Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-05T02:20:18.346Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false
This chapter is part of a book that is no longer available to purchase from Cambridge Core

4 - Political economy: the science of the state and the market

Dorinda Outram
Affiliation:
University of Rochester, New York
Get access

Summary

Political economy, the science of production, buying and selling and their relationship with law, custom and government, and thus connected to the changes in government which we examined in the last chapter, was largely elaborated in the Enlightenment. The term was first used in French in Antoine de Montchrétien's 1615 Traîté de l’économie politique. It was not replaced by the term ‘economics’ in English until the 1890s. Many seventeenth-century writers worked in this field but it was in the Enlightenment that the subject came together far more strongly as a consistent academic discipline. It was formed by the confluence of several contemporary sciences of the economy in its relationship to government, such as Cameralism, physiocracy and mercantilism. It was also influenced by views of the political economy of distant civilisations, such as China. University chairs in political economy appear for the first time in the eighteenth century, the first being at Naples, held by Antonio Genovesi; in 1763 one was founded in Vienna, held by the Cameralist statesman Joseph von Sonnenfels, in 1769 for Beccaria in Milan, and in 1782 for Paradisi, the theorist of Italian decline, at Modena. The field acquired a formalised mathematical language in the work of Pietro Verri in Milan, who argued for the status of political economy as a science wedded to objective laws. Other conceptual advances in political economy also marked the Enlightenment: in France, the Physiocrat school of political economy developed macro-economic models for the first time, in François Quesnay's 1758 Tableau économique, while the Scots thinker Adam Smith developed the first full-scale description of mercantilism in an industrialising society.

Type
Chapter
Information
The Enlightenment , pp. 43 - 53
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Reinert, Sophus A., ‘Lessons on the Rise and Fall of Great Powers: Conquest, Commerce and Decline in Eighteenth-Century Italy’, American Historical Review, 115 (2010), 1395–1425Google Scholar
Wahnbaeck, Till, Luxury and Public Happiness: Political Economy in the Italian Enlightenment (Oxford, 2004), 176
Kaplan, Steven L., Bread, Politics and Political Economy in the Reign of Louis XV (2 vols, The Hague, 1976), II, 677–82
Weulersse, Georges, La physiocratie à l'aube de la Révolution, 1781–1792 (Paris, 1985)
Weulersse, La physiocratie sous les ministères de Turgot et de Necker, 1774–1781 (Paris, 1950)
Wahnbaeck, Luxury and Public Happiness, 98–184; Mario Mirri, La lotta politica in Toscana intorno alle ‘riforme annonarie’: 1764–1775 (Pisa, 1972)
Lisbet Koerner, Linnaeus: Nature and Nation (Cambridge, MA, 1999)
Smith, Adam, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Books IV–V, ed. Andrew Skinner (London, 1999), xxxix
Mokyr, Joel, The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain, 1700–1850 (New Haven, CT, 2009)
Sutherland, Kathryn, ‘The New Economics of the Enlightenment’, in The Enlightenment World, ed. Martin Fitzpatrick, Peter Jones, Christa Knellwolf and Iain McCalman (London, 2004), 473–85; 478
Lectures on Jurisprudence (1766), 527
Smith, Adam, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. R. H. Campbell, A. S. Skinner and W. B. Todd (Oxford, 1976), I, 412
Rothschild, Emma, Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet and the Enlightenment (Cambridge, MA, 2001)
Hirschman, Albert O., The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph (Princeton, NJ, 1977)
David Hume, Treatise of Human Nature (1739), ‘Introduction
Hume, ‘Of the Rise and Progress of the Arts and Sciences’, in Essays (1772 edn)
Rothschild, ‘The Atlantic Worlds of David Hume’, in Soundings in Atlantic History: Latent Structures and Intellectual Currents, 1500–1830, ed. Bernard Bailyn and Patricia L. Denault (Cambridge, MA, 2009), 405–48.
Crowley, John E., The Invention of Comfort: Sensibilities and Design in Early Modern Britain and Early America (Baltimore, MD, 2001)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×