Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T02:25:10.921Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Political Knowledge and the Logic of Voting: A Comparative Study

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 October 2009

Marta Fraile
Affiliation:
Doctora Miembro of the Instituto Juan March and Research Fellow, Consejo Superior de Investigaciones Científicas (CSIC)
José María Maravall
Affiliation:
Juan March Institute, Madrid
Ignacio Sánchez-Cuenca
Affiliation:
Juan March Institute, Madrid
Get access

Summary

Introduction

This chapter examines the decision-making process by which individual voters cast their ballots. In particular, it discusses two traditional explanations of electoral behavior: ideological voting and performance voting. These explanations of voting share a common assumption: electors' decisions are based on what they expect to get from their choice. Each potential outcome has a benefit or a cost, and citizens might choose the one benefiting them most or costing them least. That is, voters will maximize the utility of their electoral decision. To maximize the utility of a given decision, an individual needs to have a certain amount of information at hand.

Previous research has explained the simple and straightforward decision rule at work in both ideological and performance voting. In the case of ideological voting, citizens vote for the party that is perceived to be closer to their ideal position on the left–right dimension. Given the lack of perfect information for the electorate, Downs conceived ideology as an information-saving device – that is, a perceptual cue that helps ordinary citizens gain a general idea about the policy positions of the main parties of their political system. In the case of performance voting, citizens decide on a standard of what they consider good performance and reward the incumbent if this standard has been achieved; otherwise, they punish the incumbent.

Type
Chapter
Information
Controlling Governments
Voters, Institutions, and Accountability
, pp. 131 - 156
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Althaus, Scott. 2003. Collective Preferences in Democratic Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, Robert, Anthony Heath, and Richard Sinnot. 2001. “Political Knowledge and Electoral Choices.” CREST Working Paper No. 87.
Bartels, Larry. 1996. “Uninformed Votes: Information Effects in Presidential Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 40 (1): 194–230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartle, John. 1997. “Political Awareness and Heterogeneity in Models of Voting: Some Evidence from the Recent British Election Studies.” In Pattie, Charles, Denver, David, Fisher, Justin, and Ludlam, Steve (eds.), British Elections and Parties Review, vol. 7 (pp. 1–24). London: Frank Cass.Google Scholar
Bennet, Stephen. 1988. “Know-nothing Revisited: The Meaning of Political Ignorance Today.” Social Science Quarterly 69: 476–90.Google Scholar
Bennet, Stephen. 1989. “Trends in Americans' Political Information, 1967–1987.” American Politics Quarterly 17: 422–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennet, Stephen. 1995. “Americas' Knowledge of Ideology, 1980–1992.” American Politics Quarterly 23: 259–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brambor, Thomas, William Roberts Clark, , and Golder, Matt. 2005. “Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses.” Political Analysis 13: 1–20.Google Scholar
Comparative Study of Electoral Systems. 2005. CSES Module 2 Third Advance Release [data set]. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, Center for Political Studies. June 29 (see http://www.cses.org).
Converse, Philip. 1964. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” In Apter, David (ed.), Ideology and Discontent (pp. 206–61). New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Converse, Philip. 1970. “Attitudes and Non-Attitudes: Continuation of a Dialogue.” In Tufte, Edward (ed.), The Quantitative Analysis of Social Problems (pp. 168–89). Reading, PA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Costa Lobo, Marina, Pedro Magalhaes, and André Freire. 2004. “Introduçao.” In Freire, Marina Costa Lobo, , and Magalhaes, Pedro (eds.), Portugal a Votos: As Eleiçoes Legislativas de 2002 (pp. 25–34). Lisbon: Imprensa de Ciencias Sociais.Google Scholar
Carpini, Delli Michael, and Keeter, Scott. 1996. What Americans Know about Politics and Why It Matters. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert, and Goldthorpe, John. 1992. The Constant Flux: A Study of Class Mobility in Industrial Societies. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Fearon, James. 1999. “Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance.” In Przeworski, Adam, Stokes, Susan C., and Manin, Bernard (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation (pp. 55–97). New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gómez, Brad, and Wilson, Matthew. 2001. “Political Sophistication and Economic Voting in the American Electorate: A Theory of Heterogeneous Attribution.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (4): 899–914.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gómez, Brad, and Wilson, Matthew. 2006. “Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: A Comparative Analysis of Four Democratic Electorates.” American Journal of Political Science 50 (1): 127–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Key, V. O. Jr. 1966. The Responsible Electorate: Rationality in Presidential Voting: 1936–1960. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiewiet, D. Roderick. 1983. Macro-economics and Micro-politics: The Electoral Effects of Economic Issues. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kinder, Donald R., and Kiewiet, Roderick. 1979. “Economic Discontent and Political Behavior: The Role of Personal Grievances and Collective Economic Judgements in Congressional Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 23: 495–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kinder, Donald R., and Kiewiet, Roderick. 1981. “Sociotropic Politics.” British Journal of Political Science 11: 129–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. 1971. “Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964.” American Political Science Review 65: 131–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. 1983. “The Ecological Fallacy Revisited: Aggregate versus Individual Level Findings on Economics and Elections, and Sociotropic Voting.” American Political Science Review 77: 92–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krause, George A. 1997. “Voters, Information Heterogeneity, and the Dynamics of Aggregate Economic Expectations.” American Journal of Political Science 41: 1170–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luskin, Robert. 1990. “Explaining Political Sophistication.” Political Behavior 12: 331–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manin, Bernard, Adam Przeworski, and Susan Stokes. 1999. “Elections and Representation.” In Przeworski, Adam, Stokes, Susan, and Manin, Bernard (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation (pp. 29–54). New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Millner, Henry. 2002. Civic Literacy: How Informed Citizens Make Democracy Work. Tufts University: University Press of New England.Google Scholar
Pitkin, Hanna F. 1967. The Concept of Representation. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sinnot, Richard. 2000. “Knowledge and the Position of Attitudes to a European Foreign Policy on the Real-to-Random Continuum.” International Journal of Public Opinion Research 12: 113–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sniderman, Paul M., Richard, A. Brody, and Philip, E. Tetlock. 1991. Reasoning and Choice. Explorations in Political Psychology. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toka, Gabor. 2003. “Can Voters Be Equal? A Cross-National Analysis. Part 1.” The Review of Sociology 9: 51–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Torcal, Mariano, and Rico, Guillem. 2004. “The 2004 Spanish General Election: In the Shadow of Al-Qaeda?South European Society & Politics 9 (3): 107–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaller, John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaller, John R. 2004. “Floating Voters in US Presidential Elections: 1948–2000.” In Saris, Willem and Sniderman, Paul (eds.), Studies in Public Opinion: Attitudes, Nonattitudes, Measurement Error, and Change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×