Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-f554764f5-8cg97 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-04-16T08:06:41.711Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

9 - Subsidies and Future PTAs

From Market Distortions to Legitimate Policy Goals?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 April 2025

Kathleen Claussen
Affiliation:
Georgetown University, Washington DC
Manfred Elsig
Affiliation:
Universität Bern, Switzerland
Rodrigo Polanco
Affiliation:
Universität Bern, Switzerland

Summary

Subsidies are among the most prevalent government measures to support the domestic economy. This chapter argues that the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (ASCM), while regulating trade distortions caused by subsidies, is largely agnostic of how subsidies can also help address important twenty-first century challenges. These include policy goals like the green transition, economic recovery, and research and development support. First, we outline existing trends in countries’ resort to subsidies against the backdrop of WTO rules. Second, we explain why and how PTAs are a powerful instrument to address the ‘focal point shift’ from the alleviation of trade distortions to the promotion of public goods in subsidies regulation, also considering global value chains (GVCs) dynamics. Our approach balances regulation of ‘good’ and ‘bad’ subsidies, placing emphasis on the former, while being wary of new forms of distortive industrial subsidies. Third, we examine subsidy-related norms currently escaping multilateral rules and make a case for their inclusion into PTAs. We conclude that PTAs’ flexibilities make them best-suited for future-proof subsidies regulation and innovation in WTO agenda.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2025
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NC
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

9.1 Introduction

Subsidies regulation is one of the most contentious and complicated issues in international trade. There are various reasons for that. Subsidies are extraordinarily complex in the sense that they are extremely difficult to evaluate and quantify. Another important factor is their political sensitivity. Above all, the debate over subsidies puts in stark contrast the national spending required to attain public policy goals and international rules founded on a free trade ideology. Striking a balance between these two objectives is as crucial as it is challenging in a world in which, on the one hand, market integration has unbundled production across multiple regions and, on the other hand, the climate crisis and a global pandemic call for an increasingly active role of the state at home.

A growing number of frictions around subsidies have been playing out both at the domestic level in the form of countervailing duty (CVD) investigations and at the international level, as evidenced by the number of subsidy-related disputes taken to the World Trade Organization (WTO). Between 1 January 1995 and 30 June 2022, governments initiated 669 CVD investigations (WTO 2023a), with at least one CVD investigation per week being launched in 2018–2020 (Evenett and Fritz Reference Evenett and Fritz2021: 12). At the multilateral level, WTO Members invoked the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (ASCM) as many as 130 times in disputes from 1995 to 2021.Footnote 1

Against this background, the chapter argues that a future-proof subsidies regulation in trade can only result from a paradigm shift in how these policy measures are evaluated, and therefore sanctioned or permitted. Such a shift would be concretised by moving away from singular assessments of a subsidy’s trade-distortive potential to a balancing test that weighs any possible trade distortions against the benefits that subsidies pursuing legitimate policy objectives create. The latter crucially includes economic recovery, public health, and environmental protection – all objectives whose urgency and legitimacy cannot simply be undermined by a trade distortion benchmark. This approach would entail introducing a balancing test to ‘legitimate’ subsidies assessment, strengthening the transparency rules as well as expanding the list of prohibited subsidies, along with the requisite exceptions, to attain a more nuanced, practical, and balanced outcome. In elaborating on this argument, we look at preferential trade agreements (PTAs) as the most feasible institutional framework in which such a focal point shift can occur. Preliminary evidence already points in this direction. For instance, the European Union (EU) has incorporated into its recent PTAs a notion of ‘state aid’ with a wide scope and public policy focus that grants parties greater leeway in subsidy implementation than the current framework provided in the ASCM (Rubini and Hoekman Reference Rubini and Hoekman2022).

This chapter is structured as follows. First, we provide an overview of the state of the art of countries’ resort to subsidies, discussing figures from advanced capitalist economies in the G7 (Section 9.2). Second, we conceptualise and discuss the hybrid and ambivalent policy nature of subsidies, which are caught between the pursuit of legitimate public policy objectives and the market distortions they might generate (Section 9.3). Third, we explain why and how PTAs are the right platform for introducing changes to subsidies regulation for the twenty-first century (Section 9.4). Fourth, we briefly conclude (Section 9.5).

9.2 The State of the Art of Subsidies in International Trade

The ASCM is the primary legal framework governing subsidies regulation at the multilateral level. The ASCM deems a subsidy to exist if there is a ‘financial contribution’ by a government or any public body or if there is any form of ‘income or price support’ and a benefit is thereby conferred.Footnote 2 It broadly tackles the issue of subsidisation from two perspectives. First, it regulates the provision of subsidies by WTO Members, and second, it governs the use of countervailing measures to offset the adverse trade effects caused by subsidised imports. The ASCM disciplines two kinds of subsidies – prohibited and actionable subsidies (Part II and III of the ASCM, respectively). While the prohibition applies to local content and export-contingent subsidies that are deemed to be specific,Footnote 3 actionable subsidies are those specific subsidies that can be subject to challenge in the WTO or by resorting to countervailing measures at the national level.

As mentioned, the most significant controversy that revolves around the question of subsidisation is its ambivalence. Subsidies have been frequently seen as undermining the effects of market access prerogatives that result from tariffs and other trade concessions (Horlick and Clarke Reference Horlick and Clarke2016: 8–9). However, there is increasing recognition that subsidies can and, in fact, do produce positive effects and pursue legitimate goals (Heyl et al. Reference Heyl, Ekardt, Sund and Roos2022: 9).

In this latter case, subsidies can, indeed, correct the market process at least as much as they may distort it (Schwartz and Harper Reference Schwartz and Harper1972: 833). This section relaxes the assumption that subsidies are necessarily an expression of anti-competitive behaviour by anti-liberal countries challenging the tenets of the free market. Far from wanting to make a normative statement as to what is trade-distortive or not, we argue here that resorting to subsidies is a policy practice that can coexist with both an open economy and a political commitment to trade liberalisation. The multilateral legal framework has so far failed to properly take into account the positive externalities that subsidies may produce. Rather, it focuses on a trade distortion benchmark in assessing the effects of a particular subsidy scheme. Subsidy codification at the multilateral level also does not meet the level of detail and flexibility that such widespread and varied use of these policy tools would require.

The relationship between subsidies and trade law speaks directly to political economy debates assessing the role of the state within increasingly globalised and interconnected market economies. In this context, the ‘retreat of the state’ paradigm, which has populated political economy literature since the 1990s, has implied a mutual exclusivity between globalisation and market integration on one side, and an active role of the state in public and welfare policies on the other. Scholars like Strange (Reference Strange1996) argue that, as globalisation advances, the ability of the state to manage and regulate the market shrinks (see also Streeck and Crouch Reference Streeck and Crouch1997). Similar arguments are in line with the idea that the need to counter trade distortions is hierarchically prior to and largely incompatible with the need for states to deliver public and welfare policies.

We suggest here, however, that thinking of future-proof subsidy rules in twenty-first century trade is best served by arguments that see globalisation and widespread market liberalisation as going hand in hand with a resilient, if not, growing role of the state at home. This phenomenon was famously captured by Ruggie (Reference Ruggie1982), who juxtaposed a notion of ‘embedded liberalism’ to neoliberal paradigms calling for an unconstrained role of markets, like the Washington Consensus (see also Cameron Reference Cameron1978; Rodrik Reference Rodrik1998). The essence of embedded liberalism lies in seeking to strike a balance between domestic demands for an active role of the state in the economy and the fact of remaining a globally integrated market. In this sense, the relationship between domestic subsidies and free trade poses a paradox for liberal democracies, understood in terms of states’ ‘political mandate … to pursue the political economic interests of their citizenry under conditions of complex economic, legal and regulatory interdependence where large parts of economic governance are no longer exclusively within their control’ (Crouch Reference Crouch2008, as quoted in Clift and Woll Reference Clift and Woll2012: 308; Clift Reference Clift2013).

Figure 9.1 suggests that subsidies are a common feature of highly developed and economically integrated liberal democracies. The plot is based on the Global Trade Alert (GTA) database (Evenett and Fritz Reference Evenett and Fritz2020) and displays the share of subsidies and state aid measures implemented by G7 countries since the 2008 financial crisis, relative to the economic size of each (measured in average GDP). It categorises them based on their estimated trade-distortive potential.

Figure 9.1 G7 country shares of subsidy measures implemented since 2008 (GTA data).

Figure 9.1 indicates that the main divide amid G7 economies is one of quantity, rather than quality. While Italy accounts for the largest share of implemented subsidy measures proportional to its economic size, all G7 Members predominantly resort to subsidies which, albeit with varying magnitude, go in the direction of creating distortions in foreign markets – according to GTA evaluations. That is, subsidy and state aid policies implemented by globally integrated liberal economies like G7 ones are unlikely to have effects that are limited to their home markets. Considering the political economy drivers of subsidisation, the fact of resorting to these policies also seems to go beyond the ‘Varieties of Capitalism’ (VoC) divide between liberal market economies (LMEs) and coordinated market economies (CMEs) (Hall and Soskice Reference Hall and Soskice2001). The VoC framework suggests subsidies would be utilised differently in deregulated political economies (LMEs) than they would in more regulated and welfare-oriented ones (CMEs). Yet, at least at a macro-level, the above figures indicate that the VoC intuition is not really reflected by the data. Proportionally to their economic size, both LMEs and CMEs rely on subsidisation extensively. Specifically, two LMEs like the United States (US) and the United Kingdom (UK) score higher in their share of implemented measures than a CME like Japan, and an LME like Canada scores closer to a CME like Germany than to the US and the UK. Overall, subsidies qualify as a ubiquitous policy tool, which becomes particularly prominent in the aftermath of shocks and crises.

9.3 Subsidies as Hybrid Policy Instruments

Having discussed how subsidies constitute a widespread policy tool in even highly integrated capitalist economies, this section moves to consider how the hybrid policy nature of subsidies and their specific politico-economic effects are at odds with existing subsidy rules at the WTO level.

Specifically, we contend that the ASCM has yet to cover existing gaps in multilateral subsidies regulation. The reason for that is that subsidies are ambiguous and ambivalent in nature, in that the same policy measure can pursue certain legitimate goals and be classified as actionable or prohibited under the ASCM at the same time.

A first challenge in regulating the issue of subsidies multilaterally lies precisely in the difficulty in accounting for overlaps between ‘good’ and ‘bad’ subsidies within the same policy measure (Hoekman and Kostecki Reference Hoekman and Kostecki2009). We contend here that the reason for that lies in the ASCM’s one-sided focus on the adverse trade effects of the subsidy in question as opposed to a balanced analysis of both its negative and positive effects.

Subsidies are often the most immediate, readily available, and politically invoked public policy measures for governments to pursue given public objectives. Yet, subsidies can also be pushed for by vested interests of import-competing groups. In this latter case, subsidies may qualify as trade-distortive measures invoked by given industrial sectors in view of enhancing their market competitiveness at the expense of foreign exporters. The recent US Inflation Reduction Act (IRA), which introduces subsidies supporting the electric vehicle sector, alongside a local content requirement limiting the provision of government transfers to American manufacturers (United States Congress 2022), is an example of how a measure targeting desirable public policy objectives (i.e. climate change mitigation) can likewise have a trade-distortive potential.

Another example is the EU Green Deal Industrial Plan, as announced in January 2023 by Commission President Von der Leyen. While it entails ‘simplified’ state aid rules aimed at pursuing legitimate public policy objectives, including targeted aid for R&D in green technologies (WEF 2023), its trade-distortive potential may not be excluded.

The ASCM category of non-actionable subsidy contained in its Part IV lapsed in 2000, which means WTO law currently fails to define a category of subsidies de jure considered to be legitimate on the ground of attaining goals such as climate change mitigation, environmental protection, public health, or economic recovery, both nationally and globally.Footnote 4 The main implication of this legal void is that the specific subsidy evaluation at the level of international trade law is currently possible only through the prohibited and actionable categories.

Therefore, the key limitation of the ASCM framework lies in the absence of a coherent ‘test’ to assess the dual nature of any given subsidy: its alleged trade-distortive potential (as either a prohibited or an actionable subsidy) on the one hand, and its sustainable non-actionable component on the other. More deeply, the ASCM also lacks the case specificity to measure the specific nature of spillovers generated by a given subsidy for foreign markets, at least without initiating a dispute settlement process under WTO rules.

9.4 PTAs: Paving the Way for Trade and Subsidy Reform

Having discussed the ubiquity of subsidies and how challenging it is to devise recommendations for allowing or proscribing them, we now move on to arguing why and how PTAs are a good place to start for future-proof subsidies regulation. We argue here that PTAs can serve as helpful institutional ‘laboratories’ for subsidies regulation. PTAs have the potential to enact subsidy provisions built around a ‘balancing test’ focal point, while strengthening related transparency obligations between two or more parties.

While objectives pursued by subsidies do matter, so does the design of the system. Subsection 9.4.1 below discusses how PTAs can ensure greater governance specificity to address subsidy spillovers along global value chains (GVCs). We understand GVCs as consisting of industries spread globally and each contributing to different segments of the production of a single good. In subsection 9.4.2 below, we propose that subsidies pursuing legitimate objectives should be guided by a set of principles, which are by their very nature more conceptual than prescriptive. It goes without saying that in order to make the notion of ‘subsidies to attain a legitimate objective’ operational, a lot of questions about their precise boundaries and treatment are yet to be answered. Nevertheless, we believe that incorporating principles as opposed to directly applicable rules to regulate them is the best approach currently available. It is flexible enough to apply to a wide set of all possible scenarios but, at the same time, stringent in the sense that it provides clear indications on how to practically determine what is covered and what is not covered, when a subsidy creates a positive spillover and when it does not.

Another necessary means to further reinforce the PTAs’ potential to address current deficiencies in subsidies regulation is to improve the way they regulate transparency, which we discuss in subsection 9.4.3. Information is the key towards a constant improvement, and ensuring there is timely and sufficient information on subsidies is absolutely critical to creating a better and more effective subsidies regulation in the future.

Lastly, in subsection 9.4.4, we explain why and how PTAs are an appropriate avenue to expand the notion of ‘prohibited subsidies’ pending WTO deadlock. It is noteworthy that, unlike some other aspects of subsidies regulation, this is least likely to create a conflict with the WTO rules and could indeed be in the nature of a typical ‘WTO-plus’ obligation found in PTAs.Footnote 5 Future PTAs can develop a robust mechanism for governing newer types of extremely trade-distortive subsidies by including them within the definition of ‘prohibited subsidies’ and weighing their distortive potential against the stated domestic policy goal.

9.4.1 PTAs and Value-chain Specificity

The added value of PTAs in subsidies regulation is not only due to the limitations of the ASCM. It is also ascribable to the specificity of both the political economy drivers and effects of subsidisation across integrated markets, and more specifically GVCs. The effects – both positive and negative, and both market and non-market ones – of a given subsidy along a GVC are a function of a specific array of variables. These include the degree of subsidised goods’ access to a given foreign market, the weight of a subsidised sector in a country’s own export or import, as well as the specific politico-economic drivers leading to a subsidy in the first place.

Overall, the specificity of subsidy spillovers along GVCs qualifies PTAs as targeted institutional tools capable of prescribing and proscribing given policies in line with broader WTO rules. Paradoxically, the legitimacy of a subsidy cannot be measured separately from the market effects it yields on country B or C if implemented in country A, or vice versa (Hoekman and Nelson Reference Hoekman and Nelson2020). For instance, a subsidy implemented in final-good production by country B can expand the industrial base by multiplying intermediary inputs in country A (Baldwin and Venables Reference Baldwin and Venables2015; Hoekman Reference Hoekman2016). But intra-GVC subsidisation can also yield opposite effects. Biesebroek and Sturgeon (Reference Van Biesebroeck, Sturgeon, Cattaneo, Gereffi and Staritz2010) argue that subsidisation of large downstream car manufacturers can damage upstream producers when downstream car producers are the largest purchaser of these intermediary products, hence controlling their market (see also Blonigen Reference Blonigen2016). Against this background, another type of externality that could be envisioned has to do with ‘free riding’, and specifically with the problem of who is bearing the costs of subsidies generating positive spillovers along a GVC. Take, for instance, the implementation of a subsidy within a country (country A) sustaining the production of more innovative and energy-efficient microchips and bringing innovation also to the downstream semiconductors industry in country B, without requiring substantial technology adjustment in the latter. The subsidising government in country A would paradoxically be the one bearing the highest financial and political costs vis-à-vis taxpayers in terms of investment in new technologies, while country B would simply benefit from the positive spillover of a subsidy implemented elsewhere.

We argue here that PTAs qualify as viable institutions to govern the specificity of similar issues. For example, assuming that the intra-GVC externalities from subsidies were controlled for, a PTA would allow institutionalising processes of even burden-sharing for subsidies deemed to benefit the entire GVC. Let us go back to the semiconductors example, where intermediary-level innovation would positively impact also on downstream producers. A PTA would allow GVC Members to design forms of collective contributions, such as institutionalised shared funds, under the auspices of the agreement, from which subsidies with envisioned positive GVC spillovers would be disbursed. Contributions would be made on the basis of respective market size, or based on the extent to which a state’s national industry is expected to benefit from the subsidy in question, and would be limited to sectors where subsidisation is expected to benefit all PTA Members. Similar arrangements could be reviewed periodically by an ad hoc PTA committee, as is the case for various policy domains in twenty-first century agreements (like sustainable development or data protection). That would guarantee sufficient flexibility to channel shared investments to a defined set of sectors having ‘value-chain relevance’, adjusting the magnitude and direction of investments based on the evolving priorities of the preferential partners.

Overall, we acknowledge that countries that are part of a GVC may not be members of the same PTA. Furthermore, subsidy spillovers may extend well beyond members of a PTA. Yet, it is reasonable to assume that countries in a GVC would be comparatively more incentivised to enter a PTA (if not having one already in place), as preferential agreements have witnessed faster tariff cuts on intermediate goods, whose flow is essential for the existence of GVCs (Baccini et al. Reference Baccini, Dür and Elsig2018). Lower market barriers, in turn, would, all else being equal, make subsidy GVC spillovers (both positive and negative) more pronounced, and their impact assessment and regulation even more pressing.

9.4.2 ‘Legitimate’ Subsidies: A Balancing Test

Subsidies granted to provide public services, provide regional aid, or ensure environmental protection have been frequently incorporated into PTAs as a part of sustainability chapters or provisions. These are frequently referred to as ‘legitimate’ subsidies (Rubini Reference Rubini, Mattoo, Rocha and Ruta2020) and would have belonged to the non-actionable category referred to above in Section 9.3, unless lapsed.

The EU has so far been a champion in promoting such provisions in PTAs with its trading partners, particularly in its ‘new generation’ PTAs (e.g. the EU–Korea FTA; EU–UK Trade and Cooperation Agreement (TCA). However, these PTAs differ significantly in what they consider a legitimate objective, be it greening the economy or providing support to underdeveloped regions.

While there cannot be a one-size-fits-all approach, we argue that in the multilateral or regional context, it is insufficient that a subsidy merely pursues a legitimate objective. It is critical that such a legitimate subsidy generates benefits that are at least regional or, preferably, global in nature.

As we have explained above, subsidies, even those that have the most commendable objectives, such as environmental stewardship, could either incidentally or intentionally improve the competitive outlook or performance of the respective domestic industry in the subsidising country. One example would be local content requirements introduced by the US in the IRA. The introduction of a balancing test between negative trade-distortive and positive (e.g. public good creation) effects of a subsidy is, therefore, necessary for a comprehensive and fair assessment of the real impact of the subsidy in question. Despite their prominence and variability, as of today, no PTA would contain such guidance and, thus, give an understanding of how to draft, incorporate, and enforce an effective mechanism to regulate legitimate subsidies, serving not only a subsidising country’s interest but also of the peer countries’. The introduction of a balancing test that may allow assessing the effect of a particular legitimate subsidy taking into account its potential to bring about positive changes on a broader-than-national scale might, thus, act as a game changer in effective subsidies regulation.

We suggest that the focal point shift should take place in this context and along these lines.

Based on the best practices of the selected set of PTAs, as well as general economic and legal concepts, we draw up guiding principles and interpretation notes thereto (where relevant) that may serve as a basis for an efficient balancing mechanism for future PTAs.

This subsection, therefore, proceeds as follows. It suggests a respective principle to be incorporated, elaborates on its potential content and form, and discusses various settings where its application may be relevant.

The first principle is the adequacy of a subsidy in question to attain or otherwise promote the achievement of a legitimate objective. The critical question to be answered in this respect is how and why a subsidy may or may not be an adequate means to achieve a stated objective.

To answer this question, the respective competent authority in the granting country shall consider whether the potential beneficiary is capable of providing a business plan and/or investment strategy linked to a project with a detailed explanation of why that subsidy type is needed and its amount is necessary to achieve the stated objective.

The second principle is the effectiveness of a subsidy in attaining a legitimate objective. Effectiveness differs from adequacy in that while adequacy assesses whether a subsidy is the best instrument to pursue the stated objectives, effectiveness assesses the extent to which stated objectives are attained. Thus, the focus of effectiveness is on targeting the correct actions and completing them in a timely manner.

Here the test should be more stringent than a mere declaration that a subsidy is ‘not incapable of’ achieving the stated objective.Footnote 6 Instead, due regard must be given to the particular circumstances surrounding the granting of a subsidy.

These circumstances may include the effect of the policies already in place in the particular country and their contribution to the attainment of the stated legitimate objective (e.g. policies to promote renewables, tax cuts for ‘green’ production processes, etc.) akin to the ‘non-attribution’ test under the ASCM.Footnote 7

In other words, the subsidy in question should be the main and genuine contributor to the attainment of the stated legitimate objective. The need for such a causal-link analysis stems from the necessity to eliminate double support in cases where the stated objective would be achieved nonetheless. For instance, consider the French government’s EUR 7 billion bailout of Air France, which came with conditions for the airline to become ‘the most environmentally friendly airline on the planet’. This ambitious goal was pegged to three conditions: (i) halving overall emissions from domestic flights by 2024; (ii) sourcing 2 per cent of its fuel from ‘sustainable’ sources by 2025; and (iii) reducing carbon intensity by 50 per cent by 2030 over 2005 levels (Alderman Reference Alderman2020). However, every other airline that neither received support from the government nor did commit to ‘extra’ obligations to protect the environment is bound to reduce emissions and switch to renewable energy sourcesFootnote 8 under the EU’s Green Deal and the EU’s commitments under the Paris Agreement. Also, the third condition attached to the Air France bailout is no more than a simple reaffirmation of a commitment that the airline made as part of its Horizon 2030 Initiative (AF 2019: 3).

The effectiveness of a subsidy to attain a legitimate objective may also be assessed as a part of the ‘benefit’ analysis. This could be done by introducing an additional pillar to the ‘better off’ test, namely, whether there are positive spillovers and whether these are the effect of the subsidy in question.Footnote 9

On top of that, PTAs may introduce a supervision mechanism that would allow control over a subsidy’s amount and allocation. This may include granting a subsidy incrementally, such as, for instance, every month/year based on the milestones achieved and/or actions undertaken at a particular stage of the project. A sunset clause may reinforce this obligation even further by making a payment of a subsidy feasible only insofar as it produces the incentive effect (Rubini Reference Rubini2015).

Introducing a yearly obligation of the beneficiary to provide a detailed status report on the progress achieved and on the particular items of expenditure is another instrument against opportunistic behaviour. Thus, in cases where resources were spent on purposes other than the stated objective (e.g. the delivery of a particular public good) and if the beneficiary failed to prove the opposite, a subsidy due for the next milestone should be reduced by this ‘off-label’ amount.

The third principle is the enforceability of the particular obligations attached to a subsidy to ensure the attainment of a legitimate objective.

There are several aspects that must be examined in this respect.

First is the enforceability of the transparency obligations, which will be discussed in more detail in the next subsection.

Second is the existence of an enforcement body, responsible for overseeing whether subsidies are being used for the intended purpose. This enforcement body may be either a separate and independent body or a division of the Subsidies Committee (or any similar body created by the parties to the PTA).

Third is the enforceability of the ‘strings’ attached to subsidies. One example is ‘green strings’ attached to subsidies granted to ailing undertakings in times of emergency.

The green stimulus has recently become a typical feature of state aid, even though it still comprises only a small chunk of the total stimulus packages. According to some estimations, as of February 2021, the world’s leading economies have announced economic stimulus packages worth approximately USD 4.6 trillion directly into sectors that have a large and lasting impact on carbon emissions and nature, namely agriculture, industry, waste, energy, and transport, but less than USD 1.8 trillion has been allocated for green initiatives (GSI 2021). There are various reasons for such a disparity, including the lack of regulatory oversight on environmentally intensive sectors, and conflicting priorities, such as boosting economic performance during the crisis (as was the case during the COVID-19 crisis) versus environmental stewardship.

Therefore, attaching enforceable green conditions to the recovery packages is absolutely critical. This should be done, however, in a way that does not preclude the achievement of the primary growth-enhancing goals of such emergency-assistance packages, thus making them redundant. Instead, the main requirement for such green commitments should be a precautionary ‘do no harm’ requirement obliging the respective undertakings to ensure that no harm is done to the environment as a result of the increased economic performance. Additional green commitments (beyond the status quo) may come into play as the recovery gains momentum.

9.4.3 Transparency

Transparency has become all the more important when it comes to subsidies schemes. In order to facilitate a discussion on government support and to develop effective disciplines to cover existing and potential new support, information on the nature and scale of government support would be very useful, if not indispensable. Yet, such information remains limited (WTO 2021). There are several explanations for that: first, the difficult technical nature of subsidies; second, the political sensitivity of state aid measures; third, the fact that subsidies are diffuse, namely granted by various departments and levels of government. Attempts to address the lack of transparency on the multilateral level by ‘naming and shaming’ serial defaulters at the WTO in 2019 were harshly criticisedFootnote 10 and the proposal did not see the light of day. Addressing this concern at the level of PTAs may, therefore, be a feasible solution. Currently, many PTAs already include WTO+ obligations on transparency on subsidies (Mattoo et al. Reference Mattoo, Rocha and Ruta2020). The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) Free Trade Area (AFTA), for example, contains requirements to create repositories on laws and measures. Preferential trade agreements of the EU with countries like Montenegro, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia, and Ukraine provide for an inventory of all aid schemes. Another example is the PTA between Guatemala and Taiwan and China which contains the requirement to carry out studies.

However, more should be done.

Better information, objective analysis, and regular dialogue are key parameters that must be taken into account while elaborating a transparency chapter on subsidies in the model twenty-first century PTAs (IMF, OECD, World Bank and WTO 2022).

Keeping in mind these key pillars and based on the current best practices at the WTO (such as Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT)/Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) Committees) as well as minimum standards elaborated by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) in the context of disclosed requirements, this subsection provides few recommendations that may underpin the transparency provisions in future PTAs.

These recommendations seek a balance between the need for early and complete information on subsidy schemes with a requirement that notifications and disclosures are timely, complete, and enforceable and avoid placing an undue compliance burden on the respective party.

The first recommendation is differentiated reporting obligations. Reporting may contemplate different degrees of detail and/or different formats and/or content. For instance, reporting requirements may be a mere notification of a particular subsidy being granted when the subsidy is below the respective threshold valueFootnote 11 Such an approach would be consistent with the EU’s State Aid regime and potentially increase the mechanism’s efficiency by attributing more resources (e.g. person-hours) to cases contemplating significant public spending.Footnote 12 These notifications, however, should be subject to review on a yearly basis to ensure that this flexibility is not being abused.

At the same time, when the subsidy scheme involves significant state aid, its notification should follow the pre-assessment procedure of the dedicated unit of the Subsidies Committee (or any similar body created by the parties to the PTA). Such a committee could incorporate best practices that currently exist at the WTO TBT/SPS Committees, namely discussion of ‘specific trade concerns’ (STC), annual reviews on implementation of transparency provisions (notifications), as well as the introduction of information management systems.

The second recommendation is obtaining the high-quality data on subsidisation that would allow measuring the fiscal, economic, and positive global spillover effects of subsidy schemes and carrying out respective assessments and/or audits. The data should be complete, comprehensive, verifiable, and accessible. For instance, the UK Department for Business Energy and Industrial Strategy (BEIS)Footnote 13 developed a subsidy transparency database where comprehensive information on subsidies can be uploaded and viewed. This database may be used as an example of good practice and used as a starting point in elaborating on the subsidies’ data set template in future PTAs (BEIS 2022).

The third and last recommendation is the enforceability of transparency requirements. In particular, we suggest the application of non-monetary penalties such as temporary revocation of benefits or concessions granted by the PTA in cases of non-compliance with transparency obligations.

9.4.4 Prohibited Subsidies: A Future of Expansion?

Over the years, the predominant approach in international subsidies regulation has centred around disciplining different kinds of trade-distortive subsidies depending upon the level of distortion caused.Footnote 14 This stems from the fact that the outcome of the ASCM negotiations prioritised the ‘impact on competing producer interests’ over the possible welfare effects from certain subsidies (Zhou and Fang Reference Zhou and Fang2021: 484). Arguably, prohibited subsidies, as envisaged under the ASCM, are the most trade-distortive of the lot. In fact, they are to be withdrawn immediately in case of a positive finding in a WTO dispute.Footnote 15

While this chapter argues for a focal point shift from a trade distortion to a balancing approach for regulating subsidies in the PTAs (as elaborated in subsection 9.4.2 above), it does not propose to completely abandon the existing tenets of international subsidies regulations in these agreements, such as those surrounding prohibited subsidies. Indeed, the balancing test would assist in categorising a given assistance as prohibited, by assessing its trade-distortive effects over any potential positive effects. However, the outcome of the test may change in an exceptional situation, such as a financial emergency. This subsection hence proposes an update of the existing list of prohibited subsidies, counterbalanced by an expanded exceptions framework in future PTAs. In essence, this chapter argues for a yin–yang approach where modern twenty-first century PTA rules on subsidies adopt a well-balanced mechanism for both promoting and disciplining subsidies, depending upon their typology and effect. To this end, this subsection evaluates the current state and future prospects for disciplining the most trade-distortive subsidies in the PTAs with specific recommendations.

At present, the WTO rules explicitly prohibit two kinds of subsidies, namely the export subsidies and the import-substitution subsidies, under ASCM Article 3.1. While the former refers to subsidies contingent upon export performance,Footnote 16 the latter deals with subsidies contingent upon the use of imported over local products.Footnote 17 These kinds of subsidies are also presumed to be specific without any requirement to demonstrate adverse effects under the WTO rules (IMF, OECD, World Bank and WTO 2022; Rubini Reference Rubini, Hancher and López2021).Footnote 18

However, in recent times there has been a resurgence of discontent from certain quarters with respect to the narrow range of subsidies that are treated as prohibited under the WTO rules and, by extension, subject to the most stringent disciplines. The genesis of this can primarily be traced to the perceived inability of WTO rules to tackle trade-distorting subsidisation in the state-led economic model seen in countries such as China (McDonagh and Draper Reference McDonagh and Draper2020).

Primarily led by the EU, two recent initiatives in this regard stand out. These are the Joint Statement of the Trilateral Meeting of the Trade Ministers of Japan, the United States and the EU (USTR 2020), and the EU’s concept paper for WTO Modernisation (European Commission 2018). The primary thrust of these proposals is upon the need for expanding the current rules governing the most trade-distortive subsidies and going beyond prohibited subsidies.

The Trilateral Statement, for instance, proposes a trifold approach for updating the WTO disciplines since they are perceived to be inadequate to tackle market and trade-distorting subsidies in certain countries (USTR 2020). First, it argues for expanding the list of ‘new’ unconditionally prohibited subsidies based on what the proponents consider to be extremely trade-distortive. These could include unlimited guarantees, subsidies to ailing or insolvent enterprises without a credible restructuring plan, subsidies to enterprises operating in sectors or industries in overcapacity that cannot obtain long-term financing from independent commercial sources, etc. Second, the Trilateral Statement argues for a shift of the burden of proof on the subsidising country to demonstrate that its subsidy is not causing negative trade or capacity effects, for example, in the case of excessively large subsidies. Arguably, this approach could also be relevant in the context of GVCs. Finally, it argues for the direct linking of the concept of ‘serious prejudice’ under Article 6.3 to capacity.Footnote 19 The EU Concept Paper also provides the additional option of creating a rebuttable presumption of serious prejudice for these kinds of subsidies (as opposed to categorising them as prohibited subsidies).

Given the sweeping nature of changes to WTO rules proposed, both these initiatives are, however, surprisingly short on details or justifications. Concerns have also been raised regarding the lack of clarity on how the expanded notion of prohibited subsidies will interact with the developmental objectives of developing and least developed countries (Bhatnagar and Arora Reference Bhatnagar and Arora2020).

With the WTO system already under considerable stress at the moment, an emerging consensus could very well be elusive on these issues, at least in the short to medium term. Predictably, these proposals have failed to yet attract enough traction at the WTO. The PTAs are, hence, poised to emerge as a more viable platform for any future rulemaking in this field. They have the potential to serve as laboratories for the future, feeding into any future developments at the multilateral level.

Subsidies regulations in PTAs have largely remained underdeveloped beyond the transparency, dispute settlement, and countervailing duties frameworks for a large number of countries. While many PTAs do include disciplines on prohibited subsidies, very often these are a reiteration of the WTO position (Rubini Reference Rubini, Mattoo, Rocha and Ruta2020). However, this does not apply to the EU-, UK-, and US-led PTAs, particularly the recent ones (Sekine Reference Sekine2020). A limited expansion of the prohibited subsidies list is observed in these PTAs, primarily through the inclusion of unlimited guarantees and subsidies to insolvent or ailing enterprises without a credible restructuring plan within the ambit (e.g. EU–Japan Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA), EU–Singapore Free Trade Agreement (FTA), United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA), UK–New Zealand FTA). This is considerably smaller in scope, compared to the proposed prohibited subsidies list in the Trilateral Statement at the WTO. Other major PTAs, such as the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement (RCEP) and the African Continental Free Trade Agreement (AfCFTA), do not include an expanded list of prohibited subsidies.

There is also a variance observed in the approaches of the EU and the US. While the EU-led PTAs tackle the issues of prohibited subsidies as part of the larger subsidies’ disciplines, not much different to the WTO template, the US addresses this in the context of state-owned enterprises (SOEs). For instance, the USMCA prohibits non-commercial assistance provided by a party or its state enterprise or SOE to another SOE in case of insolvency without a credible restructuring plan.Footnote 20 At its core, the concept of non-commercial assistance is not very different to that of a subsidy, allowing for the above comparison.Footnote 21 As Siqi and Rubini (Reference Siqi, Rubini, Hoekman, Xinquan and Dong2021) note, the issue of state enterprises is largely a subsidy issue. This provides an avenue for streamlining the rules on the two issues. In sum, while limited strides have been made in the prohibited subsidies disciplines under PTAs by some countries, there is scope for developing these further in the coming times.

Any proposal for a future design of a PTA cannot be oblivious to its accompanying context, geopolitics, and global developments. When the world is only now bracing up to experience the full impact of COVID-19 on international trade and the global economy, the use of subsidies as a regulatory tool by governments to overcome the situation cannot be ruled out, and, indeed, can already be observed (IMF 2021). Against this background and building upon the existing rules and proposals, this subsection lays down an array of recommendations based on certain broad principles for tackling the issue of prohibited subsidies through future PTAs.

First, an overarching principle behind any future disciplining of prohibited subsidies must be viewed through the prism of maintaining a balance of the rights and obligations (Low et al. Reference Low, Mamdouh and Rogerson2018) of the parties to the PTA. Rules that are skewed in favour of only expanding the list of prohibited subsidies, without accounting for the accompanying exemptions or flexibilities that may be needed – particularly to deal with exceptional situations – may not be a tenable proposition in the long run. For instance, the EU–Japan EPA exemption from the prohibited subsidies rules for subsidies granted temporarily to respond to a national or global economic emergency may serve as an effective precedent.Footnote 22 Despite their not very successful track record at the WTO, horizontal exceptions along the lines of Article XX of GATT 1994 and Article XIV of GATS can also be made available to the subsidies discipline under PTAs.Footnote 23 Further, going forward, PTAs should also be designed to provide the necessary flexibility from the prohibited subsidies disciplines in case of a pandemic or post-pandemic recovery or other kinds of health emergencies.

Second, there is a need for undertaking a robust assessment through the balancing test before any expansion of the prohibited subsidies list. As mentioned earlier, the Trilateral Statement and the EU Concept Paper list potential subsidies that could be included in the prohibited subsidies list in the context of the WTO. However, PTA parties should examine the economic/trade distortion effects of the subsidies in question before including these in their agreements (Bown and Hillman Reference Bown and Hillman2019). Further, the proposed treatment of the subsidies in question should be proportionate to their effects. It is prudent not to repeat the mistakes made in the past, particularly at the WTO. Sykes, for instance, argues the WTO rules on subsidies are indefensible from an economic perspective, and they fail to identify the types of subsidisation in any meaningful way (Sykes Reference Sykes2010).

Third, any negotiated outcome on prohibited subsidies would require pre-empting legal loopholes by accurately capturing the understanding of the parties on specific new terms used in the new PTA rules. For instance, there is yet to be any global consensus on what would constitute an industrial ‘overcapacity’ in relation to subsidies (Bown and Hillman Reference Bown and Hillman2019). This will, thus, need to be resolved in a future PTA, in the event the parties agree to include the related subsidies in the expanded ambit of prohibited subsidies.

Finally, future PTA rules on prohibited subsidies could be designed to make subsidies and the state-owned enterprise (SOE) approaches for tackling prohibited subsidies converge, given the conceptual overlap between the two subjects. At their core, both broadly target the issue of distortive subsidisation by public bodies/SOEs that escape the WTO disciplines through the PTA route. As mentioned earlier, the US deals with some of the subsidies-related issues in the chapter on SOEs in PTAs such as the erstwhile Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement (TPPA) and the USMCA. This allows it the flexibility to define SOEs in broader terms, compared to the ‘public body’ definition under WTO. This chapter builds upon the ASCM Article 1.1 definition of a ‘subsidy’ as a basis for its analysis and recommendations. As per the ASCM, a subsidy is deemed to exist if there is a financial contribution by a government or any public body within the territory of a Member and a benefit is thereby conferred.

While the notion of ‘public body’ has not been defined under the ASCM, Appellate Body rulings have elaborated the meaning and scope of the term. For instance, in the US – Antidumping Countervailing Duties (China), the Appellate Body concluded that a ‘public body’ ‘must be an entity that possesses, exercises or is vested with governmental authority’.Footnote 24 According to the Appellate Body, the precise contours of a public body will vary from entity to entity, state to state, and case to case.Footnote 25 Thus, the Appellate Body interpretation appears to give precedence to governmental authority and control over governmental ownership of an entity. This would imply that the determination of whether an SOE is a public body would also vary on a case-by-case basis, despite both the terms being similar to some extent.

This interpretation has attracted much criticism, especially from the US, which argues that it is too narrow.Footnote 26 Thus, it is not surprising to see the US PTAs defining an SOE in clear terms, with ownership being an independent criterion front and centre of the definition.Footnote 27 The Trilateral Statement also states that the interpretation of the ‘public body’ by the WTO Appellate Body in several reports undermines the effectiveness of WTO subsidy rules, without proposing any specific modifications.

Future PTAs could be designed to include additional clarifications on what constitutes governmental authority or control in the context of a public body. While using ownership as an independent determinant may be easy to establish from publicly available resources, it may be unsuited to accurately capture the different shades of public bodies seen across the globe (OECD 2018) – for the specific purpose of prohibited subsidies. This approach can also be said to have contributed to a large number of exclusions sought and agreed upon with respect to SOEs in recent PTAs (Willemyns Reference Willemyns2016). Hence, it is recommended that future PTAs further evolve the case-by-case analysis approach of the Appellate Body by laying down additional grounds for clarity and consistency. The enjoyment of monopolistic or dominant market positions by the SOE on account of government-conferred advantages could be one such additional criterion to examine (Wu Reference Wu2019).

In conclusion, the WTO and PTA experiences with prohibited subsidies, along with some of the reform proposals, provide the groundwork needed to tailor a modern twenty-first century PTA design for prohibited subsidies. The recommendations above attempt to weave together different stands of the prohibited subsidies discourse to form a coherent strategy for the future.

9.5 Conclusion

Subsidies are one of the most widely used instruments to pursue public policy objectives, be it support of ailing undertakings, export promotion, or green transition.

World Trade Organization subsidy disciplines do not prohibit subsidies per se. They do prohibit, however, subsidies that are distortive to international trade. Distortion is measured by economic indicators such as increased market share or revenue of the subsidised industry to the detriment of exporters that might have competed equally.

Therefore, the current regime’s notion is that all prohibited or actionable subsidies are intrinsically harmful irrespective of oftentimes legitimate objectives they strive to pursue and their positive effects on the economy. We argue that this is one of the most critical omissions of the system, and where we see the need for a ‘focal point’ shift: from the system that fights against trade distortions to a system that would protect and shelter subsidies granted to attain legitimate objectives. We do not suggest that this system should bluntly exclude such subsidies from the ASCM regime. Neither do we suggest that one should turn a blind eye to subsidies with high distortive potential, such as unlimited guarantees, or subsidies to undertakings without a solid restructuring plan. We are also cognisant that the proposed approach may suit the interests of some countries more than others depending upon their level of development and capacity to subsidise.

Instead, we suggest introducing a set of guiding principles against which to assess not only the detrimental but also the positive effects of a particular subsidy. The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, in its current iteration, is incapable of fulfilling this task. That is where PTAs may serve as a game changer, first on the bilateral or regional and, later, on the multilateral level by gradually paving the way towards new and improved subsidies regulation for the twenty-first century.

Footnotes

* Views expressed are personal.

1 This is only slightly behind the Anti-Dumping Agreement (AD Agreement) with 142 and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT 1994) that appears in 511 of the 607 disputes initiated over the same period (WTO 2023b). Interestingly, however, as of 25 October 2022, only thirty-eight Members had notified that they maintain subsidies in accordance with Article 25.1 of the Agreement and Article XVI of GATT 1994, and ten Members had notified that they did not maintain any notifiable subsidies. See the ‘Report (2022) of The Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures’, adopted on 28 October 2022 (Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 2022).

2 See Article 1.1 of the ASCM.

3 In particular, see Article 3 of the ASCM.

4 As per Article 1.2 of the ASCM, the agreement only applies to subsidies that are ‘specific’ within the meaning of Article 2; non-specific subsidies continue to be non-actionable as per the WTO framework.

5 A potential conflict may, however, arise to the extent that there are additional exceptions to the WTO-recognised prohibited subsidies incorporated in the PTA text.

6 Appellate Body Report, Colombia – Textiles, WT/DS461/AB/R, paras 5.67–5.70. See also Panel Report, US – Tariff Measures, WT/DS543/R, para 7.125.

7 See Article 15.5 ASCM.

8 Conditions i and ii under the Air France bailout.

9 The standard ‘benefit’ test under Article 1.1(b) of the SCM Agreement seeks to identify whether the financial contribution has made ‘the recipient “better off” than it would otherwise have been, absent that contribution’. See Appellate Body Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft (2nd complaint), WT/DS353/AB/R, paras 635–636, 662, and 690.

10 The African Group, Cuba, and India stressed the capacity constraints of developing members, thus strongly opposing any transparency obligations that go beyond existing ones. See Communication from African Group, Cuba and India (Revision) ‘An Inclusive Approach to Transparency and Notification Requirements in the WTO’ (WTO 2019).

11 For the purposes of this contribution, referred to as ‘insignificant’ while aid that exceeds this threshold is referred to as ‘significant’.

12 In particular, under the EU State aid control there are a few exceptions to mandatory notification, including de minimis aid that, among others, does not exceed €200,000 per undertaking over any period of three fiscal years. See Commission Regulation (EU) No 1407/2013 of 18 December 2013 on the application of Articles 107 and 108 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to de minimis aid (OJ L 352, 24.12.2013).

13 Since 2023, the database has been maintained by the Department for Business and Trade (DBT) – one of the three departments, together with the Department for Energy Security and Net Zero (DESNZ) and the Department for Science, Innovation and Technology (DSIT) that BEIS was split into.

14 Since the non-actionable subsidy category under the ASCM is now lapsed.

15 See Article 3, ASCM. In case a WTO Member is found to have granted or maintained a prohibited subsidy through a dispute, it is to ‘withdraw the subsidy without delay’ as per Article 4.7, ASCM.

16 See also Appellate Body Report, Canada – Aircraft, WT/DS70/AB/R, para 167.

17 Appellate Body Report, Canada – Renewable Energy, WT/DS412/AB/R, para 5.6.

18 See Article 2.3, ASCM regarding the deemed specificity of prohibited subsidies.

19 For more details on the link between subsidies and overcapacity, see the submission from the European Union, Japan, Mexico and the United States, ‘The Contribution of the WTO to the G20 Call for Action to Address Certain Measures Contributing to Overcapacity’ (Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 2016); and the Communication from Canada, European Union and the United States, ‘Role of Subsidies in Creating Overcapacity and Options for Addressing this Issue in the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures’ (Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 2017).

20 See Article 22.6(b) of the USMCA.

21 For the definition of a non-commercial assistance, see Article 22.1 of the USMCA.

22 See Article 12.3.6 of the EU–Japan EPA.

23 See, for instance, Article 12.9 of the EU–Japan EPA.

24 Appellate Body Report, US – Antidumping Countervailing Duties (China), para 317.

26 Statement by the US at the 25 March 2011 meeting of the Dispute Settlement Body (United States Mission in Geneva 2011).

27 See the USMCA definition of SOE in Article 22.1. It defines an SOE, inter alia, to mean an enterprise that is principally engaged in commercial activities, and in which a party: (a) directly or indirectly owns more than 50 per cent of the share capital.

References

Aggarwal, V. K. and Evenett, S. J. 2010. ‘Financial Crisis, “New” Industrial Policy, and the Bite of Multilateral Trade Rules’, Asian Economic Policy Review 5: 221224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Air France (AF) 2019. ‘Air France Horizon 2030’, Air France Corporate Communications Division, pp. 3–11, https://corporate.airfrance.com/sites/default/files/air_france_horizon_2030_aftakescare_dossier_presse_eng.pdf, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Alderman, L. 2020. ‘Europe Hands Air France-KLM a $10.8 Billion Lifeline’, 26 April 2020, Section A, p. 22: The New York Times, New York edition, www.nytimes.com/2020/04/25/business/air-france-klm-bailout.html, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Baccini, L., Dür, A. and Elsig, M. 2018. ‘Intra-Industry Trade, Global Value Chains, and Preferential Tariff Liberalization’, International Studies Quarterly 62(2): 329340.Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Venables, A. J. 2015. ‘Trade Policy and Industrialisation When Backward and Forward Linkages Matter’, Research in Economics 69(2): 123131.Google Scholar
BEIS 2022. ‘Subsidy Transparency Database’, https://searchforuksubsidies.beis.gov.uk, accessed on 28 September 2022.Google Scholar
Bhatnagar, M. and Arora, P. 2020. ‘Industrial Subsidies’ Reform: The Developmental State under Siege’, August, Centre for WTO Studies Working Paper, https://wtocentre.iift.ac.in/workingpaper/Industrial%20Subsidies.pdf, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Blonigen, B. A. 2016. ‘Industrial Policy and Downstream Export Performance’, The Economic Journal 126(595): 16351659.Google Scholar
Bown, C. and Hillman, J. 2019. ‘WTO’ing a Resolution to the China Subsidy Problem’, October, Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper, www.piie.com/sites/default/files/documents/wp19-17.pdf, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Busch, M. L. 1999. Trade Warriors. States, Firms, and Strategic-Trade Policy in High-Technology Competition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, D.R. 1978. ‘The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis’, American Political Science Review 72(4): 12431261.Google Scholar
Clift, B. 2013. ‘Economic Patriotism, the Clash of Capitalisms, and State Aid in the European Union’, Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 13(1): 101117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clift, B. and Woll, C. 2012. ‘Economic Patriotism: Reinventing Control Over Open Markets’, Journal of European Public Policy 19(3): 307323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 2016. ‘The Contribution of the WTO to the G20 Call for Action to Address Certain Measures Contributing to Overcapacity’, Communication from the European Union, Japan, Mexico and the United States, 14 October, https://docs.wto.org/dol2fe/Pages/SS/directdoc.aspx?filename=q:/G/SCM/W569.pdf and Open=True, accessed on 29 August 2023.Google Scholar
Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 2017. ‘Role of Subsidies in Creating Overcapacity and Options for Addressing this Issue in the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures’, 13 April, Communication from Canada, the European Union, and the United States, https://docs.wto.org/dol2fe/Pages/FE_Search/FE_S_S009-DP.aspx?language=E&CatalogueIdList=239757,239584,236014,235895,235880,235672,235491,235439,232337,231889&CurrentCatalogueIdIndex=5&FullTextHash=&HasEnglishRecord=True&HasFrenchRecord=True&HasSpanishRecord=True, accessed on 29 August 2023.Google Scholar
Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures 2022. ‘Report (2022) of the Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures,’ G/L/1438 G/SCM/161, www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/scm_e/scm_e.htm, accessed on 29 August 2023.Google Scholar
Crouch, C. 2008. ‘Economic Patriotism and the Paradox of Neo-liberal Democracy,’ Paper presented at the first Economic Patriotism Workshop, Warwick University, 13–14 February.Google Scholar
European Commission 2018. ‘EU Concept Paper on WTO Modernisation,’ 18 September, https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2018/september/tradoc_157331.pdf, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
European Commission 2022. ‘EU-New Zealand: Text of the Agreement – Chapter 16: Subsidies’, 7 July, https://circabc.europa.eu/ui/group/09242a36-a438–40fd-a7af-fe32e36cbd0e/library/4dcdc64a-9f5b-415a-9087-b7bef1b0c2e4/details, accessed on 29 September 2022.Google Scholar
Evenett, S. and Fritz, J. 2020. The Global Trade Alert Database Handbook. Manuscript, 21 October 2022.Google Scholar
Evenett, S. and Fritz, J. 2021. ‘Subsidies and Market Access: Towards an Inventory of Corporate Subsidies by China, the European Union and the United States’, The 28th Global Trade Alert Report. London: CEPR Press, pp. 1151.Google Scholar
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyl, K., Ekardt, F., Sund, L. and Roos, P. 2022. ‘Potentials and Limitations of Subsidies in Sustainability Governance: The Example of Agriculture’, Sustainability 14(23): 15859. doi:10.3390/su142315859.Google Scholar
Hoekman, B. M. 2016. ‘Subsidies, Spillovers and WTO Rules in a Value‐chain World’, Global Policy 7(3): 351359.Google Scholar
Hoekman, B. M. and Kostecki, M. M. 2009. The Political Economy of the World Trading System: The WTO and beyond. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hoekman, B. M. and Nelson, D. 2020. ‘Rethinking International Subsidy Rules’, The World Economy 43(12): 31043132.Google Scholar
Horlick, G. and Clarke, P. 2016. ‘Rethinking Subsidy Disciplines for the Future. E15 Task Force on Rethinking International Disciplines – Policy Options Paper’, E15Initiative. Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD) and World Economic Forum.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF) 2021. ‘Policy Responses to Covid 19’, 1 July, www.imf.org/en/Topics/imf-and-covid19/Policy-Responses-to-COVID-19, accessed on 30 January 2023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF), Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), World Bank, and World Trade Organisation (WTO) 2022. ‘Subsidies, Trade, and International Cooperation’, 22 April, www.wto.org/english/news_e/news22_e/igo_22apr22_e.pdf, accessed on 28 September 2022.Google Scholar
Low, P., Mamdouh, M. and Rogerson, E. 2018. ‘Balancing Rights and Obligations in the WTO – A Shared Responsibility’, Government Offices of Sweden, www.swedenabroad.se, accessed on 30 September 2022.Google Scholar
Maskus, K. 2015. ‘Research and Development Subsidies: A Need for WTO Disciplines?’ The E15 Initiative, International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD), World Economic Forum, pp. 1–10, https://e15initiative.org/publications/research-and-development-subsidies-a-need-for-wto-disciplines/, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Mattoo, A., Rocha, N. and Ruta, M. 2020. Handbook of Deep Trade Agreements. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
McDonagh, N. and Draper, P. 2020. ‘Industrial Subsidies, State-Owned Enterprises and WTO Reform: Prospects for Cooperation?’ July. Institute of International Trade Policy Brief 08, https://iit.adelaide.edu.au/ua/media/783/mcdonagh-draper-2020-industrial-subsidies-soes-and-wto-reform_0.pdf, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Japan 2018. ‘Japan–EU Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA)’, 18 February 2021, www.mofa.go.jp/files/000382106.pdf, accessed on 29 September 2022.Google Scholar
Office of the United States Trade Representative (USTR) 2020. ‘Joint Statement of the Trilateral Meeting of the Trade Ministers of Japan, the United States and the European Union’, 14 January, https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/press-releases/2020/january/joint-statement-trilateral-meeting-trade-ministers-japan-united-states-and-european-union, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) 2018. ‘Ownership and Governance of State-Owned Enterprises: A Compendium of National Practices’, www.oecd.org, accessed on 30 September 2022.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. 1998. ‘Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?Journal of Political Economy 106(5): 9971032.Google Scholar
Rosendorff, P. and Milner, H. 2001. ‘The Optimal Design of International Trade Institutions: Uncertainty and Escape’, International Organization 55(4): 829857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubini, L. 2015. ‘Rethinking International Subsidies Disciplines: Rationale and Possible Avenues for Reform’, E15Initiative. Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD) and World Economic Forum, 2015, https://cadmus.eui.eu/handle/1814/39404, accessed on 28 August 2023.Google Scholar
Rubini, L. 2020. ‘Subsidies’, in Mattoo, A., Rocha, N. and Ruta, M. (eds.), Handbook of Deep Trade Agreements. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 427461.Google Scholar
Rubini, L. 2021. ‘State Aid and International Trade Law, in Hancher, L. and López, J. (eds.), Research Handbook on European State Aid Law. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, pp. 103133.Google Scholar
Rubini, L. and Hoekman, B. 2022. ‘Transcending Territoriality: Expanding EU State Aid Control Through Consensus and Coercion’, Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies Research Paper No. RSC_33.Google Scholar
Ruggie, J. G. 1982. ‘International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order’, International Organisation 36(2): 379415.Google Scholar
Schwartz, W. and Harper, E. 1972. ‘The Regulation of Subsidies Affecting International Trade’, Michigan Law Review 7: 833.Google Scholar
Sekine, T. 2020. ‘Possibility of Developing and Expanding the Regulation of Subsidies Through Free Trade Agreements (FTAs): Analysis Focusing on a Trend in FTAs Concluded by the EU’, Public Policy Review 16(5): 133.Google Scholar
Siqi, L. and Rubini, L. 2021. ‘About Knowledge and Rule-Making: Reforming WTO Rules on Subsidies’, in Hoekman, B., Xinquan, T. and Dong, W. (eds.), Rebooting Multilateral Trade Cooperation: Perspectives from China and Europe. London: CEPR Press.Google Scholar
Strange, S. 1996. The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Streeck, W. and Crouch, C. 1997. ‘Political Economy of Modern Capitalism’, Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.Google Scholar
Sykes, A. O. 2010. ‘The Questionable Case for Subsidies Regulation: A Comparative Perspective’, Journal of Legal Analysis 2(2): 473523.Google Scholar
United States Congress 2022. ‘H.R.5376 – Inflation Reduction Act of 2022, 117th Congress (2021–2022)’, the US Government Publishing Office, www.congress.gov/bill/117th-congress/house-bill/5376/text, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
United States Mission in Geneva 2011. ‘Statements by the United States at the March 25, 2011 DSB Meeting’, 25 March 2011, https://geneva.usmission.gov/2011/03/28/mar-25-2011-dsb-meeting/, accessed on 29 August 2023.Google Scholar
Van Biesebroeck, J. and Sturgeon, T. 2010. ‘Effects of the 2008–09 Crisis on the Automotive Industry in Developing Countries: A Global Value Chain Perspective’, in Cattaneo, O., Gereffi, G. and Staritz, C. (eds.), Global Value Chains in a Post-Crisis World: A Development Perspective. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 209244.Google Scholar
Willemyns, I. 2016. ‘Disciplines on State-Owned Enterprises in International Economic Law: Are We Moving in the Right Direction?Journal of International Economic Law 19(3): 657668.Google Scholar
World Economic Forum (WEF) 2023. ‘Davos 23: Special Address by Ursula von der Leyen, President of the European Commission’, Davos, 17 January 2023, www.weforum.org/agenda/2023/01/davos-23-special-address-by-ursula-von-der-leyen-president-of-the-european-commission/, accessed on 30 January 2023.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (WTO) 2021. ‘World Trade Report 2021. Economic Resilience and Trade’, Geneva: WTO www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/wtr21_e/00_wtr21_e.pdf, accessed on 28 September 2022.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (WTO) 2023a. ‘Countervailing Initiations by Reporting Member 01/01/1995–31/12/2022’, www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/scm_e/scm_e.htm, accessed on 29 August 2023.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (WTO) 2023b. ‘Disputes by Agreement’, www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/dispu_e/dispu_agreements_index_e.htm, accessed on 29 August 2023.Google Scholar
Wu, Y. 2019. ‘Reforming WTO Rules on State-Owned Enterprises: SOEs and Financial Advantages’, Northwestern Journal of International Law and Business 39(3): 275308.Google Scholar
Zhou, W. and Fang, M. 2021. ‘Subsidizing Technology Competition: China’s Evolving Practices and International Trade Regulation’, Washington International Law Journal 30(30): 470544.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 9.1 G7 country shares of subsidy measures implemented since 2008 (GTA data).

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×