scholar
Mitchell, T. (2005) The work of economics: how a discipline makes its world. European Journal of Sociology, 46(2), 297320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, T. (2008) Rethinking economy. Geoforum, 39(3), 11161121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, F. (2014) The Provoked Economy. Economic Reality and the Performative Turn. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, F., and Callon, M. (2007) Economic experiments and the construction of markets, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 163189.Google Scholar
Muniesa, F., and Trébuchet-Breitwiller, A.-S. (2010) Becoming a measuring instrument. Journal of Cultural Economy, 3(3), 321337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollock, N., and Williams, R. (2016) How Industry Analysts Shape the Digital Future. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, T., Brenninkmeijer, J., and Woolgar, S. (2022) Enacting the ‘consuming’ brain: an ethnographic study of accountability redistributions in neuromarketing practices. The Sociological Review, 70(5), 10251043.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzkopf, S. (2021a) Market research as ascetic detachment: product testing in a German market test town. Consumption Markets and Culture, 24(4), 329342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzkopf, S. (2021b) Ten little jurors in the training camp: a genealogy of audience simulation. Journal of Cultural Economy, 14(6), 732749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sorgner, H. (2017) Economics in the laboratory: a case study on epistemic practices and valuations in experimental economics. Master’s thesis, Department of Science and Technology Studies, University of Vienna.Google Scholar
Teil, G. (1993) Représenter les consommateurs. Gérer et Comprendre Annales des Mines, 32, 7484.Google Scholar
Teil, G. (1998) Devenir expert aromaticien: y a-t-il une place pour le goût dans les goûts alimentaires? Sociologie du travail, 40(4), 503522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teil, G., and Muniesa, F. (2006) Donner un prix: observations à partir d’un dispositif d’économie expérimentale. Terrains & Travaux, 2(11), 222244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

References

ADEME (2019) Évaluation du dispositif des certificats d’économie d’énergie: Rapport synthétique. Paris: ADEME.Google Scholar
Asdal, K. (2014) From climate issue to oil issue: offices of public administration, versions of economics, and the ordinary technologies of politics. Environment and Planning A, 46(9), 21102124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barral, S. (2021) Conservation, finance, bureaucrats: managing time and space in the production of environmental intangibles. Journal of Cultural Economy, 14(5), 549563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, A. (2002) The anti-political economy. Economy and Society, 31(2), 268284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, U. (1992) Risk Society: Towards a New Modernity. London: SAGE.Google Scholar
Blaise, G., and Glachant, M. (2019) Quel est l’impact des travaux de rénovation énergétique des logements sur la consommation d’énergie? La Revue de l’énergie, 646, 4660.Google Scholar
Blok, A. (2011) Clash of the eco-sciences: carbon marketization, environmental NGOs and performativity as politics. Economy and Society, 40(3), 451476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun, M. (2009) The evolution of emissions trading in the European Union: the role of policy networks, knowledge and policy entrepreneurs. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34(3/4), 469487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breslau, D. (2013) Designing a market-like entity: economics in the politics of market formation. Social Studies of Science, 43(6), 829851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bromley, P., and Powell, W. W. (2012) From smoke and mirrors to walking the talk: decoupling in the contemporary world. Academy of Management Annals, 6(1), 483530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryant, G. (2016) The politics of carbon market design: rethinking the techno-politics and post-politics of climate change. Antipode, 48(4), 877898.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M. (ed.) (1998) The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (2007) What does it mean to say that economics is performative?, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 311357.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (2009) Civilizing markets: carbon trading between in vitro and in vivo experiments. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34(3/4), 535548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
CGEDD (2014) Les certificats d’économies d’énergie: Efficacité énergétique et analyse économique. Paris: CGEDD.Google Scholar
Chiapello, E., and Engels, A. (2021) The fabrication of environmental intangibles as a questionable response to environmental problems. Journal of Cultural Economy, 14(5), 517532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960) The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 16(3), 144.Google Scholar
Cochoy, F., Giraudeau, M., and McFall, L. (2010) Performativity, economics and politics: an overview. Journal of Cultural Economy, 3(2), 139146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cointe, B., and Nadaï, A. (2018) Feed-in tariffs in the European Union: Renewable Energy Policy, the Internal Electricity Market and Economic Expertise. Zurich: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crampes, C., and Léautier, T.-O. (2021) White certificates and competition. Competition Law Review, 2021(1), 6674.Google Scholar
D’Adderio, L., and Pollock, N. (2014) Performing modularity: competing rules, performative struggles and the effect of organizational theories on the organization. Organization Studies, 35(12), 18131843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dales, J. H. (1968) Pollution, Property and Prices: An Essay in Policy-Making and Economics. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Davies, W. (2016) The Limits of Neoliberalism: Authority, Sovereignty and the Logic of Competition. London: SAGE.Google Scholar
Ehrenstein, V., and Muniesa, F. (2013) The conditional sink: counterfactual display in the valuation of a carbon offsetting reforestation project. Valuation Studies, 1(2), 161188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrenstein, V., and Neyland, D. (2021) Economic under-determination: industrial competitiveness and free allowances in the European carbon market. Journal of Cultural Economy, 14(5), 596611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, C., Ossandón, J., and Pallesen, T. (2019) The organization of markets for collective concerns and their failures. Economy and Society, 48(2), 153174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, J., and Kolstad, C. D. (2006) Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraudet, L.-G., and Finon, D. (2015) European experiences with white certificate obligations: a critical review of existing evaluations. Economics of Energy and Environmental Policy, 4(1), 113130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraudet, L.-G., Glachant, M., and Nicolaï, J.-P. (2020) Selling and saving energy: energy efficiency obligations in liberalized energy markets. The Energy Journal, 41(S), DOI: 10.5547/01956574.41.SI.1gir.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glachant, M., Kahn, V., and Lévêque, F. (2020) Une analyse économique et économétrique du dispositif des Certificats d’Economies d’Energie, research report. Paris: Mines ParisTech.Google Scholar
Halpern, C. (2010) Governing despite its instruments? Instrumentation in EU environmental policy. West European Politics, 33(1), 3957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heidbreder, E. G. (2013) European Union governance in the shadow of contradicting ideas: the decoupling of policy ideas and policy instruments. European Political Science Review, 5(1), 133150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holm, P., and Nielsen, K. N. (2007) Framing fish, making markets: the construction of Individual Transferable Quotas (ITQs). The Sociological Review, 55(2S), 173195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lascoumes, P., and Le Galès, P. (2007) Introduction: understanding public policy through its instruments – from the nature of instruments to the sociology of public policy instrumentation. Governance, 20(1), 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lauber, V., and Schenner, E. (2011) The struggle over support schemes for renewable electricity in the European Union: a discursive-institutionalist analysis. Environmental Politics, 20(4), 508527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, P., and Espeland, W. (2002) Pollution futures: commensuration, commodification, and the market for air, in Hoffman, A., and Ventresca, M. (eds.), Organizations, Policy, and the Natural Environment. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 119147.Google Scholar
Lohmann, L. (2008) Carbon trading, climate justice and the production of ignorance: ten examples. Development, 51(3), 359365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2003) An equation and its worlds: bricolage, exemplars, disunity and performativity in financial economics. Social Studies of Science, 33(6), 831868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2009) Making things the same: gases, emission rights and the politics of carbon markets. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 440455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.) (2007) Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mallard, A. (2020) Can energy savings certificates help in boiler scrappage programs? Exploring the market agencing of a detachment policy. Consumption Markets and Culture, 24(2), 115.Google Scholar
Meckling, J. (2011) Carbon Coalitions: Business, Climate Politics, and the Rise of Emissions Trading. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., and Rowan, B. (1977) Institutionalized organizations: formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, D. (2002) Turning Callon the right way up. Economy and Society, 31(2), 218233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P., and Nik-Khah, E. (2007) Markets made flesh: performativity, and a problem in science studies, augmented with a consideration of the FCC auctions, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L.-S. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 190224.Google Scholar
Montgomery, W. D. (1972) Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs. Journal of Economic Theory, 5(3), 395418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neyland, D., Ehrenstein, V., and Milyaeva, S. (2019) Can Markets Solve Problems? An Empirical Inquiry into Neoliberalism in Action. London: Goldsmiths Press.Google Scholar
Reverdy, T., and Breslau, D. (2019) Making an exception: market design and the politics of re-regulation in the French electricity sector. Economy and Society, 48(2), 197220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reverdy, T., Marty, F., and Bolton, R. (2021) The redesign of electricity markets under EU influence: the capacity mechanism in Britain and France, in Webb, J., Wade, F., and Tingey, M. (eds.), Research Handbook on Energy and Society. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 8396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rilinger, G. (2023) Conceptual limits of performativity: assessing the feasibility of market design blueprints. Socio-Economic Review, 21(2), 885908.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmalensee, R., Joskow, P. L., Ellerman, A. D., Montero, J. P., and Bailey, E. M. (1998) An interim evaluation of sulfur dioxide emissions trading. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(3), 5368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silvast, A. (2017) Energy, economics, and performativity: reviewing theoretical advances in social studies of markets and energy. Energy Research and Social Science, 34, 412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skjærseth, J. B., and Wettestad, J. (2010) Making the EU emissions trading system: the European Commission as an entrepreneurial epistemic leader. Global Environmental Change, 20(2), 314321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1971) The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 321.Google Scholar
Voss, J.-P. (2007) Innovation processes in governance: the development of ‘emissions trading’ as a new policy instrument. Science and Public Policy, 34(5), 329343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voss, J.-P., and Simons, A. (2014) Instrument constituencies and the supply side of policy innovation: the social life of emissions trading. Environmental Politics, 23(5), 735754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wettestad, J., and Jevnaker, T. (2019) Smokescreen politics? Ratcheting up EU emissions trading in 2017. Review of Policy Research, 36(5), 635659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodman, B., and Mitchell, C. (2011) Learning from experience? The development of the Renewables Obligation in England and Wales 2002–2010. Energy Policy, 39(7), 39143921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

References

ABSA (2023) Behavioural science teams. Available at www.behavioralscience.org/behavioral-science-teams (accessed 19 April 2024).Google Scholar
Araujo, L. (2007) Markets, market-making and marketing. Marketing Theory, 7(3), 221226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D. (2009) Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape Our Decisions. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Berg, N., and Gigerenzer, G. (2010) As-if behavioral economics: neoclassical economics in disguise? History of Economic Ideas, 18(1), 10001033.Google Scholar
Berndt, C. (2015) Behavioural economics, experimentalism and the marketization of development. Economy and Society, 44(4), 567591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldyrev, I., and Svetlova, E. (eds.) (2016) Enacting Dismal Science: New Perspectives on the Performativity of Economics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brisset, N., (2019) Economics and Performativity: Exploring Limits, Theories and Cases. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Cabantous, L., and Gond, J. P. (2011) Rational decision making as performative praxis: explaining rationality’s éternel retour. Organization Science, 22(3), 573586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cabinet Office (2011) Behavioural Insights Team: annual update 2010–11. London: Cabinet Office.Google Scholar
Çalışkan, K., and Callon, M. (2009) Economization, part 1: shifting attention from the economy towards processes of economization. Economy and Society, 38(3), 369398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Çalışkan, K., and Callon, M. (2010) Economization, part 2: a research programme for the study of markets. Economy and Society, 39(1), 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M. (1998a) The embeddedness of economic markets in economics, in Callon, M. (ed.), The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell, 158.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (ed.) (1998b) The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (2007) What does it mean to say that economics is performative?, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 311357.Google Scholar
Callon, M. (2008) Economic markets and the rise of interactive agencements: from prosthetic agencies to habilitated agencies, in Pinch, T., and Swedberg, R. (eds.), Living in a Material World: Economic Sociology Meets Science and Technology Studies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2956.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M., and Muniesa, F. (2005) Peripheral vision: economic markets as calculative collective devices. Organization Studies, 26(8), 12291250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F., and Loewenstein, G. (2004) Behavioral economics: past, present, future, in Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., and Rabin, M. (eds.), Advances in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carton, G. (2020) How assemblages change when theories become performative: the case of the Blue Ocean Strategy. Organization Studies, 41(10), 14171439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chataway, R. (2020) The Behaviour Business: How to Apply Behavioural Science for Business Success. Petersfield: Harriman House.Google Scholar
Chater, N. (2018) The Mind Is Flat: The Remarkable Shallowness of the Improvising Brain. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Cochoy, F. (2008) Calculation, qualculation, calqulation: shopping cart arithmetic, equipped cognition and the clustered consumer. Marketing Theory, 8(1), 1544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochoy, F., Trompette, P., and Araujo, L. (2016) From market agencements to market agencing: an introduction. Consumption Markets & Culture, 19(1), 316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. (1982) The normative basis of economic analysis: a critical review of Richard Posner’s The Economics of Justice. Stanford Law Review, 34(5), 11051131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D’Adderio, L., Glaser, V., and Pollock, N. (2019) Performing theories, transforming organizations: a reply to Marti and Gond. Academy of Management Review, 44(3), 676679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D’Adderio, L., and Pollock, N. (2014) Performing modularity: competing rules, performative struggles and the effect of organizational theories on the organization. Organization Studies, 35(12), 18131843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diacon, P. E., Donici, G.-A., and Maha, L. G. (2013) Perspectives of economics: behavioural economics. Theoretical and Applied Economics, 20(7), 2732.Google Scholar
Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J., and Sutton, R. I. (2005) Economic language and assumptions: how theories can become self-fulfilling. Academy of Management Review, 30(1), 824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fogg, B. (2020) Tiny Habits: The Small Changes that Change Everything. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Fourcade, M., and Healy, K. (2007) Moral views of market society. Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 285311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frerichs, S. (2011) False promises? A sociological critique of the behavioural turn in law and economics. Journal of Consumer Policy, 34(3), 289314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fridman, D. (2010) A new mentality for a new economy: performing the Homo economicus in Argentina (1976–83). Economy and Society, 39(2), 271302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. (1953) Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Garcia-Parpet, M.-F. (2007) The social construction of a perfect market: the strawberry auction at Fontaines-en-Sologne, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2053.Google Scholar
Ghoshal, S. (2005) Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 4(1), 7591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghoshal, S., and Moran, P. (1996) Bad for practice: a critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21(1), 1347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gond, J. P., Cabantous, L., Harding, N., and Learmonth, M. (2016) What do we mean by performativity in organizational and management theory? The uses and abuses of performativity. International Journal of Management Reviews, 18(4), 440463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gond, J. P., and Carton, G. (2022) The performativity of theories, in Neesham, C., Reihlen, M., and Schoeneborn, D. (eds.), Handbook of Philosophy of Management. Cham: Springer International, 159181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grüne-Yanoff, T. (2012) Old wine in new casks: libertarian paternalism still violates liberal principles. Social Choice and Welfare, 38(4), 635645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guala, F. (2001) Building economic machines: the FCC auctions. Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part A, 32(3), 453477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guala, F. (2007) How to do things with experimental economics, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 128162.Google Scholar
Guala, F. (2008) Experimental economics, history of, in Durlauf, S., and Blume, L. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, vol. 3. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 152156.Google Scholar
Güntner, A., Lucks, K., and Sperling-Magro, J. (2019) Lessons from the front line of corporate nudging. McKinsey Quarterly, 23 January.Google Scholar
Halpern, D. (2015) Inside the Nudge Unit: How Small Changes Can Make a Big Difference. London: Penguin Random House.Google Scholar
Hargreaves Heap, S. P. (2013) What is the meaning of behavioural economics? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37(5), 9851000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. M., and McPherson, M. S. (2008) The philosophical foundations of mainstream normative economics, in Hausman, D. M., (ed.), The Philosophy of Economics: An Anthology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 226250.Google Scholar
Heukelom, F. (2014) Behavioral Economics: A History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackson, S. E. (2010) Nudge your way to higher value. Journal of Business Strategy, 31(6), 4648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobi, E. S., Freund, J., and Araujo, L. (2015) ‘Is there a gap in the market, and is there a market in the gap?’ How advertising planning performs markets. Journal of Marketing Management, 31(1/2), 3761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, M. (1995) An essay on the normative foundations of antitrust economics. North Carolina Law Review, 74(1), 219266.Google Scholar
Johnson, E. J., and Goldstein, D. (2003) Do defaults save lives? Science, 302(5649), 13381339.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jones, R., Pykett, J., and Whitehead, M. (2013) Behaviour change policies in the UK: an anthropological perspective. Geoforum, 48, 3341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2011) Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1891) The Scope and Method of Political Economy. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kotler, P. (2020) Marketing is the original behavioral economics. Evonomics, 15 July. Available at https://evonomics.com/philip-kotler-marketing-is-the-original-behavioral-economics (accessed 19 May 2023).Google Scholar
Kuhn, T. S. (1962) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Langley, P., and Leaver, A. (2012) Remaking retirement investors: behavioural economics and defined-contribution occupational pensions. Journal of Cultural Economy, 5(4), 473488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, M. (2017) The Undoing Project: A Friendship that Changed Our Minds. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Ly, K., and Soman, D. (2013) Nudging around the world, research report. Toronto: Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2007) Is economics performative? Option theory and the construction of derivatives markets, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 5486.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2009) Material Markets: How Economic Agents Are Constructed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D., and Millo, Y. (2003) Constructing a market, performing theory: the historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 109(1), 107145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (2007a) Introduction, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 119.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.) (2007b) Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
McMahon, J. (2015) Behavioral economics as neoliberalism: producing and governing Homo economicus. Contemporary Political Theory, 14(2), 137158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marti, E., and Gond, J. P. (2018) When do theories become self-fulfilling? Exploring the boundary conditions of performativity. Academy of Management Review, 43(3), 487508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marti, E., and Gond, J. P. (2019) How do theories become self-fulfilling? Clarifying the process of Barnesian performativity. Academy of Management Review, 44(3), 686694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, K., Kjellberg, H., and Hagberg, J. (2015) Exploring the performativity of marketing: theories, practices and devices. Journal of Marketing Management, 31(1/2), 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michie, S., van Stralen, M. M., and West, R. (2011) The behaviour change wheel: a new method for characterising and designing behaviour change interventions. Implementation Science, 6, DOI: 10.1186/1748-5908-6-42.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mitchell, G. (2004) Libertarian paternalism is an oxymoron, Public Law Research Paper 136. Tallahassee, FL: Florida State University College of Law.Google Scholar
Mols, F., Haslam, S. A., Jetten, J., and Steffens, N. K. (2015) Why a nudge is not enough: a social identity critique of governance by stealth. European Journal of Political Research, 54(1), 8198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moscati, I. (2007) Early experiments in consumer demand theory: 1930–1970. History of Political Economy, 39(3), 359401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, F. (2014) The Provoked Economy: Economic Reality and the Performative Turn. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, F., and Callon, M. (2007) Economic experiments and the construction of markets, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 163189.Google Scholar
OECD (2017) Behavioural Insights and Public Policy: Lessons from around the World. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Ortmann, A. (2013) Episodes from the early history of experimentation in economics, Research Paper 2013-34. Sydney: School of Business, University of New South Wales.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellandini-Simányi, L. (2016) Non-marketizing agents in the study of markets: competing legacies of performativity and actor-network-theory in the marketization research program. Journal of Cultural Economy, 9(6), 570586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellandini-Simányi, L., and Conte, L. (2021) Consumer de-responsibilization: changing notions of consumer subjects and market moralities after the 2008–9 financial crisis. Consumption Markets & Culture, 24(3), 280305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polanyi, K. (1977) The economistic fallacy. Review (Fernand Braudel Center), 1(1), 918.Google Scholar
Quaglia, L. (2012) The ‘old’ and ‘new’ politics of financial services regulation in the European Union. New Political Economy, 17(4), 515535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rebonato, R. (2014) A critical assessment of libertarian paternalism. Journal of Consumer Policy, 37(3), 357396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. (2016) Economics Rules: The Rights and Wrongs of the Dismal Science. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Roth, A. E. (1993) The early history of experimental economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 15(2), 184209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sassatelli, R. (2001) Tamed hedonism: choice, desires and deviant pleasures, in Warde, A., and Gronow, J. (eds.), Ordinary Consumption. London: Routledge, 93106.Google Scholar
Schmidt, A. T., and Engelen, B. (2020) The ethics of nudging: an overview. Philosophy Compass, 15(4), DOI: 10.1111/phc3.12658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzkopf, S. (2018) Consumer-citizens: markets, marketing and the making of ‘choice’, in Kravets, O., Maclaran, P., Miles, S., and Venkatesh, A. (eds.), The SAGE Handbook of Consumer Culture. London: SAGE, 435452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selinger, E., and Whyte, K. (2011) Is there a right way to nudge? The practice and ethics of choice architecture. Sociology Compass, 5(10), 923935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shu, S. (2018) Example companies involved with behavioral economics. Steve Shu Consulting, 1 July. Available at https://steveshuconsulting.com/2018/07/companies-involved-behavioral-economics (accessed 19 May 2023).Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1990) Bounded rationality, in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P. (eds.), Utility and Probability. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 1518.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Singler, E. (2015) Nudge Marketing: Winning at Behavioral Change. Harlow: Pearson.Google Scholar
Slater, D. (1997) Consumer Culture and Modernity. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Slater, D., and Tonkiss, F. (2001) Market Society: Markets and Modern Social Theory. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Smith, N. C., Goldstein, D. G., and Johnson, E. J. (2013) Choice without awareness: ethical and policy implications of defaults. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 32(2), 159172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1976) Experimental economics: induced value theory. American Economic Review, 66(2), 274279.Google Scholar
Soman, D., and Yeung, C. (eds.) (2020) The Behaviorally Informed Organization. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R., and Thaler, R. H. (2003) Libertarian paternalism is not an oxymoron. University of Chicago Law Review, 70(4), 11591202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svorenčík, A., and Maas, H. (2016) The Making of Experimental Economics. Heidelberg: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2016a) Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2016b) Why most economists might as well be studying unicorns, interview by S. Vedantam. The Hidden Brain Podcast, 12 January. Available at www.wnyc.org/story/richard-thaler-why-most-economists-might-as-well-be-studying-unicorns (accessed 19 May 2023).Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., Sunstein, C. R., and Balz, J. P. (2013) Choice architecture, in Eldar, S., (ed.), The Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 428439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thurstone, L. L. (1931) The indifference function. Journal of Social Psychology, 2(2), 139167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tikotsky, A., Pè’er, E., and Feldman, Y. (2020) Which nudges do businesses like? Managers’ attitudes towards nudges directed at their business or at their customers. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 170, 4351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1974) Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 11241131.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1985) The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice, in Wright, G. (ed.), Behavioral Decision Making. Boston: Springer, 2541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valdés, J. G. (1995) Pinochet’s Economists: The Chicago School of Economics in Chile. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wendel, S. (2020) Who is doing applied behavioral science? Results from a global survey of behavioral teams. Behavioral Scientist, 5 October. Available at https://behavioralscientist.org/who-is-doing-applied-behavioral-science-results-from-a-global-survey-of-behavioral-teams (accessed 19 May 2023).Google Scholar
Weston, S. (1994) Toward a better understanding of the positive/normative distinction in economics. Economics & Philosophy, 10(1), 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, M. D. (2013) The Manipulation of Choice: Ethics and Libertarian Paternalism. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitehead, M., Jones, R., Howell, R., Lilley, R., and Pykett, J. (2014) Nudging all over the world: assessing the impacts of the behavioural sciences on public policy, Negotiating Neuroliberalism project report. London: ESRC.Google Scholar
Young, S. (2018) Behavioural economics, in Fischer, L., Hasell, J., Proctor, J. C., Uwakwe, D., Perkins, Z. W., and Watson, C. (eds.), Rethinking Economics: An Introduction to Pluralist Economics. Abingdon: Routledge, 7690.Google Scholar

References

Aspers, P. (2011) Markets. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Baehr, P. (2019) The Unmasking Style in Social Theory. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baudrillard, J. (1981) Simulacres et simulation. Paris: Galilée.Google Scholar
Bellman, R. (1958) Top management decision and simulation processes, talk given at the National Convention of the American Institute of Industrial Engineers, Los Angeles, 12 June.Google Scholar
Bellman, R., et al. (1957) On the construction of a multi-stage, multi-person business game. Operations Research, 5(4), 469503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blue Chip Journal (1987), 1(2).Google Scholar
Burns, J. (2019) How the invention of spreadsheet software unleashed Wall Street on the world. Gizmodo, 14 August. Available at https://gizmodo.com/how-the-invention-of-spreadsheet-software-unleashed-wal-1837177232.Google Scholar
Bush, R. F., and Carlson, M. S. (1988) Microcomputers in marketing education, in Bahn, K. (ed.), Developments in Marketing Science: Proceedings of the Academy of Marketing Science Annual Conference. Cham: Springer, 319323.Google Scholar
Çalışkan, K., and Callon, M. (2010) Economization, part 2: a research programme for the study of markets. Economy and Society, 39(1), 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M. (2021) Markets in the Making: Rethinking Competition, Goods and Innovation. New York: Zone Books.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M., and Roth, A. E. (2021) The design and performation of markets: a discussion. AMS Review, 11(3/4), 219239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
CIO Magazine (1999) Daniel S. Bricklin. 15 December, 140.Google Scholar
Cochoy, F. (2007) A sociology of market-things: on tending the garden of choices in mass retailing, in Callon, M., Millo, Y., and Munesia, F. (eds.), Market Devices. Oxford: Blackwell, 109129.Google Scholar
Cochoy, F., and Hagberg, J. (2016) Win, earn, gain: gamification in the history of retailing, in Dymek, M., and Zackariasson, P. (eds.), The Business of Gamification: A Critical Analysis. Abingdon: Routledge, 8198.Google Scholar
Coombs, N. (2022) Narrating imagined crises: how central bank storytelling exerts infrastructural power. Economy and Society, 51(4), 679702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunningham, J., and Curtis, H. (2020) Noise as information: finance economics as second-order observation. Theory, Culture & Society, 37(5), 5174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, W. (2020) Post-liberal competitions? Pragmatics of gamification and weaponization, in Stark, D. (ed.), The Performance Complex: Competition and Competitions in Social Life. New York: Oxford University Press, 187208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deringer, W. (2020) Michael Milken’s spreadsheets: computation and charisma in finance in the go-go ’80s. IEEE Annals of the History of Computing, 42(3), 5369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Espeland, W., and Sauder, M. (2007) Rankings and reactivity: how public measures recreate social worlds. American Journal of Sociology, 113(1), 140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esposito, E. (2011) The Future of Futures: The Time of Money in Financing and Society. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faria, A. J. (2001) The changing nature of business simulation/gaming research: a brief history. Simulation & Gaming, 32(1), 97110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faria, A. J., and Schumacher, M. (1984) The use of decision simulations in management training programs: current perspectives. Developments in Business Simulation & Experiential Exercises, 11, 228231.Google Scholar
Feldman, S. (1985) Fun and games in the corporation. Macworld, August, 144–147.Google Scholar
Fleck, J. (1988) Innofusion or diffusation? The nature of technological developments in robotics, Programme on Information and Communication Technologies Working Paper 4. Edinburgh: Research Centre for Social Sciences, University of Edinburgh.Google Scholar
Greenlaw, P., Frey, W., and Vernon, I. (1979) Finansim: A Management Simulation, 2nd ed. St Paul, MN: West Publishing.Google Scholar
Hamilton, R. (1986) Dan Bricklin Demo speeds prototyping via simulation. Computerworld, 20(7 April), 33, 36.Google Scholar
Hines, T. F. (1985) Hey, big spender! MacUser, November, 84–88, 153.Google Scholar
Ingleby, E. (2021) Neoliberalism, secondary and tertiary education, in Neoliberalism across Education: Policy and Practice from Early Childhood through Adult Learning. Cham: Springer, 5371.Google Scholar
Jagoda, P. (2020) Playing through a serious crisis: on the neoliberal art of video games. Post45, 31 August. Available at https://post45.org/2020/08/playing-through-a-serious-crisis-on-the-neoliberal-art-of-video-games.Google Scholar
Khurana, R. (2007) From Higher Aims to Hired Hands: The Social Transformation of American Business Schools and the Unfulfilled Promise of Management as a Profession. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kibbee, J. M., Craft, C. J., and Nanus, B. (1961) Management Games. New York: Reinhold.Google Scholar
Komporozos-Athanasiou, A. (2022) Speculative Communities: Living with Uncertainty in a Financialized World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotler, P., and Schultz, R. L. (1970) Marketing simulations: review and prospects. Journal of Business, 43(3), 237295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luhmann, N. (1994) Die Wirtschaft der Gesellschaft. Frankfurt: Suhrkamp.Google Scholar
Luhmann, N. (2002) Risk: A Sociological Theory. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mace, S. (1986) Business simulations graduate into the real world. InfoWorld, 17 February, 37–38.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2006) An Engine, Not a Camera: How Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McRaith, J. R., and Goeldner, C. R. (1962) A survey of marketing games. Journal of Marketing, 26(3), 6972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markulis, P., and Strang, D. (1985) The use of decision support systems (DSS) and operations management science (OR/MS) techniques to enhance the learning experience of students participating in computerized simulations. Developments in Business Simulations & Experiential Exercises, 12, 3034.Google Scholar
Martin, E. W. (1959) Teaching executives via simulation. Business Horizons, 2(2), 100109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millionaire (1983) PC Magazine, June, 207.Google Scholar
Morgenroth, W., and Sims, J. T. (1974) Simulations: methods and applications, in Ferber, R. (ed.), Handbook of Marketing Research. New York: McGraw Hill, 2-5182-546.Google Scholar
Muniesa, F. (2014) The Provoked Economy: Economic Reality and the Performative Turn. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, F. (2020) Business education and anxiety in the performance of value, in Stark, D. (ed.), The Performance Complex: Competition and Competitions in Social Life. New York: Oxford University Press, 260269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, F., and Callon, M. (2007) Economic experiments and the construction of markets, in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., and Siu, L. (eds.), Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 163189.Google Scholar
Murphy, D. T. (2016) Struggling with simulations: decoding the neoliberal politics of digital games. PhD thesis, Ryerson University, Toronto.Google Scholar
Newbery, R., Lean, J., Moizer, J., and Haddoud, M. (2018) Entrepreneurial identity formation during the initial entrepreneurial experience: the influence of simulation feedback and existing identity. Journal of Business Research, 85, 5159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osteryoung, J. S., McCarthy, D. E., and McDaniel, W. R. (1983) The use of VisiCalc in the teaching of corporate finance. Journal of Financial Education, 12, 8291.Google Scholar
Perec, G. (1989) L’Infra-ordinaire. Paris: Éditions du Seuil.Google Scholar
Reality Development Corp. (1986) What they do teach you at Wharton Business School. InfoWorld, 17 February, 43.Google Scholar
Ricciardi, F. M., et al. (1957) Top Management Decision Simulation: The AMA Approach. New York: American Management Association.Google Scholar
Rilinger, G. (2023) Conceptual limits of performativity: assessing the feasibility of market design blueprints. Socio-Economic Review, 21(2), 885908.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosen, R. (2012) Anticipatory Systems. New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzkopf, S. (2019) Magic towns: creating the consumer fetish in market research test sites, in Bajde, D., Kjeldgaard, D., and Belk, R. W. (eds.), Consumer Culture Theory. Bingley: Emerald Publishing, 121135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seyfert, R. (2016) Bugs, predations or manipulations? Incompatible epistemic regimes of high-frequency trading. Economy and Society, 45(2), 251277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Small ads (1983) PC Magazine, March, 527.Google Scholar
Stanger, K. (1986) Dan Bricklin’s Demo program. College & Research Libraries News, 47(9), 582585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinbrink, J. E., and Helmer, J. W. (2004) Intervention: simulating the war on global terrorism, Journal of Geography, 103(6), 239247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Švelch, J. (2022) Normalizing player surveillance through video game infographics. New Media & Society, DOI: 10.1177/14614448221097889.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Touzet, L., and Corbeil, P. (2015) Vital Roux, forgotten forerunner of modern business games. Simulation & Gaming, 46(1), 1939.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walkenbach, J. (1986) Dan Bricklin crafts a Demo program. Infoworld, 31 March, 41–43.Google Scholar
Wolfe, J. (1993) A history of business teaching games in English-speaking and post-socialist countries: the origination and diffusion of a management education and development technology. Simulation & Gaming, 24(4), 446463CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaloom, C. (2006) Out of the Pits: Traders and Technology from Chicago to London. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×