Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T01:18:43.116Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 March 2023

Randall G. Holcombe
Affiliation:
Florida State University
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Following Their Leaders
Political Preferences and Public Policy
, pp. 199 - 208
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies, and the Fate of Liberty. New York: Penguin Press, 2019.Google Scholar
Achen, Christopher H., and Bartels, Larry M.. Democracy for Realists: Why Elections Do Not Produce Responsive Government. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2016.Google Scholar
Ackerlof, Robert. “‘We Thinking’ and Its Consequences.” American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 415419.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Kranton, Rachel E.. “Economics and Identity.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, no. 3 (August 2000): 715753.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A.Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory.” Journal of Political Economy 58, no. 3 (June 1950): 211221.Google Scholar
Anderson, Terry L., and Hill, P. J.. The Birth of a Transfer Society. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, and Socorro Puy, M.. “Identity Voting.” Public Choice 169, nos. 1/2 (October 2016): 7795.Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah. The Origins of Totalitarianism. Cleveland, OH: World Publishing, 1958.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J.General Economic Equilibrium: Purpose, Analytic Techniques, Collective Choice.” American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 253272.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. Social Choice and Individual Values, 2nd ed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., and Debreu, Gerard. “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.” Econometrica 27, no. 3 (1954): 265290.Google Scholar
Bailyn, Bernard. The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Barber, Michael, and Pope, Jeremy C.. “Does Party Trump Ideology? Disentangling Party and Ideology in America.” American Political Science Review 113, no. 1 (2019): 3854.Google Scholar
Bator, Francis M.The Simple Analytics of Welfare Maximization.” American Economic Review 47, no. 1 (March 1957): 2259.Google Scholar
Bator, Francis M.The Anatomy of Market Failure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 72, no. 3 (August 1958): 351379.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. Entrepreneurship, Management, and the Structure of Payoffs. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J.Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive.” Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 5, Part 1 (October 1990): 893921.Google Scholar
Beasley, Ryan K., and Joslyn, Mark R.. “Cognitive Dissonance and Post-Decision Attitude Change in Six Presidential Elections.” Political Psychology 22, no. 3 (September 2001): 521540.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S., “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, no. 3 (1983): 371400.Google Scholar
Benabou, Roland, and Tirole, Jean. “Identity, Morals and Taboos: Beliefs as Assets.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, no. 2 (2011): 805855.Google Scholar
Benabou, Roland, and Tirole, Jean. “Mindful Economics: The Production, Consumption, and Value of Beliefs.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 30, no. 3 (Summer 2016): 141164.Google Scholar
Bernheim, Douglas, Braghieri, Luca, Martinez-Marquina, Alejandro, and Zuckerman, David. “A Theory of Chosen Preferences.” American Economic Review 111, no. 2 (February 2021): 720754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Billings, Stephen B., Chyn, Eric, and Haggag, Kareem. “The Long-Run Effects of School Racial Diversity on Political Identity.” American Economic Review Insights 3, no. 3 (September 2021): 267284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, Douglas, Braghieri, Luca, Martinez-Marquina, Alejandro, and Zuckerman, David. “A Theory of Chosen Preferences.” American Economic Review 111, no. 2 (February 2021): 720754.Google Scholar
Black, Dunan. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1958.Google Scholar
Boleslavsky, Raphael, and Cotton, Christopher. “Information and Extremism in Elections.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 7, no. 1 (February 2015): 165207.Google Scholar
Bowen, Howard R.The Interpretation of Voting in the Allocation of Economic Resources.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 58, no. 1 (November 1943): 2748.Google Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Buchanan, James M.. The Reason of Rules: Constitutional Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Hamlin, Alan. “Expressive Voting and Electoral Equilibrium.” Public Choice 95, nos. 1/2 (April 1998): 149175.Google Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Hamlin, Alan. “A Revisionist View of the Separation of Powers.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 6, no. 3 (1994): 345368.Google Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Lomasky, Loren. Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.Afraid to Be Free: Dependency as Desideratum.” Public Choice 124, nos. 1/2 (July 2005): 1931.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.Individual Choice in Voting and the Market.” Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 4 (August 1954): 334343.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. The Logical Foundations of Constitutional Liberty. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1999.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.Public Choice: Politics without Romance.” Policy 19, no. 3 (Spring 2003): 1318.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.Public Finance and Public Choice.” National Tax Journal 28, no. 4 (December 1975): 383394.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.The Relevance of Pareto Optimality.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 6, no. 4 (December 1962): 341354.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.What Should Economists Do?Southern Economic Journal 30, no. 3 (January 1964): 213222.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, Gordon. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Bursztyn, Leonardo, Egorov, Georgy, and Fiorin, Stefano. “From Extreme to Mainstream: The Erosion of Social Norms.” American Economic Review 110, no. 11 (November 2020): 35223548.Google Scholar
Campbell, Angus, Converse, Philip E., Miller, Warren E., and Stokes, Donald F., The American Voter. New York: John Wiley, 1960.Google Scholar
Cameron, Charles M. Veto Bargaining: Presidents and the Politics of Negative Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Camon, Ziv, and Ariely, Dan. “Focusing on the Forgone: How Value Can Appear So Different to Buyers and Sellers.” Journal of Consumer Research 23, no. 3 (December 2000): 360370.Google Scholar
Cantoni, Enrico, and Pons, Vincent. “Does Context Outweigh Individual Characteristics in Driving Voting Behavior? Evidence from Relocations within the United States.” American Economic Review 112, no. 4 (April 2022): 12261272.Google Scholar
Caplan, Bryan. The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Carvalho, Jean-Paul.Identity-Based Organizations.” American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 410414.Google Scholar
Chakraborty, Archman, Ghosh, Parikshit, and Roy, Jaideep. “Expert-Captured Democracies.” American Economic Review 110, no. 6 (June 2020): 17131751.Google Scholar
Chen, Stephanie, and Urminsky, Oleg. “The Role of Causal Beliefs in Political Identity and Voting.” Cognition 188, no. 1 (July 2019): 2738.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law & Economics, 3 (1960): 1–44.Google Scholar
Cohen, Geoffrey L.Party over Policy: The Dominating Impact of Group Influence over Political Beliefs.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 85, no. 5 (2003): 808822.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Conover, Pamela Johnston. “The Influence of Group Identifications on Political Perception and Evaluation.” Journal of Politics 46, no. 3 (August 1984): 760785.Google Scholar
Coyne, Christopher J., and Hall, Abigail R.. Manufacturing Militarism: U.S. Government Propaganda in the War on Terror. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2021.Google Scholar
Coyne, Christopher J., and Hall, Abigail R.. Tryanny Comes Home: The Domestic Fate of U.S. Militarism. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Delgado, Richard, and Stefancic, Jean. Critical Race Theory: An Introduction, 2nd ed. New York: New York University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
Diamond, Jared. The World Until Yesterday: What Can We Learn from Traditional Societies? New York: Viking, 2012.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row, 1957.Google Scholar
Edelman, Murray, The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1964.Google Scholar
Elender, Mikael. “Correcting Mistakes: Cognitive Dissonance and Political Attitudes in Sweden and the United States.” Public Choice 153, nos. 1/2 (October 2012): 235249.Google Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Hinich, Melvin J.. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Engelen, Bart. “Solving the Paradox: The Expressive Rationality of the Decision to Vote.” Rationality and Society 18, no. 4 (2006): 419441.Google Scholar
Eubanks, Austin D., Eidelman, Scott, Till, Derrick F., Sparkman, David, Stewart, Patrick, and Wicks, Robert H.. “Outcome-Based Dissonance and Morton’s Fork: Evaluative Consequences of Unfavorable Alternatives in the 2016 U.S. Presidential Election.” Journal of Theoretical Social Psychology 4, no. 1 (January 2020): 2131.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy J., and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang. “The Swing Voter’s Curse.” American Economic Review 86, no. 3 (June 1996): 408424.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P.Further Evidence on the Partisan Consequences of Legislative Professionalism.” American Journal of Political Science 43, no. 3 (1989): 974977Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Folsom, Burton W., Jr. The Myth of the Robber Barons. Reston, VA: Young America’s Foundation, 1991.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. Choosing the Right Pond: Human Behavior and the Quest for Status. New York: Oxford University Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. Luxury Fever: Weighing the Cost of Excess. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis. The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Free Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Gal, David. “A Psychological Law of Inertia and the Illusion of Loss Aversion.” Judgment and Decision Making 1, no. 1 (July 2006): 2332.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1952.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. The Anatomy of Power. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1983.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. “Political Ignorance and Collective Policy Preferences.” American Political Science Review 95, no. 2 (June 2001): 379396.Google Scholar
Gino, Francesca, Norton, Michael I., and Weber, Roberto A.. “Motivated Bayesians: Feeling Moral while Acting Egotistically.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 30, no. 3 (Summer 2016): 189212.Google Scholar
Golman, Russell, Loewenstein, George, Ove, KarlMoene, , and Zarri, Luca. “The Preference for Belief Consonance.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 30, no. 3 (Summer 2016): 165188.Google Scholar
Gordon, Thomas, and Trenchard, John. Essays on Liberty, Civil and Religious, and Other Important Subjects, Hamowy, Ronald, ed. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1995.Google Scholar
Graaf, J. de V. Theoretical Welfare Economics. London: Cambridge University Press, 1957.Google Scholar
Hamlin, Alan, and Jennings, Colin. “Expressive Political Behaviour: Foundations, Scope, and Implications.” British Journal of Political Science 41, no. 3 (July 2011): 645670.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A.The Non-Sequitur of the ‘Dependence Effect.’Southern Economic Journal 27, no. 4 (April 1961): 346348.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. The Road to Serfdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1944.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1939.Google Scholar
Higgs, Robert. Depression, War, and Cold War: Challenging the Myths of Conflict and Prosperity. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute, 2006.Google Scholar
Higgs, Robert. Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Hillman, Arye L.Expressive Behavior in Economics and Politics.” European Journal of Political Economy 26, no. 4 (December 2010): 403418.Google Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas. Leviathan. New York: E.P. Dutton, 1950 [orig. 1651].Google Scholar
Hochman, Harold M., and Rodgers, James D.. “Pareto Optimal Redistribution.” American Economic Review 59, no. 4, Part 1 (September 1969): 542557.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. Advanced Introduction to Public Choice. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2016.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G.Contractarian Ideology and the Legitimacy of Government.” Journal of Institutional Economics 17, no. 3 (June 2021): 379391.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. Coordination, Cooperation, and Control: The Evolution of Economic and Political Power. London: Palgrave-Macmillan, 2021.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. An Economic Analysis of Democracy. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. Liberty in Peril: Democracy and Power in American History. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute, 2019.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. Political Capitalism: How Economic and Political Power Is Made and Maintained. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G.Political Incentives for Rent Creation.” Constitutional Political Economy 28, no. 1 (March 2017): 6278.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G.Populism: Promises and Problems.” The Independent Review 26, no. 1 (Summer 2021): 2737.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G.Principles and Politics: Like Oil and Water.” Review of Austrian Economics 22, no. 2 (June 2009): 151157.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., and Gmeiner, Robert J.. “Interest Group Support for Non-Group Issues.” Constitutional Political Economy 29, no. 3 (September 2018): 303316.Google Scholar
Ikeda, Sanford, Dynamics of the Mixed Economy: Toward a Theory of Interventionism. London: Routledge, 1997.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L., and Thaler, Richard H.. “Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem.” Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 6 (December 1990): 13251348.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L., and Thaler, Richard H.. “Anomalies: The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 1 (Winter 1991): 193206.Google Scholar
Kagel, John H., Battalio, Raymond C., Rachlin, Howared, Green, Leonard, Basmann, Robert L., and Klem, W. R.. “Experimental Studies of Consumer Demand Behavior Using Laboratory Animals.” Economic Inquiry 13, no. 1 (March 1975): 2238.Google Scholar
Kartik, Navin, Kleiner, Andreas, and Van Weelden, Richard. “Delegation in Veto Bargaining.” American Economic Review 111, no. 12 (December 2021): 40464087.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. The Economic Consequences of the Peace. New York: Harcourt Brace and Howe, 1920.Google Scholar
Klein, Dominik. “Expressive Voting, Graded Interests, and Participation.” Public Choice 188, nos. 1/2 (July 2021): 221239Google Scholar
Kmec, Keenan D.The Origin and Current Meanings of ‘Judicial Activism.’California Law Review 92, no. 5 (October 2004): 14411477.Google Scholar
Kohn, Meir, “Value and Exchange.” Cato Journal 24, no. 3 (Fall 2004): 303339.Google Scholar
Kolko, Gabriel. Railroads and Regulation, 1877–1916. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Kolko, Gabriel. The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History, 1900–1916. New York: The Free Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E.Identity Economics 2016: Where Do Social Norms Come From?American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 405409.Google Scholar
Krueger, Anne O., “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 291303.Google Scholar
Larcinese, Valentino. “Does Political Knowledge Increase Turnout? Evidence from the 1997 British General Election.” Public Choice 131, nos. 3/4 (June 2007): 387411.Google Scholar
Layman, Geoffrey C., Carsey, Thomas M., Green, John C., Herrera, Richard, and Cooperman, Rosalyn. “Activists and Conflict Extension in American Party Politics.” American Political Science Review 104, no. 2 (May 2010): 324346.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter T, “Better Off Stateless: Somalia before and after Government Collapse,” Journal of Comparative Economics 35, no. 4 (2007): 689710.Google Scholar
Lenz, Gabriel L. Follow the Leader? How Voters Respond to Politicians’ Policies and Performance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2012.Google Scholar
Levine, David K., and Mattozzi, Andrea. “Voter Turnout with Peer Punishment.” American Economic Review 110, no. 10 (October 2020): 32983314.Google Scholar
Lindsay, James, and Pluckrose, Helen. Cynical Theories: How Activist Scholarship Made Everything about Race, Gender, and Identity. Durham, NC: Pluckstone Publishing, 2020.Google Scholar
Locke, John. Two Treatises of Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960 [orig. 1690].Google Scholar
Marx, Karl, and Engels, Friedrich. The Communist Manifesto. New York: International Publishers, 1948.Google Scholar
Maslow, Abraham H.A Theory of Human Motivation.” Psychological Review 50, no. 4 (July 1943): 370396.Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred S.Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Legal Studies 16, no. 1 (January 1987): 101118.Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred S. Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1997.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R.D.Intransitivities in Multi-Dimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control.” Journal of Economic Theory 12, no. 3 (June 1976): 472482.Google Scholar
McMurray, Joseph. “Ideology as Opinion: A Spatial Model of Common-Value Elections.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 9, no. 4 (November 2017): 108140.Google Scholar
McMurray, Joseph. “The Paradox of Information and Voter Turnout.” Public Choice 165, nos. 1/2 (2015): 1323.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G.The Coase Theorem at Sixty.” Journal of Economic Literature 58, no. 4 (December 2020): 10451128.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. On Liberty, People’s Edition. London: Longmans, Green, and Co., 1913.Google Scholar
Mills, C. Wright. The Power Elite. New York: Oxford University Press, 1959.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. Interventionism: An Economic Analysis. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2011.Google Scholar
Mullainathan, Sendhil, and Washington, Ebonya. “Sticking with Your Vote: Cognitive Dissonance and Political Attitudes.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1, no. 1 (2009): 86–111.Google Scholar
Murray, Charles. Losing Ground: American Social Policy, 1950–1980. New York: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Niskenen, William A. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1971.Google Scholar
Nordnaus, William D.The Political Business Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies 42, no. 2 (April 1975): 169190.Google Scholar
Nyhan, Brendan. “Facts and Myths about Misperceptions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 34, no. 3 (Summer 2020): 220236.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur, Jr. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur, Jr. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Ortoleva, Pietro, and Snowberg, Erik. “Overconfidence in Political Behavior.” American Economic Review 105, no. 2 (February 2015): 504535.Google Scholar
Packard, Vance. The Hidden Persuaders. London: Longmans, Green and Co., 1957.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. The Mind and Society: A Treatise on General Sociology. New York: Dover Publications, 1963.Google Scholar
Peacock, Alan T., and Wiseman, Jack. The Growth of Public Expenditures in the United Kingdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1961.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven. The Better Angels of Our Nature: Why Violence Has Declined. New York: Viking, 2011.Google Scholar
Podhoretz, Norman. Why Are Jews Liberals? New York: Doubleday, 2009.Google Scholar
Riker, William H.Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of Institutions.” American Political Science Review 74, no. 2 (June 1980): 432446.Google Scholar
Robbett, , Andrea, , and Matthews, Peter Hans. “Partisan Bias and Expressive Voting.” Journal of Public Economics 157, no. 1 (January 2018): 107120.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. The Nature and Significance of Economic Science. London: Macmillan, 1932.Google Scholar
Rolf, Meredeth. Voter Turnout: A Social Theory of Political Participation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosethal, Howard. “Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo.” Public Choice 33, no. 4 (1978): 2743.Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray N. The Ethics of Liberty. Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray N. The Progressive Era. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2017.Google Scholar
Rothstein, Bo. “Epistemic Democracy and the Quality of Government.” European Politics and Society 20, no. 1 (2019): 1631.Google Scholar
Rousseau, Jean Jacques. The Social Contract, or Principles of Political Right. Translated by G. D. H. Cole. www.constitution.org/jr/socon.htm. 1762.Google Scholar
Russell, Bertrand. “What Desires Are Politically Important?” Nobel Lecture, December 11, 1950, found at www.nobelprize.org/prizes/literature/1950/russell/lecture.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1947.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A.A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumer’s Behavior.” Economica n.s. 5, no. 17 (February 1938): 6171.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. “Instability of Simple Dynamic Games.” Review of Economic Studies 45, no. 3 (October 1978): 575594.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A., Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, 2nd ed. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1947.Google Scholar
Schlesinger, Arthur M., Jr., “The Supreme Court, 1947.” Fortune (January 1947): 202208.Google Scholar
Schweizer, Peter. Extortion: How Politicians Extract Your Money, Buy Votes, and Line Their Own Pockets. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 2013.Google Scholar
Shayo, Moses. “A Model of Social Identity with an Application to Political Economy: Nation, Class, and Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 103, no. 2 (May 2009): 147174.Google Scholar
Sinclair, Upton. The Jungle. New York: Doubleday, Page, & Co., 1906.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library, 1937 [orig. 1776].Google Scholar
Snower, Dennis J., and Bosworth, Steven J.. “Identity-Driven Cooperation versus Competition.” American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 420424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobel, Russell S.Testing Baumol: Institutional Quality and the Productivity of Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Business Venturing 23, no. 6 (November 2008): 641655.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J.The Theory of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2, no. 1 (Spring 1971): 3–21.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., and Becker, Gary S.. “De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum.” American Economic Review 67, no. 2 (March 1977): 7690.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers the Future. New York: W.W. Norton, 2012.Google Scholar
Tideman, Nicolaus. Collective Decisions and Voting: The Potential for Public Choice. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate Publishing, 2006.Google Scholar
Tideman, , Nicolaus, T., and Gordon, Tullock.A New and Superior Process for Making Social Choices.” Journal of Political Economy 84, no. 6 (December 1976): 11451159.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. “Veto Players and Institutional Analysis.” Governance: An International Journal of Policy and Administration 13, no. 4 (October 2000): 441474.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. “The Charity of the Uncharitable.” Western Economic Journal 9, no. 4 (December 1971): 379392.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, “The Welfare Cost of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft,” Western Economic Journal 5, no. 3 (June 1967): 224232.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. “Why So Much Stability?Public Choice 37, no. 2 (1982): 189202.Google Scholar
Tyran, Jean-Rovert, and Wagner, Alexander K.. “Experimental Evidence on Expressive Voting,” Oxford Handbook of Public Choice, vol. 2. Congleton, Roger D., Grofman, Bernard N., and Voigt, Stefan, eds. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2019, ch. 45, 928–940.Google Scholar
van Bavel, Jay J., and Pereira, Andrea. “The Partisan Brain: An Identity-Based Model of Political Belief.” Trends in Cognitive Psychology 22, no. 3 (March 2018): 213224.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: Macmillan, 1899.Google Scholar
Wagner, Richard E. Politics as a Peculiar Business: Public Choice in a System of Entangled Political Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2016.Google Scholar
Wang, Tianyi. “Media, Pulpit, and Populist Persuasion: Evidence from Father Coughlin.” American Economic Review 111, no. 9 (September 2021): 30643092.Google Scholar
White, Richard. Railroaded: The Transcontinentals and the Making of Modern America. New York: W.W. Norton, 2011.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. “A Comparison of Alternative Approaches to Economic Methodology.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146, no. 1 (1990): 6171.Google Scholar
Wilson, Woodrow. The State. Boston: D.C. Heath & Company 1889.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. The Myth of Democratic Failure. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97, no. 6 (1989): 13951424.Google Scholar
Yandle, Bruce. “Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory Economist.” Regulation 7, no. 3 (May–June 1983): 1216.Google Scholar
Yeager, Leland B. Ethics as a Social Science: The Moral Philosophy of Social Cooperation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2001.Google Scholar
Yeager, Leland B.Rights, Contract, and Utility in Policy Espousal.” Cato Journal 5, no. 1 (Summer 1985): 259294.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×