Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T00:36:56.804Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - Advance of Total Factor Productivity from Entrepreneurial Innovations

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Paul A. Samuelson
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Zoltan J. Acs
Affiliation:
George Mason School of Public Policy, Fairfax
David B. Audretsch
Affiliation:
Indiana University, Bloomington
Robert J. Strom
Affiliation:
Kauffman Foundation, Kansas City
Get access

Summary

Joseph Schumpeter (1883–1950), my Harvard mentor, won early fame for his 1911 Theory of Economic Development. However, during the fifteen years I was his Cambridge neighbor, it was Maynard Keynes (1883–1946) who, by general agreement, earned the reputation of being the greatest economist of the twentieth century. The primary reason for this was that the great global depression of 1929–1935 desperately needed a new macro paradigm like Keynes's 1936 General Theory.

I believe there was a grain of truth in the innuendo that Schumpeter experienced some scholarly jealousy of Keynes's celebrity. Like the entrepreneurs he praised, Schumpeter possessed a competitive personality. Because the Muse of History has an ironic sense of humor, now in the twenty-first century, Schumpeter's fame (and his citation frequency) exceeds anything he enjoyed during his lifetime, including my colleagues here who cite him authoritatively in their explorations of entrepreneurship.

It would be useful for the few surviving members of the Schumpeter Circle to record the evolutionary nuances of change in Schumpeter's own late-in-life thinking. For example, when first in September 1935 I entered his Harvard Yard graduate classroom, Schumpeter was still stressing youthful innovators. He then seemed to doubt that a General Electric or a Bell System Laboratory could succeed in staying at the frontier of technical and know-how discovery. But later, contemporary economic history converted him to the view that the great oligopolies of the Fortune 500 corporations deserved most credit for progress in mid-twentieth-century total factor productivity.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Douglas, Paul H. 1934. The Theory of Wages. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Heckscher, Eli. 1919. “Effects of Foreign Trade on Distribution of Income.”Ekonomisk Tidskrift. Reprinted in Ellis, H. S. and Metzler, L., eds., Readings in the Theory of International Trade. Philadelphia: Blakiston, 1949.Google Scholar
Jevons, William S. 1865. The Coal Question. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. 1936. “The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.” Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 7. London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus. 1991. Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development: A Long-Run Comparative View. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus. 2003. The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malthus, Thomas R. 1789. An Essay on the Principle of Population. Reprint. London: Macmillan, 1926.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl H., and Engels, Friedrich. 1848. Manifest der Kommunistischen Partei. Translated into English as Manifesto of the Communist Party. New York: International Publishers, 1948.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1848. Principles of Political Economy, with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy. London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
Ohlin, Bertil G. 1933. Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1949. “International Factor-Price Equalization Once Again.” Economic Journal, 59, 181–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., and Nordhaus, William D.. 1995. Economics, 18th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1943 (1911). The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Cannan, E., ed. New York: Modern Library, 1937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1957. “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function.” Review of Economic Statistics, 39, 312–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×