Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T20:06:43.678Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - Eating with the Tax Collectors

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 March 2023

Noah Kaye
Affiliation:
Michigan State University

Summary

The budgetary earmark was a key feature of public finance in the expanded Attalid kingdom and contributed to the success of the Pergamene imperial project. The dynamics and meaning of this administrative technique are thus explored in depth. Earmarking not only increased the quantity of money available to royal bureaucrats; it also made money into a medium for messaging. In a pointedly transparent manner, specific royal taxes and other revenues were earmarked for specific public goods. A series of inscriptions record the neat and final arrangements, but it is possible and even illuminating to reconstruct the entanglements of the process of negotiation by which these earmarks came into existence. The creation of an earmark required an interlocking of royal and civic fiscal institutions that further entrenched Attalid rule. The earmarking process posed ideological risks, as kings delved into the domain of private property and devolved agency to local actors, while also providing an arena for the display of providential care (pronoia) for royal subjects.

Type
Chapter
Information
The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
Money, Culture, and State Power
, pp. 34 - 73
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Resolved by the Council and the People; Menemachos son of Archelaos moved: since Korragos son of Aristomachos, the Macedonian, when he was appointed general (strategos) of the regions (topoi) about the Hellespont, continuously applied all his enthusiasm and goodwill to the improvement of the People’s condition and made himself serviceable both publicly and in private to all the citizens who had dealings with him, and when he took over the city he requested from the king the restoration of our laws, the ancestral constitution, the sacred precincts, the funds for cult expenses and the administration of the city, the oil for the young men (neoi) and everything else which originally belonged to the People, and as the citizens were destitute because of the war, he supplied at his own expense, cattle and other victims for the public sacrifices and after mentioning the matter to the king he secured the provision of corn for sowing and for food, and he enthusiastically assisted [the king] in preserving the private property of each of the citizens and in providing those who had none with some from the royal treasury, and as exemption (ateleia) from all taxes (prosodoi) had been granted by the king for three years, he secured a further exemption for two years, wishing to restore the citizens to a state of prosperity and increase, acting in conformity with the king’s policy; so that the people may be seen to be rendering adequate thanks to its benefactors, be it resolved by the People [to praise] Korragos the general and [to crown him] with a gold [crown…].Footnote 1

The decree for Korragos the Macedonian, the Attalid governor of Pergamon’s new Hellespontine province, recalls catastrophic conditions in an anonymous city, ca. 188 BCE. It describes a postwar landscape of both material want and profound social disorder. Still suffering from the effects of the War of Antiochos, the city could not so much as feed itself, let alone plant crops. Naturally, public sacrifices, rituals, and politics – the institutions that had preserved collective identity over generations – had all gone into abeyance. The very basis of ancient social structure, the distribution of landed property, felt insecure. It was as if everything had broken down all at once. This was the breach into which the Attalids and their administrators stepped after the Treaty of Apameia. In cities such as this, the first task of postwar governance was simply to reconstitute the community. In the case of Korragos on the Hellespont, a royal official personally provided the animals for the initial public sacrifices and feasting. He was also the catalyst for the king’s own benefactions, prevailing upon Eumenes II to distribute seed and, in the meanwhile, sustenance. Ultimately, the Attalids even paid to preserve the city’s social order, assuring those with property of their rights and granting land to the landless.Footnote 2 For these kings, the initial steps of assembling an empire required getting their hands dirty. Building up this city entailed deep familiarity with its social fabric and institutions.

Remarkably, the citizens of this devastated city, who were the recipients of so much strings-attached aid, seem to have negotiated rather ably. Weakened as they were by the recent war, they still managed to drive a hard bargain with Eumenes. In the near term, what had been envisioned as a three-year tax holiday was extended for two more years. In the long term, Eumenes acceded to their request for a return to certain privileged conditions of the past. In the felicitous shorthand of civic memory, those privileges are described as “everything else which originally belonged to the People” (ἃπερ ἐξ ἀρχῆς ὑπῆ[ρ]|χεν τῷ δήμῳ).”Footnote 3 That term “originally” was chronographically ambiguous by design. Demands for privileges backdated to the hoary past were more likely to succeed.Footnote 4 Equally vague and malleable was the notion of an “ancestral constitution (patrios politeia),” which Eumenes also promptly returned to them without modification. Yet we know that one trumpeted privilege was almost certainly of very recent vintage: “[royal] funds for cult expenses and the administration of the city” (τὸ εἰς τὰ ἱερὰ καὶ πόλεως διοίκησιν ἀργύριον).”Footnote 5

This practice of earmarking, of injecting royal money directly into the organs of civic finance, has long been considered, if not an exclusively Pergamene habit, a trademark of the Attalids.Footnote 6 By nature, the injection was not a one-time gift, but like the “oil for the neoi” mentioned in the same breath, a routine, regularized, usually annual disbursement of money.Footnote 7 Earmarks also allowed donors to give targeted gifts, which in this case were subsidies that sustained a local culture under threat of extinction. While they did not invent the practice, the Attalids were the most prolific issuers of what is usefully labeled the “earmark”: the designation of specific future revenues for specific public goods.Footnote 8 These are promised gifts; the money is anticipated. These are also gifts with a purpose. Pergamon, for example, dominates our records for foundations, the endowments, the pots (sometimes literally) of money, which priests and other magistrates of Greek cities and sanctuaries managed in order to fund public life. As Graph 1.1 shows, no other dynasty matched the Attalids for giving on this score.Footnote 9

Graph 1.1 Philanthropic foundations of the Hellenistic world.

(data from Bringmann et al. 1995)

Earmarks reflect the Attalids’ exceptional facility with moving money. Around Anatolia and throughout the Aegean, they shifted cash between accounts and polities more often than any of their peers (Graph 1.2), and they moved grain, the most money-like commodity of their day and the most easily converted into cash, at a rate rivaling the Ptolemies with their Nilotic cornucopia (Graph 1.3). Fascinatingly, while Attalid gifts of money are so numerous, they tended to be very small. Numbers are scarce, but Attalid donations make up a mere 9% of the total (recorded) amount of money comprised by the gifts of Hellenistic kings. Moreover, while the median gift size for a king was 45 talents, the Attalids’ was just 10. Many Attalid subventions were even smaller. Perhaps, as has been suspected, Polybius was aiming a barb their way when he complained of miserly kings who gave four or five talents and expected the highest honors in return. By the standards of Hellenistic royalty, these were small gifts, but by contemporary standards of public finance, these were sophisticated gifts.Footnote 10

Graph 1.2 Royal gifts of money.

(data from Bringmann et al. 1995)

Graph 1.3 Royal gifts of grain.

(data from Bringmann et al. 1995)

The so-called Korragos Decree from modern Bursa, Turkey, highlights the modesty, frequency, and indeed the rationality of an Attalid earmark. This was not a one-off transaction. Nor was it a windfall bonus of mysterious origins. Admittedly, the Korragos Decree is silent about the source of the money promised in perpetuity. However, those texts which do speak to the issue invariably specify a local source of revenue. In other words, the money is not assumed to issue forth from a distant, centralized treasury. Either some portion of those royal taxes collected locally is rerouted into the city’s coffers or another source of revenue is provided. This could be a piece of property or the taxes of an entire village. According to Greek fiscal categories, it did not make much difference. Rather, to a Greek, these revenues were all prosodoi of one kind or another, the taxes and endowment income of the modern fiscal lexicon.Footnote 11 We may not always hear about the source of the earmark, or one text may refer to the public good while another designates the revenue source, but we can be sure that royal bureaucrats and Attalid subjects both knew the details well. This is because they were the ones who had hammered them out. Earmarking was a social process.

By the time that Korragos and the Attalids appeared on the Hellespont, ancient political communities had been earmarking money for a very long time. The practice of reserving future revenues for specific public goods such as security had been a feature of the Classical polis.Footnote 12 What was new and distinctive about the Attalids was the extent to which they employed earmarking as a tool of empire. How to explain this? A review of the evidence will not support an explanation that relies exclusively on either top-down, royal, or local, civic initiative. Both parties clearly reaped benefits from these arrangements. So were the Attalids simply sweetening the bitter pill of imperialism?Footnote 13 While earmarking contributed to the ideological accommodation of Attalid subjects, it also circumscribed the king’s freedom of action and exposed the limits of his power. This chapter explores the dynamics of earmarking as a social process, arguing that the static earmarking arrangements of our sources were negotiated into existence. The dynamics of earmarking will be seen to include frequent royal forays into the sphere of private property, the devolution of agency, and an interleaving of civic and royal institutions that implies deep familiarity. Finally, a set of culturally specific meanings emerges for earmarking, which rendered it a privileged solution to the problems of risk and governance in the expanded Attalid kingdom.

Earmarking as a Social Process

Before delving into the dynamics and meanings of earmarking in the Attalid kingdom, it is worth considering how insights from economic sociology can help us reanimate a practice that has become fossilized in our inscriptions. Earmarking is one way of relating to money by means of differentiating it, and if we step back from any particular artifact, from ingots to coins, cowry shells to bricks of tea, paper to plastic, we can see that money has always taken many different forms. Theoretically, as an economic instrument, money is homogeneous. And so the tautology goes, a dollar is a dollar; any dollar works like any other. The conventional, four-fold definition of money as a means of exchange, a means of payment, a store of value, and a unit of account takes money to be perfectly fungible.Footnote 14 Historically, the homogeneity of money is what has given it economic significance. Money lowers transaction costs because different goods and services are priced according to a standard unit. As Aristotle remarked in his imagined history of coinage, the convenience of money for partners to an exchange is irresistible (Pol. 1.3.1257a31–42). Because in such a world money is perfectly fungible, the existence of money by itself promotes an increase in the volume of exchanges, as all money finds acceptance in all transactions. However, such a world does not exist; not today, nor in Antiquity.Footnote 15

Certainly, money is an economic instrument of enormous significance. Exchange looks very different without money. Yet as social scientists have demonstrated, human beings steadfastly refuse to treat all money as equal. In a monetary regime that contains multiple forms of money, different monies may be appropriate for different transactions, sometimes exclusively so. One pays a dowry in, say, bronze ingots, but the services of a seer can only be had for token money – seashells, for example, even if these must be bought with bronze. These are the “special-purpose monies” of the work of Karl Polanyi.Footnote 16 Moreover, money is still differentiated and restricted in its fungibility in a monetary regime in which a single form of money predominates or even achieves monopoly status.Footnote 17 We differentiate money in a great number of ways. To take just two examples, we make distinctions between “clean” and “dirty” money, or between “windfall” money and regular income. The crucial factor here that dictates the ways in which the money can be employed is the source of the money. A purely utilitarian or functionalist account of money misses the link between the variable meaning of money and its uses. Money is both an economic and a symbolic instrument.Footnote 18 When the two modalities collide, a friction is produced that we can observe.

Research in the social sciences has heightened our awareness of the diverse properties and possibilities of money. Among economic sociologists, Viviana Zelizer has led the charge in exposing the limits of money’s fungibility and highlighting the socially and culturally constructed nature of its meaning.Footnote 19 She places special emphasis on the practice of earmarking money, both according to its source and according to its use.Footnote 20 Earmarking is a prime example of the way in which notionally homogeneous money becomes differentiated. Fundamentally, earmarking is the differentiation of money, whether by source, by use, or as in the Attalid practice, by both: money from a particular source is designated for a particular use. Anthropologist Mary Douglas studied how so-called primitive societies mark off monies into separate spheres of sacred and profane, fungible and nonfungible, as well as the way money moves in and out of those categories.Footnote 21 Zelizer’s contribution was to show that modern economic life is also full of earmarking, and not as the result of the survival of a primitive, precapitalist practice. In fact, she argues, in American history we see a proliferation of earmarking and more broadly of the social differentiation of money precisely when the federal government imposes with its full weight a single, uniform, and generalized form of money, a process that began with the National Banking Act of 1863. In Zelizer’s late nineteenth- and early twentieth-century households, the money is not kept under the mattress in one lump sum. It is divided between a set of tin cans: one for mortgage payments, another for the children’s education, and another for emergencies. “Pin money” is set aside for the wife’s consumption. Earmarking, however, is by no means the exclusive strategy of nonstate actors. The modern state itself engages in earmarking in its budgets, routing cigarette taxes into college scholarships and gas taxes into roads. The state might even encourage households to adopt the practice of budgetary earmarking in an ideological struggle over the shape of home economics.Footnote 22

Earmarking and Greek Epigraphy

An earmark is often the end result of a long process of negotiation. Even then, the process can continue as earmarks are met with counter-earmarks. Relations of domination and subordination are articulated and rearticulated. “The earmarking of money is thus a social process: money is attached to a variety of social relations rather than to individuals.”Footnote 23 A large number of Greek epigraphic documents bear witness to this very process. To choose from countless examples, we may consider a debate that took place in the context of an Athenian cultic association of the third century.Footnote 24 In a decree, the association published new rules for the source and use of its patron goddess’ money: rents from sacred land were thenceforth earmarked exclusively for sacrifices. In the background, we can glimpse a dispute, which had concerned the differentiation of money. The question had been, “Was income from sacred land ‘clean’ or ‘dirty’?” It had also been unclear whether members (orgeones) were entitled to borrow money from the goddess for worldly ends.Footnote 25 Methodologically, we must be aware that such an inscription records the outcome of the dispute, while the process by which it was resolved tends to be obscured. Another difficulty is discovering a social process when earmarking appears in the context of imperial domination. The orgeones of an Athenian cultic association met on egalitarian terms. Was earmarking any less of a process in Hellenistic Asia Minor, with its vast disparities of power between kings and cities? The case of Antigonos and the cities of Teos and Lebedos suggests it was not. The ill-fated attempt of the Macedonian to execute the synoicism of Teos and Lebedos involved a negotiation over the constitution of a public grain fund. Lebedos had earlier requested of Antigonos that 1,400 gold staters “be set aside from the revenues (ἐξαιρεῖσθαι ἀπὸ τῶν προσόδων)” for a complicated grain scheme. In other words, certain revenues were to be reserved for the provision of the new city’s grain supply. Antigonos did not act on the initial request of Lebedos, but when Teos later petitioned for an even larger amount, he rejected the idea. Any exigent import of grain, Antigonos argued, ought to come from his own “tribute-bearing (phorologoumenê)” land, effectively claiming a royal monopoly. Yet in the end, the cities prevailed over the king: Antigonos agreed to earmark the 1,400 gold staters, per the original request of Lebedos.Footnote 26

The Dynamics of Earmarking in the Attalid Kingdom

Our sources are fragmentary, but together they capture many different stages of the earmarking process. The Korragos Decree, which shows Eumenes II resuscitating one community after the War of Antiochos, demonstrates the power of earmarks to bind subjects and rulers together. Though rich with information, the document is also lacunose. It only alludes to the process of negotiation lurking behind Eumenes’ decision to extend the city’s tax holiday. The Korragos Decree tells us little about the institutional arrangements put in place. We only hear that royal funds are earmarked for the religious life of the city and for its administration. The tap is turned on, the money set to flow in regularly, but how regularly? Annually or in installments? According to which calendar, the city’s or the king’s? Eumenes also promises a provision of oil for the neoi (young men of the gymnasium), presumably disbursed in like manner, but the language of the inscription is even cloudier on this point.Footnote 27 So much is left out or left ambiguous. Should we imagine two separate funds, one for sacrifices and another for “the administration of the city” (dioikesis) – or is it a joint fund?Footnote 28 How much money will be earmarked for each purpose? And finally, where exactly will the money come from?

Private Property and Sale

In 2007, an extraordinarily rich document for the Attalid earmarking process was published, a double-sided inscription from the modern village of Taşkuyucak, west of Lydian Daldis (D2). The inscription was discovered in the Keçi Dağ mountain range, north of Lake Koloe/Gygaia, near a pass that connects the plain of Sardis to the road to Thyateira and the upper Kaikos Valley. After 188, this was a vital link between the old Attalid core and what had been the primary Seleukid administrative center in cis-Tauric Asia Minor. The site of the town (katoikia) and fortress of Apollonioucharax must have been nearby since the inscription shows the town’s ambassadors appealing to Eumenes II in the wake of the destructive conflict with the Galatians (168–166). Soldiers as well as civilians lived in this town. The soldiers, largely Mysian, were not necessarily professional, as evidenced by a partial conscription alluded to in the text. This inscription shares many similarities with the Korragos Decree, from its script to its postwar setting.Footnote 29 Once again, Eumenes II aimed to ameliorate the devastation of war with a variety of fiscal privileges and outright gifts. Side B appears to be a petition of Apollonioucharax. Side A appears to be the response of Eumenes II to the requests. The text reads in Peter Thonemann’s translation and edition (my modifications in underlined italics):Footnote 30

Side B:

… of these … registered … (we request that) these privileges should persist, and (we request that you) annul the [punishments?] of those reported as having deserted from the army in Year 32 (166/5 BCE), and that they should have the same (privileges) as the others. (We request that) there should be inviolability for Zeus Stratios, and instead of the seven stadia previously granted, it should extend to ten stadia. In order that the priest Bacchios might make a golden wreath, (we request that) our registered debts, both in silver and grain, should be remitted until the third year, unless anyone has already exacted and sequestered them. Concerning the houses in the suburb (of Apollonioucharax) which were burned and pulled down, (we request that you) take care that, because we are co-citizens, some grant be given for their reconstruction. (We request that) the village of Sibloe, which was earlier ours – about which it is written that “it will be restored to us when we have settled up a price with Meleager, who bought the village, (vacat), 448 drachmas and 1.5 obols” – that it should now be conveyed to us without a price, so that the revenues of the village shall provide for the sacrifices for Zeus Stratios and for those on your behalf. (We also request that) the village should remain for us sacred and tax-free, and that the money for it should be given to Meleager from the royal treasury. (We request that) villages should be granted to meet the shortfall of kleroi and associated buildings. Since those (villages) which were previously taken from us have not been restored in the way in which you promised, (we request that you) mark out for this purpose Thileudos and Plazeira as hunters’ settlements, and move the inhabitants of these villages to whatever settlements Lykinos the land-distributor may decide. (Royal official) – For we have ordered him to look into the matter and mark them out.Footnote 31

Side A:

… Kournoubeudos … [made] demonstrations [sc. of their loyalty] in the war; [I was intending] to move the Mysians living in this place to Kastollos, since fresh land certainly exists there in an uncultivated condition. But [ambassadors] from Apollonioucharax came to meet me, and said that they were grateful for the … of their territory; they also said that, since the Mysian settlers at Kournoubeudos [were …] and had become well-acquainted/friendly with them, they wished to …, in whatever way they might decide among themselves. And so, in recognition of their good sense and moderation, I have granted this just as they have requested. I have also ordered Lykinos the land-distributor to [take thought] whence we might be able to add a further stretch of land to their territory. Since they deserve great consideration, having been destroyed last year by the enemy, I grant another five years’ exemption from customs-dues in addition to the five years granted previously, just as I have done for the Mysians at Kadooi. Registration for compulsory military service will fall only on one man in three, for I know that if some emergency occurs, they will provide more soldiers of their own accord because of their eagerness and goodwill. They shall all be exempted from the collection of the tithe on produce for the current year, and those on whom the eisphora-taxes are levied are also exempted for the current year. Since they are making a start on the rebuilding of the settlement, I have also agreed to provide masons for them.Footnote 32

Here, a document speaks to the crucial issue of the source of an earmark. The earmark’s source was property purchased by the king. By purchase and redemption of private property from third parties, the Attalids funded the public goods that earned them loyalty at home and accolades abroad. It bears emphasizing that this was an unusual pattern of kingly behavior, but one detectable in the dynasty already with Philetairos, who acquired real estate in Thespiai in the 270s. Lands which the dynast purchased and designated as sacred fed the cult of the Muses, provided for the festival of the Philetaireia, and maintained the supply of oil for a local gymnasium.Footnote 33 Another episode involves the visit of Attalos I to Sikyon in 198. The city had lost control of land sacred to Apollo, evidently being held as private property. Attalos purchased it – for a steep price, notes Polybius – and restored to the Sikyonians their sacred lands.Footnote 34 That the Attalids built their redistributive system by routinely transacting with private partners is now further underscored by the inscription from Taşkuyucak.

In postwar Apollonioucharax, the breakdown of order was again complete. With some soldiers homeless and others deserting, both social stability and state control were in doubt. Again, Eumenes’ goal was to reconstitute a community, this one rural and in certain ways non-Greek. For his generosity, the king demanded an easy conscription in yet tougher times. Eumenes provided the settlers with land allotments, building materials, and masons. He instructed his official to find and survey the land, transfer out other populations, distribute construction materials, and bring in know-how. He also provided support for the ancient Anatolian cult of Zeus Stratios (“the army leader”), first, by expanding an unparalleled grant of territorial immunity (asylia) to a sanctuary outside the control of a Greek polis.Footnote 35 Second, he employed a pair of earmarks: taxes in arrears, both cash and kind, were remitted for a period of three years so that the priest Bacchios might furnish a golden wreath.Footnote 36 To fund the worship of Zeus and sacrifices on his own behalf, the king earmarked revenues that he redeemed from the nearby village of Sibloe, perhaps the place once attached to an indigenous sanctuary known from a fourth-century Aramaic inscription from Kenger (Side B lines 11–19).Footnote 37

Financially, Apollonioucharax was in over its head. Apparently, the town had sold the usufruct of the village of Sibloe to an individual named Meleager for cash. The town retained the right of redemption, but could not come up with the money. The ambassadors seem to have asked the king to unwind this old transaction. It is helpful to think of the new transaction of Eumenes with Meleager as the unwinding of the old one because it allows us to make sense of the odd number on the stone: 448 drachmas and 1.5 obols. Thonemann finds the price too low for an entire village’s revenues and so postulates a missing numeral in the vacat.Footnote 38 However, this assumes that the price recorded in the inscription was the original price paid by Meleager. Peter Herrmann and Hasan Malay, working from the stone itself, note, “It looks as if the amount had been added later in a space left blank.”Footnote 39 This does not fit well with the model of interpretation put forward by Thonemann, which sees here a contract quoted verbatim (“about which it is written” περὶ ἧς γέγρα|πται). Perhaps, we should consider the lowball price as the result of Eumenes’ “settling up” with Meleager. In fact, settling is exactly what the act of diorthôsis (“setting to right”) implies – the “sticker price” was not necessarily the final price.Footnote 40

Quoted in the moral register of setting to right, the 448 drachmas and 1.5 obols may have sounded like a just price, given the circumstances. An implicit contrast is then drawn with Eumenes’ own conveyance of Sibloe back into the patrimony of Zeus Stratios. Trenchantly, that transaction is described as “without price (ἄνευ τιμῆς).” For the king who forgoes a sale, earmarking becomes an arena for the display of a particularly economic royal virtue. That we are told that the final transfer of the village to the cult was a specifically priceless conveyance is an indication of what is at stake when it comes to earmarking. One must describe these transactions, and description is a gambit of ideological risks and rewards. Without a price, Eumenes and Apollonioucharax meet at a point, as it were, above and beyond the market.Footnote 41 In the end, neither party assumes the dreaded role of buyer. Yet what of Meleager, the original buyer? We can only guess at how he really fared in all this. If he had not as yet collected the usufruct of the village and marketed it, the whole business would have at best approximated an interest-free loan to Apollonioucharax for whatever period of time had elapsed since the original sale. If he had collected anything at all, this was profit, maybe even a windfall, if on account of the tumult of war the revenues of Sibloe were unlikely to equal 448 drachmas and 1.5 obols any time soon. We should note that the inscription makes clear that some partial collection of taxes has already taken place: the remission of arrears explicitly excludes those taxes that are already in the hands of tax farmers (Side B Lines 7–9).

It is impossible to know what became of Meleager. However, to focus on one of the key relationships in earmarking – the king and his private business partner – it is necessary to speculate. One can compare the Lycian dynast Ptolemaios, who transferred land to another katoikia town, the Kardakon Kome near Telmessos, but did not receive the money promised from the community in return. In a letter of 181, Eumenes II freed the Kardakoi from their debt, even if, he added, they happened to have the money on hand (SEG XIX 867; D3, lines 7–10). Just as in the case of Meleager and Apollonioucharax, the fate of the Lycian creditor Ptolemaios or his heirs is effaced. Presumably, Eumenes settled up with them, too. In both cases, we can infer that private third parties transacted with the king over the fate of subject communities. The inscription from Taşkuyucak shows the Attalid king purchasing private property in order to provide a source of revenue for an earmark. Indeed, it is one more piece of evidence to belie the old scholarly notion that only two forms of land tenure existed in Hellenistic Asia Minor: royal/nonprivate land and the territory (chora) of the polis, on which private property existed alongside public.Footnote 42 In fact, private property has a distinctly high profile in earmarking.

However, the full significance of Eumenes’ purchase becomes clear only when we can see it as part of a reciprocal exchange with the community of Apollonioucharax. With the diorthôsis, the king brought to an ethical conclusion a transaction that had not gone according to the original participants’ plan. We should note that Eumenes does nothing to perpetuate the relationship with Meleager. He does not ask the land-distributor Lykinos to find a different village for Meleager. It seems that Meleager just walks away with the money that he receives from the royal treasury. By contrast, the earmarking arrangement construes the relationship between king and community as fixed and everlasting. The earmarking of revenues for sacrifice takes the form of a purpose clause that contains the almost atemporal verb ὑπάρχειν in the subjunctive.Footnote 43 The agreement is open-ended and eternal. One does not dare imagine a time when the revenue stream will not provide for sacrifices.Footnote 44 Eumenes promises that the village of Sibloe will remain perpetually earmarked. And while Apollonioucharax and its priest may avoid negotiating any further with Meleager, they are involved in an exchange with Eumenes. They are now responsible for the cost of revenue collection in the village. In turn, they will perform sacrifices to Zeus Stratios on the king’s behalf.

The inscription from Taşkuyucak may also illuminate the transactions echoed in a very fragmentary text found in Pergamon itself, long known but poorly understood (RC 48; D4). A lamentable four discrete fragments of it survive. It is a letter of Eumenes II to the Aeolian polis of Temnos, a city of the old kingdom. The Attalids likely had an especially good knowledge of local institutions in Temnos. The city had even exchanged political rights (isopoliteia) with Pergamon in predynastic days, which makes it all the more intriguing to find in Temnos those same dynamics of earmarking that proliferated in the new territories.Footnote 45 Bradford Welles could not interpret any further what he termed “certain subsidies” of Eumenes II for Temnos, but he saw in this inscription the same “financial policy” as that instantiated in the Korragos Decree.Footnote 46 In other words, the Temnos letter was another important building block in the early twentieth-century theory of Attalid penetration into civic finance.

The crucial passages are in Fragment D. Welles’ text here, however, must be used with caution, as he himself admitted. Though the script is “fine and even,” the right margin of Fragment D, the measure by which he determined line length elsewhere, is irregular. Francis Piejko, who has published several major restorations of Fragment D, provides slightly different line numbers.Footnote 47 According to the text of Welles, the opening lines of Fragment D tell us: (1) land had been purchased (πε]πραμένης χ[ώρας); (2) a 1/10 tax (dekate) on agricultural produce was at issue (μ]έρη τῆς δεκ[άτης); and (3) funds are being earmarked for the city’s administration (εἰς τὴν διο]ίκησιν τῆ̣[ς π]όλεως καὶ̣ […). Welles asks an important question: “Does this mean that crown land had been sold to the city, from which a part of the revenue would be available for the city’s running expenses?”Footnote 48

The model of Apollonioucharax and Sibloe, Eumenes II and Meleager, suggests a different interpretation. In the case of Temnos too, a third party – a private property owner – is likely lurking. Again, earmarking entails recourse to the purchase of private property. The reasoning behind this supposition is both methodological and philological. First, Welles takes as his starting point the old conception of land tenure in Hellenistic Asia Minor as a two-tiered system consisting of royal land and polis territory, with no place for private property of any form beyond the chora of the poleis. This view is now untenable. Eumenes is the buyer, not the seller. We can note that the king divides up his purchase into “parts” (μέρος [D 14]; μέρη [D3]).Footnote 49 Further, the postulated earmark will feed Temnos “every year” (κατ᾽ ἑνια[υτὸν [D15 and 16]). While Piejko’s bold restorations are unsustainable, they suggest a general framework for interpretation. He has restored, first, the remission of two parts of the dekate and, second, an earmark for the purpose of “sacred things” (hiera) and “the administration of the city (dioikesis tes poleos),” the source of which will be the revenues from a stoa that the king undertakes to build.Footnote 50 Yet this restoration does not solve the problem posed by Welles of the purchased land. In the remainder of Fragment D, nothing is said of a stoa, but in fact everything concerns the fiscal status of land. Mention of a place called the Bomitis, of an official land survey (katametresis), and of the notification of an official named Pyrrhos regarding the act of “taking over” (paralêpsis) land follows a series of illegible fiscal prescriptions.Footnote 51 The land at issue may have once been part of a gift estate granted in early Hellenistic times, or it may have fallen more recently into private hands through public borrowing and default. The point is that Eumenes must purchase this land in the process of constructing an earmark for Temnos. Once set in motion, the mechanics of earmarking trigger a sale.

Brokering the Earmark

Though earmarks at times required the Attalids to take on the risks of transacting with private third parties, the community’s input was also crucial. Other documents depict the civic elites who served as ambassadors to the court and its regional outposts brokering earmarks. Local leaders used their embassies to negotiate the terms of earmarks and therefore the impact of Attalid power on their cities. By nature, earmarks are ad hoc solutions to local problems. With information scarce, local people represented their own problems to the Attalid state, and in the end, local people gained even more agency by helping execute the earmark. As coauthors of these line items, the Pergamene chancery and local elites, quite simply, needed each other.

The role of a man named Apollonios in the creation of an earmark for Ionian Metropolis is on display in an inscription that records his city’s appreciation for his deeds (I.Metropolis 1; D5). Metropolis was a minor city of the Kayster Valley, easily overshadowed by Ephesus. Little of its Hellenistic remains have come to light, but strong ties to imperial Pergamon are evidenced by an altar of Attalos II, a dedication to Queen Apollonis, a private association’s use of the regnal year in a dating formula, and the local onomasticon – Apollonios’ father was named Attalos.Footnote 52 A decree for Apollonios on one side of the stone dates itself to 144/3, the fifteenth year of the reign of Attalos II. Metropolis praises Apollonios for a life full of service, listing his good deeds, while all along emphasizing that his stature outstripped humble Metropolis. Insofar as Apollonios spent time in other cities, the fair reputation he earned abroad redounded to the benefit of Metropolis. Back home, citizens could count on him in a pinch to travel away again on embassies “to kings and others” (Side B lines 12–13). Owing to his characteristic perseverance and sacrifice of private advantage to public, the embassies accomplished the city’s aims.

What follows then are three positive outcomes of embassies. These are presented in a narrative passage that is closed by one final sentence before the formal expression of motivation: “(and) in all other respects he consistently engages in politics (πολιτευόμενος διατελεῖ) incorruptibly and eagerly” (Side B line 27). The three positive outcomes are as follows. First, in land disputes with neighbors, likely with Colophon, Smyrna, or Ephesus, or with some combination of such adversaries, Apollonios saw to it that the city suffered no loss. Here, editors Boris Dreyer and Helmut Engelmann, as well as Christopher Jones, who has challenged many of their interpretations, hypothesize an embassy not to the king but to the Attalid governor in Ephesus.Footnote 53 We do know that such an official (strategos) was responsible for the Kaystrian plain.Footnote 54 Next, a dispute with a mysterious group of tax farmers drew Apollonios into a formal arbitration (diakrisis) (Side B line 23). Who presided? We are not told, though we know that the Attalids settled a fiscal dispute between Parion and Priapos.Footnote 55 The tax farmers had in some way altered the fiscal status of Metropolis with respect to the “Kaystrian harbor (limen Kaïstrianos)” (Side B line 20).

The result of the embassy seems to have been a return to the status quo: Metropolis received its tax privilege back. Yet perhaps the city gained even more in the bargain. It is curious that the third and final good deed of Apollonios is not set off like the other two with an introductory clause. For the story about the land dispute: κατά τε τὰς γινομένας πρὸς τοὺς παρακειμένους ὑπὲρ χώρας ἀμφιζβητήσεις (“concerning the disputes that had risen with the other parties over land”; Side B line 14). For the story about the harbor taxes: ὑπὲρ τῶν ἐφευρισκομένων ἡμεῖν τελῶν (“over the taxes that had been invented for us”; Side B line 19). However, for the third case, we have only a pair of conjunctive particles: δὲ καὶ (Side B line 24). Here, Apollonios obtained (ἐξεπορίσατο in Side B lines 23–24) from the Attalid king an earmark of 500 drachmas for oil for the youth of the gymnasium (neoi) and 500 drachmas for lessons for freeborn youth each year (καθ’ ἕκαστον ἐνιαυτὸν) (Side B line 25). In other words, Apollonios facilitated Attalid participation in the year-by-year financial planning of Metropolis. When did he secure the earmark? Jones does not treat the issue directly, but he counts at least two embassies. “Since the text praises Apollonios just above for his embassies to ‘the kings and to the others’ (12), both issues, that of the land and that of the tax-farmers, must have required recourse either to one of the kings or to an official.”Footnote 56 And what of that other issue, who will pay for oil for the gymnasium and for the education of the freeborn youth? The text holds out the possibility that Apollonios used the same embassy to obtain both the old fiscal regime for the Kaystrian harbor and the two annual pledges of 500 drachmas. This is why we lack a new introductory clause after the story of the tax-farming dispute concludes. The process of repealing the harbor taxes may have resulted in a new earmark.Footnote 57 Certainly, Apollonios used an identical channel of communication in each case.

The Metropolis inscription points to the active participation of local notables like Apollonios in the process of cobbling together earmarks. Thus, alternative reconstructions, in which minimal interaction precedes an earmark, are to be rejected.Footnote 58 On that model, cities simply petition for benefactions, and kings reply. Or kings seem to parachute into local contexts, rearrange cities’ budgets, and leave. Earmarks, however, require intermediation and, therefore, the devolution of agency. In the Attalid kingdom, earmarking required subjects to participate in their own governance. The interactive character of earmarking was also showcased in an incident that took place in Apameia in the mid-160s, a city which then once again found itself at the center of a conflict, the aforementioned war with the Galatians. Kephisodoros son of Ariston was a leading citizen of Apameia and perhaps also a courtier.Footnote 59 For Apameia, he clearly played an important role in public finance. One of his descendants may have served as the city’s financial administrator in the first half of the first century BCE.Footnote 60 For Pergamon, Kephisodoros was a key supporter stationed in one of the kingdom’s lynchpin cities. A decree of Apameia honors him for erecting statues of the royal family during his tenure as gymnasiarch, while also maneuvering to set conditions on an earmark (D6 lines 1–16):

Decreed by the Council. Since Kephisodoros son of Ariston is a good and noble man, whose deeds are worthy both of the reputation of his ancestors and of his own love of goodness; both earlier when he made demonstrations ever fitting his character and benefited the People, he met with appropriate honors, which have been set down in decrees inscribed about him; and from that time up until now he has not let off excelling in all earnestness for the commons and showing a love of honor, and always doing whatever was advantageous for the People, serving as gymnasiarch [splendidly with his own funds?], and when he was honored by neoi, he dedicated statues of Eumenes and Attalos the brother of the king; and now, with the King having granted 3,000 drachmas, to [our?] People who provided grain to the soldiers in the war and in many other needs of war [?] furnishing fine demonstrations of our goodwill towards the king’s affairs, he [Kephisodoros] has made on behalf of the King a dedication of [X many] drachmas on condition that every year there shall be an assembly [in the gymnasium] of the ephebes and the boys of the gymnasium (paides) when they celebrate the Hermaia and Heraklea …

The document shows the Attalid king magnanimously rewarding a city’s loyalty with a cash subsidy, but also relinquishing a certain amount of control over the shape of an earmark. It highlights the degree to which earmarking devolves agency. Initially, Eumenes II had promised Apameia 3,000 drachmas as a reward for providing grain and other assistance to Attalid troops operating nearby during the recent war.Footnote 61 Kephisodoros, however, then modified the king’s gift in two different ways. First, he added more money to the original grant, a top-up dedication vowed on behalf of the king. Second, surprisingly, he attached conditions to the gift: Apameia would receive the money provided that a gathering of ephebes and other youths of the gymnasium took place each year at the festival of the Hermaia and the Heraklea. This event may also have been the legally prescribed occasion for the public proclamation of his own honors.Footnote 62 We can safely assume that the money promised, the start-up capital for a foundation, was earmarked to pay for these festivals. Yet the grammar of a provisory clause is unusual for an earmarking arrangement. The typical construction is: apo + genitive (source); then eis + accusative (purpose). On the other hand, ἐφ’ ᾦ ἔσται (“on the condition that …”) may be proper to the language of dedications. One can compare a late second-century Delphic manumission that vows a slave to Apollo, according to the convention, “on the condition that the slave be free (ἐφ’ ὧιτε ἐλεύθερον εἶμεν)” (SGDI II 2086 line 7). While its grammar may be unusual, by introducing the contingency of the young men’s synod, the decree of Apameia for Kephisodoros exposes what may have been a commonplace: a local agent succeeded in altering the terms of an Attalid earmark. For the king, the dedication of his money to a divinity always provided a measure of security against repurposing. However, it was invariably the local councils and assemblies that enshrined foundations in law and encased subventions in the procedures and rituals of civic finance. For Attalid subjects, earmarking provided numerous opportunities to exercise their own agency.

The anecdote raises a series of important if ultimately unanswerable questions. Do the citizens receive the king’s 3,000 drachmas with strings attached? In other words, did Kephisodoros, who tacked on his own contribution to the king’s gift, change the earmarking arrangement? In short, who is the author of the earmark? As the local gymnasiarch, Kephisodoros had converted his own honors into honors for the royal family in the form of a statue group (lines 10–11). So he plainly conducted his local affairs against the backdrop of the kingdom at large. His interests were certainly not at odds with those of the Attalids nor, however, were the two identical. By making an annual assembly of the gymnasium a condition, he may have guaranteed himself perennial public honors that were not available at all in any other forum. This means that Eumenes was not solely responsible for the Apameia earmark, manipulating Kephisodoros and using his stature in his community to legitimate an intrusive intervention in civic affairs. Rather, Kephisodoros’ piggy-backing of his contribution on top of the king’s gift speaks to the frequent division of agency in earmarking.

This last-minute rider to a royal writ reminds us how much local agency is unleashed in the earmarking process. On the one hand, the implementation is left to those on the ground, which entails tasks of coercion and the monitoring of the arrangement. As we have noted, the settlers of Apollonioucharax and the priests of Zeus Stratios received from the Attalids not just the right but also the responsibility to collect revenue from the village of Sibloe. In the very complaint of those settlers that other dependent villages had not been returned to them in the manner Eumenes II authorized, we may have an admission of failure in the implementation of an earlier earmark (D2, Side B lines 20–21). On the other hand, the creation of earmarking arrangements implicates multiple agencies from the start because earmarks are tailored to highly local circumstances. Infamously, this is what is called “pork-barrel spending” in the United States. There is no one-size-fits-all earmark. Kephisodoros occupied a privileged niche in the social hierarchy of the kingdom. He was therefore in a position to frame the needs of his city before the king, to be part of the conversation that ends with an earmark.

Certain documents give the impression that the king’s only role was to provide money. The royal treasury (to basilikon) dispensed the capital for a foundation of the city’s choosing, or made annual payments to a slush fund bearing the opaque name “for the administration (dioikesis) of the city” (D1 line 11). Left unexpressed, the source of the money can appear inconsequential. How the money is invested and differentiated between the various organs of civic finance and their attendant ideological categories, even the particular type of money, which currency, is on this account the city’s prerogative alone. The Attalids do not actively participate in the social process of earmarking, or so it appears. A notable example is a decree of Teos that describes the establishment of a foundation for the support of an actors’ guild, the koinon of Dionysian technitai, the powerful, inter-city association that would eventually spar with Teos over festival revenues, prompting an Attalid mediation (SEG II 580; D7).Footnote 63 Its date is placed variously after 188 or at the end of the third century, late in the reign of Attalos I.Footnote 64 This text is most often cited as surefire evidence for Attalid intervention in city finance in the form of a fund, “for the administration (dioikesis) of the city” (lines 17–18).Footnote 65 Attalid money, which is earmarked for the general administration of the city, grants Teos financial flexibility and security. To create the actors’ foundation, citizens combined 3,000 drachmas of royal dioikesis funds with 3,000 drachmas of city money. Interestingly, this latter amount was twice re-earmarked: it is filched from the grain fund, which was formerly known as the fortification fund! The combination of Attalid and civic monies is facilitated by the merging of the civic and royal financial calendars: on taking up their office, the city’s treasurers receive 3,000 drachmas as the first installment of the year’s royal dioikesis funds. The royal role here seems to begin and end with disbursement. The process by which the city arranges to provide for purchase of property to support the actors is complex, laid out in detail, and, as far as we can see, free of royal participation. The king, it seems, grants a certain number of subventions per year, and the citizens of Teos do with the money what they will.

J. D. Sosin argues that the Attalid kings played a similarly passive role in the establishment of four endowments at Delphi in 159/8.Footnote 66 Delphi lay far outside the Attalid kingdom but promised the Pergamenes a Panhellenic stage and the opportunity to politick with the Aetolians. Moreover, the city of Delphi was also a polis, with the requisite institutions to make the most of Attalid gifts so modest that Polybios may have singled them out for condemnation. The polis of Delphi stretched Attalid money into years of pageantry, cult, and public education. To summarize events, in a period of months, the city sent four embassies to Pergamon, which resulted in two gifts containing a total of four endowments. First, the co-regent Attalos II gave 21,000 attic-weight drachmas, labeled “Alexanders,” three talents of which were earmarked for teachers’ salaries, the education of Delphi’s citizen youth, and the remaining half talent for the celebration of a new festival in honor of the king and dynasty called the Attaleia.Footnote 67 One inscription describes the stringent terms on which the funds would be managed, splashing local rules about sacred and public money, guarantors and defaulters, across the base of an equestrian statue for Attalos II on which the text was inscribed (Syll.3 672). A few months later, the dying Eumenes II endowed a grain fund (three and a half talents) and another new festival, the Eumeneia (one talent). A second inscription records that Eumenes II also paid in those “Alexander” drachmas (Syll.3 671).

Together, the two gifts amounted to an injection of eight talents of “Alexanders” into a monetary system dominated by other, regional currencies. The so-called Alexanders, by contrast, were an international currency. These tetradrachms, whether or not they bore the face of the Macedonian conqueror, had been minted on the old Attic standard, meaning they now commanded a premium in long-distance trade.Footnote 68 For Sosin, this fact unlocks the dynamic that produced these earmarking arrangements. Because the Delphic elite planned to borrow the Alexanders at a lower cost than the price of that premium currency on the open market, they stood to gain the most from the arrangement, and on his account, would have plowed the coins back into international transactions. Sosin astutely demonstrates what certain Delphic citizens stood to gain. However, while this dogged pursuit of cui bono demystifies the claims of the ὅπως clause of the decree for Attalos II, which construes the whole affair as a royal plot to earmark interest “for all time” for the maintenance of sacrifices, the king’s own honors, and the teachers’ salaries, it papers over much of the complexity of the transaction.

Sosin describes the Delphic elite as “crony capitalists,” casting the Attalids as partners to a simple “gift exchange,” cash for honors. He writes, “Though these texts are inevitably studied as specimens of royal gifts, there is no reason to think that the idea to establish the endowments or the restrictions under which they were to operate came from Attalos or Eumenes. Both pairs of endowments were established only after Delphi sent embassies to the kings in support of the idea. Kings provided money. Rich Delphians provided initiative and ingenuity.”Footnote 69 The question of origin and invention here seems misplaced. Again, Attalid earmarks matched local wants and needs with the floating resources of a redistributive system. It took four embassies to produce the four earmarks contained within these two diplomatic acts. The rhetoric of Delphi’s decree was, in short: the city asked, and it received (Syll.3 672 lines 6–7). Beneath the rhetoric, however, the back-and-forth of the emissaries reflects painstaking negotiations. If not those details of the final arrangement subject to strictly local politics, then the basic shape of the earmark was bargained out. Cash or kind? We know that the Attalids skillfully deployed grain from surplus tribute in this economy of gifts. If cash, which currency? The Attalids traversed many different monetary systems and concocted their own. We can also consider the gifts’ amounts and delivery schedules; for royal honors, if a statue, its location; if a festival, its place on the religious calendar. All this and more was up for negotiation.

Institutions and Earmarking

The image of Delphi’s rules and regulations scrawled like a caption beneath the statue of Attalos II on horseback is jarring. High and low politics are combined. The king seems to get mired in the city’s red tape. One lesson to be drawn from the juxtaposition is that earmarking afforded the two parties an opportunity to gain familiarity with each other’s financial institutions. The more Attalid officials and civic elites shared information, the greater the prospects for fiscal and indeed ideological integration. Yet with power so unevenly distributed inside the kingdom, it must be demonstrated, not assumed, that subjects of the nascent Attalid empire offered kings a candid look at their finances and, conversely, that kings cultivated an interest in local institutions. Inscriptions brought to light in recent years provide two key pieces of evidence in this regard. The first is a dossier from Kyme in Aeolis, like Temnos, a city long in the Pergamene orbit (SEG L 1195).Footnote 70 The dossier emerges from an episode in the reign of Philetairos (either 280–278 or ca. 270), but it gives us a striking impression of an aspect of Attalid political culture that endured into the second century.Footnote 71 It consists of three documents: the decision of the beleaguered city of Kyme to send ambassadors to Philetairos urgently requesting military equipment, the dynast’s positive response, and a decree of Kyme on the administration and safeguarding of Philetairos’ gift, which also outlines his honors. Initially, the city had sent an embassy to Philetairos to negotiate the provision of a large number of shields for the protection (phylake) and security (asphaleia) of its citizens.Footnote 72 Philetairos obliged, confessing that while the competent Pergamene workshops had closed, he happened to have the shields on hand and would provide them as a gift.Footnote 73 We know that Hellenistic Kyme was particularly exercised by monarchical and oligarchical threats to its democracy.Footnote 74 Remarkably, we learn that the dynast who armed the citizens of Kyme also became a citizen of the Aeolian polis (line 30). Even further, the name of this super-citizen was etched into each of 600 shields alongside the name of one of the twelve tribes of Kyme. In separate musters, the phylarch (tribal leader) would have distributed shields bearing his particular tribal insignia – and the name of Philetairos.Footnote 75 The city’s proposal of an earmark, the circuit that connects centers of arms production at Pergamon and the customs houses of Kyme, appears in the first document:

συγχωρήσαντα τᾶγ γινομέναν πέλταν ἐπιχάλκ[ω]ν παρ’ ἑαυτῷ κατιστα|μένω ἀναλώματος δόμεναι ὅπλα ἑξακόσια ἵνα εἰς ἑκάσταν φυλὰν κα[τ]αταχθέωσι πεντήκον|τα, εἰς δὲ τὸ ἀνάλωμα τὸ ἐσσόμενον πόρον ὑπάρχην τὰμ πρόσοδον τὰν [ἀ]π̣ὸ τῶ διαγωγίμω σίτω|ἐπεί κε ἀποδοθέωισι τοῖς τε ἱρέ̣[ε]σσι καὶ τοῖς ἀρχόντεσσι καὶ [τ]οῖς ἄλλοισι τὰ προεψαφισμένα ἐπὶ|πρυτάνιος Λυσανία, τοὶς δὲ ἄρχοντας δόμεναι τούτων γραφὰ[ν] τοῖς πρεσβέεσσι.

(We ask that) Philetairos allow 600 of the bronze shields available to him to be given for the customary cost, so that 50 may be distributed to each tribe. As for the future cost of the shields, (we ask that) the means come in the form of the revenue from the tax on grain in transit – after the monies earmarked in the decree of the prytany of Lysanias have been apportioned between the priests, the archons, and the others. The archons are to give the ambassadors a written account of all this.

(lines 7–11)

While Philetairos chose not to execute an earmark designed to match his manufacturing resources with Kyme’s coastal ones, the encounter provides a model of interaction. Rather, in the end, Philetairos chose to trade shields for honors – not money. Yet the original proposal of Kyme forecasts a transfer of information. Kyme was prepared to buy the shields, but hoped to negotiate a good price by pleading for the “customary cost” (κατισταμένω ἀναλώματος; lines 7–8).Footnote 76 The city could not offer payment upon delivery, but promised future payment by earmarking taxes on grain in transit. To reassure Philetairos of creditworthiness, Kyme disclosed a great deal of information about its finances: still yet to be collected, the tax on grain in transit was already earmarked for a number of other purposes, but Philetairos, too, would get his money. In order to lay out the plan, the city’s ambassadors delivered to Philetairos a document called a grapha, a written account of Kyme’s fiscal outlook, perhaps including the master document known as “the decree passed in the prytany of Lysanias.” Philetairos, then, received a detailed map of Kyme’s finances. In exchange for the shields, the city had laid bare its institutions, the present state of its finances, and its projected revenues. The earmarking process continually fed the Attalids valuable information, which inevitably informed rational taxation and redistribution.Footnote 77

Kyme and Pergamon were old friends and once peers. Kyme even counted the dynast Philetairos among its own citizens. In such a city, the Attalids could hardly hope to revamp institutions to better fit their fiscal system or cultural preferences.Footnote 78 On the other hand, in the rural eastern territories awarded at Apameia, opportunities arose to tailor civic institutions. This was especially true at the moment when a new polis was born, when an Anatolian town was refounded with Greek institutions. Another new epigraphical dossier, this one from Toriaion in Phrygia Paroreios, depicts the Attalids gathering data on civic institutions, engineering them to complement their own, and founding public life on earmarking (SEG XLVII 1745; D8; Fig. 1.1). Under the Seleukid regime, Toriaion had been a katoikia, another multiethnic military town, the kind which occupied a rung just below the polis in the settlement hierarchy of the kingdom. Probably in the 180s, Eumenes II granted Toriaion the status and institutions of a polis in a process documented in the dossier of three royal letters. In the first epistle, the king addresses himself to settlers (katoikountes), in the second and third, he speaks to the freshly minted council (boule) and people (demos) of Toriaion. While it is nearly impossible to judge the pace of acculturation, the political transformation was decisive and momentous.Footnote 79 Desperate to solidify their sovereignty in the vast new territory, the Attalids turned Toriaion into an administrative hub.Footnote 80 They also ceded to it the ultimate ideological defense weapon, the title of polis, but not before predicating polis identity on paying taxes.

Figure 1.1 View of the Ilgın Plain, vicinity of ancient Toriaion, with Nodalar Höyük in the middle ground.

(© Yalburt Yaylas? Archaeological Landscape Research Project)

In the inscription, Eumenes gives the Toriaeitai permission to organize themselves, along with τοῖς μεθ’ ὑμῶν συνοικ̣οῦσιν ἐν̣χωρίοις (“those of the indigenous cohabiting with them”), into a single polity (politeuma), and to use their own laws (idioi nomoi) (line 28).Footnote 81 On the shelves of city archives around the Hellenistic world, royal orders (prostagmata and diagrammata) shared space with city laws. It seems to have been a common practice, even a standard practice in the Attalid kingdom, to send city laws up to the king for validation.Footnote 82 However, Eumenes presents Toriaion with an interesting choice. He demands that if Toriaion wishes to use its own laws, the city submit them for review, lest any of them conflict with “their” interests – or “his” interests, depending on whether one accepts the restoration of ‹ἡ›μῖν for ὑμῖν in line 30.Footnote 83 On the other hand, if the city wishes, Eumenes offers to coordinate even more. He promises to send the budding polis the full package: ready-made laws, a council, magistracies, civic tribes, and an oil fund for the neoi of the gymnasium.Footnote 84 This was no empty gesture. The Attalids vied for more than the elimination of legal contradictions smoldering in city archives. They urged the adoption of democratic institutions that were compatible with their own monarchical political economy, framing the choice for Toriaion. They set bounds around the field of legal production. The goal was to achieve the level of institutional homogeneity and interoperability necessary to implement an earmark.

In fact, an earmark did emerge from these negotiations along with Toriaion’s new institutions. Eumenes and the delegation led by a man with the Celtic name Brennos agreed to designate certain taxes collected in Toriaion for the purchase of oil for the new city’s ephebic class. In the second letter, the gymnasium of the polis of Toriaion gained royal support for its provision of oil.Footnote 85 For the time being (κα̣τ̣ὰ̣ τ̣ὸ παρὸν) – and here the political horizon is hazy – the revenue from the agoranomia, a certain market tax or fee, was earmarked for the oil. Eumenes ordered a financial official called the hemiolios to use his discretion in substituting a different set of revenues. While the nature of these revenues is imperfectly understood, they are clearly taxes on land, as the use of the term dekate (tithe; lines 41–47) implies. Of the third and final letter we have only the first few lines, but they mention another embassy. It would seem that the contingent and provisional terms of the earmarking arrangement laid out in the second letter had generated this second embassy and a third royal letter. As the new citizens of the new polis of Toriaion bargained out the shape of their institutions, they were also arguing with Eumenes over earmarks. The king traded benefaction for tax collection. The Attalids were not intervening in polis affairs so much as embedding their authority inside local institutions from their very inception.

Each of these anecdotes describes a recursive relationship between the process of arranging an earmark and the process of crafting institutions for the polis or the katoikia. Ambassadors met with kings to negotiate fiscal privileges, and when they returned home, they reshaped local institutions of public finance in ways that reflected new realities of domination. Or civic leaders aimed to shape local institutions in ways that maximized the likelihood of securing fiscal privileges from new rulers. The exchange of information and personnel between imperial centers and peripheries probably picked up in western Asia Minor during the stormy 180s, as both new hegemons, Pergamon and Rhodes, struggled to find a footing. Not only was sovereignty still shaky, but the Romans had left behind a quagmire of fiscal quarrels and territorial disputes.Footnote 86 Polybius writes:

Ὅτι κατὰ τὴν Ἀπάμειαν οἵ τε δέκα καὶ Γνάιος ὁ στρατηγὸς τῶν Ῥωμαίων, διακούσαντες πάντων τῶν ἀπηντηκότων, τοῖς μὲν περὶ χώρας ἢ χρημάτων ἤ τινος ἑτέρου διαφερομένοις πόλεις ἀπέδωκαν ὁμολογουμένας ἀμφοτέροις, ἐν αἷς διακριθήσονται περὶ τῶν ἀμφισβητουμένων.

After listening to the claimants, Manlius Vulso and the ten legates assigned to those cities that were disputing land, money, or something else, different cities that had been agreed upon to act as arbitrators.

(21.45.1)

Indeed, the Romans ruled on such issues in only a limited number of cases. For example, the cities of Chios, Smyrna, and Erythrai were all successful in petitions for pieces of taxable territory (21.45.6). Once the Romans left, Rhodes and Pergamon must have decided the lion’s share of cases. Unfortunately, we lack a well-documented case from north of the Maeander. Strabo merely alludes to a dispute between Parion and Priapus, settled by the Attalids (13.1.4). However, we can look to the Rhodian sphere to fill in the picture. The career of Pamphilos of Apollonia Salbake in Caria shows us how bargaining over taxes with the new regimes went hand-in-hand with the development and adaptation of local institutions of public finance. The decree in his honor reads (lines 1–27):Footnote 87

[When the ten legates from] Rome (were) settling (affairs) with Gnaeus (Manlius Vulso), the proconsul at Apameia, (Pamphilos) met them and conducted himself beautifully and fully in the interest of his fatherland. At that critical time, he neither looked away from the danger before his very eyes, nor did he dodge the distress, but he settled each matter with all his energy and love of honor. Later, when sent to Rhodes, with colleagues he debated our enemies among the enchorioi, and in the most advantageous way possible, he concluded an agreement with the Rhodians. Having completed many other embassies in the public interest, and on all of them, comported himself appropriately and managed affairs correctly, he was responsible for many of the city’s blessings. When the city’s finances were being administered messily, and there were regular discrepancies of account, he drafted and submitted to the Council and People a decree, which had the effect of saving the city’s finances. The men elected each year governed according to his decree with the result that there were no more shortfalls. In general, saying, writing, and doing what was best for the People in each situation, he continued to show his brilliant energy in everything which he did on behalf of the city.

The formulaic nature of the language of praise notwithstanding, it is clear that Pamphilos had an extraordinary impact on his city. With everything at stake, he had represented Apollonia’s interests before Manlius Vulso and the Romans conferencing at Apameia in the summer of 188. When his city was assigned to Rhodes, he hastened to the island to defend its interests. Among these, Jean and Louis Robert suspected, were the revenues of certain sacred villages in the vicinity of Caria’s Mount Salbake, a plausible conjecture, but one that depends on taking the ambassadors’ antagonists as indigenous Carians (enchorioi).Footnote 88 Christof Schuler, by contrast, has argued that the enchorioi are in fact “native” Rhodians hostile to the interests of Apollonia.Footnote 89 At present, it does not seem that Pamphilos played the culture card in order to secure his goal. What is important for our purposes is that at some point the energetic ambassador returned home to find the city’s revenues (demosiai prosodoi) in disarray and public monies gone missing. His technocratic solution, delivered in a lexicon more papyrological than epigraphical, was to overhaul public finance at Apollonia with a new founding document.Footnote 90 His decree (psephisma) appears to have functioned like a budget, preventing future shortfalls, in part, one assumes, by taking account of the recently formalized fiscal relationship with Rhodes.Footnote 91

Interaction with one of Asia Minor’s new hegemons may have spurred Pamphilos to reform. New institutions arrived in Hellenistic cities through different means. In this political ecosystem, cities constantly looked around at each other, which meant institutional change could occur through outright imitation.Footnote 92 When Teos and Lebedos needed a new set of laws for their synoikism, though, it was a king who urged them to take over the law code of a peer-polity, Kos (RC 3 lines 57–61). Sometimes, fear of nonconformity sparked a change. When the citizens of second-century Beroia noticed that “in the cities that have gymnasia and have established an oil fund,” there were also gymnasiarchal laws, they considered it only fitting (καλῶς ἔχει) that they pass those laws too (SEG XLIII 381 lines 6–8). Human mobility also played a role: when people moved about, they took institutions with them. Therefore, the many embassies of Pamphilos no doubt influenced his reform, for we find widespread centralization of public finance in precisely this period.Footnote 93 Perhaps his experience negotiating fiscal arrangements abroad had even conditioned what he considered “messily kept (μὴ ὀρθῶς)” books at home (line 19). If we accept that these sorts of interactions could affect a city’s choice of institutions, it is not difficult to conceptualize earmarking as an arrangement between ruler and subject that is the outcome of a social bargain struck in the name of a subject community by men such as Apollonios of Metropolis, Kephisodoros of Apameia, Brennos of Toriaion, and Pamphilos of Apollonia Salbake. In other words, part of brokering the arrangements was matching royal resources – not only cash, but the means of coercion – with civic resources – not only manpower, but institutions like public banks and the sacred repositories of temples.

On the Attalid side of the Maeander, the kings continued to deepen their familiarity with local civic institutions in order to use them as conduits and safeguards for their money, as well as tools for investment. Earmarking could not work otherwise. Beneath the bombast of self-advertisement lie humdrum details of institutional coordination. For example, in the winter of 167/6, the Ionian koinon, with the Milesians taking the lead, passed a decree that conferred a series of honors on Eumenes, including a gold statue, proclaiming him the common benefactor of the Greeks (euergetes ton hellenon). Ionian ambassadors, including Eirenias of Miletus, intercepted the king on Delos and presented him with the decree. While that decree does not survive, two other documents may contain portions of its contents. One is the king’s letter of reply to the Ionians (RC 52); the other is a fragmentary decree of Miletus found at Didyma (I.Didyma 488). In his letter, Eumenes writes:

ὅπως δὲ καὶ εἰς τὸ λοιπὸν ἐν τῆ πανηγύρει|τῶν Πανιωνίων ἡμέραν ἐπώνυμον ἄγοντες|ἡμῖν ἐπιφανέστερον τὴν ὅλην ἑορτὴν συν|τελῆτε, προσόδους ὑμῖν τὰς ἱκανὰς ἀνα|[θήσ]ω̣ ἀ̣φ’ ὧν ἕξετε τὴν καθήκουσαν ἡμῖν|[ἀνατιθ]έ̣ναι μνήμην. τὸν δὲ χρυσοῦν ἀνδρι|[άντα ποιή]σ̣ω μὲν ἐγὼ προαιρούμενος ἀδά|[πανον πάν]τ̣ω̣ς̣ [τὴν] χ̣ά̣ρ̣ιν ε̣ἶ̣ν̣αι τῷ κό[ινῳ].

In order that forever after, celebrating a day in our name during the Panionia, you should make the whole festival more illustrious, I shall dedicate for you sufficient revenues, from which you shall be able to make an appropriate dedication to our memory. I shall make the gold statue myself, preferring that this be a cost-free gift for the koinon.

(RC 52 lines 51–58)

At first glance, this looks like paternalism: the Ionians play no role in earmarking revenues for their own festival. The king magnanimously assumes the cost of one of several days’ festivities during the Panionia, and his subjects agree to rename the day in his honor, rendering him cult.Footnote 94 They propose a gift of a gilded statue, but he commutes their gold into charis – the intangible currency of gift exchange – and then orders them to erect his portrait in his sacred precinct in Miletus. It would appear that the king alone decides the source of this earmark and, moreover, that he determines without input from the Ionians just how much revenue will be appropriate. “This project,” writes Welles, “as far as the evidence of the letter goes, originated with Eumenes. It was not proposed in the [original] decree.”Footnote 95 As usual, we can only guess at the origin of the earmark. Yet our question is not one of first impetus. Rather, we want to discover the dynamic that produces the earmarking arrangement in its final form.

Welles points us in the right direction by suggesting that the earmarking arrangement anticipated in RC 52 may very well have resembled the one we know from a fragmentary Milesian decree from sanctuary of Apollo at Didyma (I.Didyma 488). In fact, the first editor of both documents, Theodor Wiegand, believed that the two inscriptions reflect the same portfolio of honors.Footnote 96 What remains of the fragmentary decree from Didyma is concerned with the financing of activities associated with the celebration of Eumenes’ birthday, rather than the king’s name day during the Panionia. Yet the institutional underpinnings of both royal galas were likely comparable. I.Didyma 488 mentions two foundations, one at the beginning of the fragment, the “revenues from the gift funds” ἀπὸ [τῶν πρ]οσό[δων|τῶν ἐκ τῶν δεδωρ]ημένων χρημάτων (lines 2–3), and, later, the “revenues from the maritime loans” ἀπὸ τῶν ὀφειλομένων ἐμπορικῶν|δ]ανείων (lines 24–25). The revenues of the first are earmarked for the festivities of the king’s birthday: sacrifices and feasting, a parade of ephebes in full armor, “and everything else according to the stephanephorikos nomos (wreath-wearing law) and the diagraphe (ordinance) of the priesthood” (lines 13–15). The revenues of the second fund, which are 30 talents of retiring maritime loans, are linked to a grain fund. That fund is to provide for a public grain distribution on Eumenes’ birthday. Each Milesian receives six hemiekteia of grain in an event that packages together citizenship, commensality, and fealty to Pergamon.

For Welles and Wiegand, the first foundation is certainly royal, while the second is also likely to be so, as it is under the control of two officials “appointed for the construction of the gymnasium”), one of whom is the same person – Eirenias of RC 52 with his Attalid connections. I.Didyma 488 may not be conclusive evidence for direct Attalid involvement with the Milesian grain fund, but it illuminates precisely what the statement of Eumenes in RC 52 occludes. An earmarking arrangement of enormous ideological import for the king, aiming as it does to implant the king’s name in civic memory, rests squarely on Milesian institutions. Eumenes’ gift of “sufficient revenues” presupposes Milesian cooperation. The king provides the seed money, while the city grows its own subsidy. This earmarking arrangement needs the public bank of Miletus and its personnel (lines 26, 31); local grain commissioners, who manage the fund in such a way that sufficient grain is produced (lines 17–18); and the legal guardrails provided by the stephanephorikos nomos and the diagraphe of the priesthood. Also aiding its chances of success are the procedural sanctions that Miletus institutes to protect against its dissolution or the repurposing of the funds (lines 46–49) – and even the facility of the Didymaion, which as the repository of the decree, lends it an aura of the permanent and sacred. Earmarking allowed the Attalids to profit handsomely from the elaborate organizational resources of the Hellenistic polis.

The Meanings of Earmarking in the Attalid Kingdom

If earmarking is a social process that produces meaning by differentiating money, which kinds of meanings did the Attalids manufacture with it? What made it such an attractive and successful solution to the problems of risk, governance, and ideological accommodation for a second-tier Hellenistic power on the rise? In the first instance, earmarking was a familiar fixture from the sphere of religion, which lent it legitimacy. At the most basic level, the practice of pre-designating portions of a sacrificial victim for the consumption of certain priests or particular members of the cultic community must go back far beyond our records in the Aegean. In the Hellenistic period, we know that priests divided up their revenues according to source and slated expenditure. On Kos, an extraordinarily rich picture has now emerged of revenues from the sales of priesthoods earmarked for cultic silverware and furniture, a theater, and other public buildings.Footnote 97 We can also look to Delos, where priests took up management of the treasury of the city of Delos for the first time in the year 192, neatly using jars to divide funds earmarked by civic decrees for specific public goods, their own working capital, and a reserve (I.Delos 399).Footnote 98

Moreover, earmarking specific revenues for cultic activity had long been a way of protecting them from misappropriation by the body politic, future magistrates, or other worshippers with their own ideas about the use of sacred wealth. For example, when the Athenians, in the time of Lykourgos, acquired a windfall, the new and soon-to-be controversial source of revenue known as the Nea, they earmarked it for the cost of the Little Panathenaia (RO 81). For Hellenistic and Roman Asia Minor, Beate Dignas has argued for the independence of cultic authorities, their sense of corporate identity, and the autonomy of the sphere of sacred finance in a study of temple administration.Footnote 99 Unsurprisingly, earmarking is at issue in one standoff at the heart of her study, the conflict between the priests of Zeus at Labraunda and the Carian city of Mylasa. That earmarking does not seem to have prevented Mylasa from claiming revenues that once belonged to Zeus Labraundeus is telling. Earmarking is one of the means by which priests and city magistrates in Dignas’ account articulate their different corporate identities. An earmarking arrangement may for a time place restrictions on public money, or create obstacles to its free employment, but these arrangements can almost always be dissolved. Accordingly, procedures were put in place for safeguarding earmarking arrangements that directed revenues into sacred coffers. The danger was ever present: we can see cities re-earmarking funds time and again through procedures like metaphora (reappropriation). The citizens of Delphi may have designated the cash gift of Attalos II as hiera chremata (sacred funds) to ensure that a charge of hierosylia (shrine robbing) would stick against anyone who diverted them from their original purpose, but they also took the extra step of decreeing fines for anyone who would so much as attempt metaphora, “by a vote or otherwise” (Syll.3 672 lines 15–18). An even wider repertoire of procedural safeguards is on full display in the charter of the foundation of Eudemos of Miletus (Syll.3 577 lines 64–66). Finally, in Pergamon itself, aspects of ruler cult in the reign of Attalos III depended on funds of Asklepios designated with the peculiar technical term ἀμέτοιστοι πρόσοδοι – nontransferable revenues (I.Pergamon 246 line 19). The Attalids could rely on the sanction of polis religion to endow their earmarks with lasting awe.

In Hellenistic cities, this administrative routine became a distinctive way to exchange gifts for honors. Of the many ways that Greeks bore gifts, earmarking puts the most emphasis on the creation of long-term bonds. In earmarking, the relationship of the donor to the recipient is conceptualized as everlasting, just as it is continually reenacted with each fiscal cycle. Earmarking puts the future at stake, while also securing it. The Attalids were demonstrating the virtue of providential care precisely when the future lurched into the epigraphic record. For many second-century philanthropists, both royal and civic, a gift’s worth was reckoned in terms of providence (pronoia). For example, a major philanthropist from Teos named Polythrous took forethought for his city (προνοήσας) when he established a fund for the education of the freeborn youth (Syll.3 57 line 3). Cities honored these benefactors for their providence, not for anticipating a rainy day so much as for troubling themselves with accomplishing the long-term goals of the community, in particular, the creation of continuity by means of regularizing revenue streams.Footnote 100 A few fixed points in the city’s fiscal landscape could go a long way in reducing anxiety about risk. The acceptance of Attalid earmarks was predicated on this culturally specific approach to risk. Yet the kings still needed to make their case, which is why the language of pronoia is so common in Attalid documents.Footnote 101 In an exhaustive study of the expression πρόνοιαν ποιεῖσθαι (to take forethought), J.-L. Mourgues even suggests that the formula was in origin a creation of the Attalid chancery, a diplomatic convention transmitted to the Greek-speaking administrators of the Roman province of Asia.Footnote 102

Yet pronoia was by no means the preserve of the Attalids in this period. We also find it in the civic epigraphy of Asia Minor: in the 180s in the Maeander Valley (Milet I 3 149 line 16) and ca. 140 in Cilicia Pedias (SEG XII 511 line 5).Footnote 103 One could see here larger-than-life civic benefactors of the later Hellenistic period imitating kings. A priest in Metropolis was praised for his pronoia, while the association that honored him dated its documents by the Attalid regnal year.Footnote 104 When the settlers of Apollonioucharax ask that “thought be taken for their needs (προνοηθῆναι),” we could see the Attalids snared by their own ideology (D2 Side B line 10). However, we now have an example of a different royal chancery boasting of “having taken the greatest pronoia (πλείστην πρόνοιαν ποιούμενοι)” in a letter of Seleukos IV, the so-called Heliodoros Stele of the year 178, a text published long after Mourges’ study (CIIP IV 2 no. 3511 line 14). In fact, the pronoia language of the Heliodoros Stele is echoed in several inscriptions from the city of Pergamon.Footnote 105 Clearly, the Attalids did not invent the virtue of pronoia. Rather, they embraced it, and they chose to emphasize earmarking because the practice instantiated this political ideal of capacious significance. Pronoia not only points to the future; it also projects an inclusive vision of the past. When a benefactor boasts of having taken forethought for his beneficiaries, he shares with them the deliberative process behind the gift.Footnote 106 By the same token, part of the meaning of earmarking was conveyed through a startlingly transparent vision of the kingdom’s fiscal structure: suddenly the subject caught sight of the logic behind royal patrimony. The thin membrane separating the city’s patrimony dissolved. In the end, earmarking arrangements bore the traces of social process.

The primary goal of this chapter has been to reveal the dynamics of earmarking in the Attalid kingdom. For Pergamon, the choice of earmarking presupposed knowledge of civic institutions, a drive to get to know them, even a desire to transform them. It also opened up a range of transactions with private individuals, all of which were conducted in the public eye. This encounter with private property owners, as much as the confrontation of city and ruler (Stadt und Herrscher), presented its own ideological risks and rewards. Throughout this chapter, the process, negotiation, and contingency behind the earmark have been emphasized in order to highlight the agency of subject communities. Was the Attalid state, then, especially weak? If measured by its capacity to penetrate society, it was in fact remarkably strong. Even the first leviathan-states of the nineteenth century, such as France of the Third Republic, built up their prodigious fiscal capacity by strategically dividing central authority.Footnote 107

Earmarking was neither simple apportionment nor the confiscation of revenues. Nor was it a matter of two states, one hegemonic, dividing up a single revenue base. We can contrast a case from Hellenistic Crete, where the polis of Praisos, having vanquished neighboring Stalai, took for itself half of Stalai’s customs dues, but left the rest, as well as “(the revenues of) the land, the city, and the islands that the citizens of Stalai now hold” (Syll.3 524 lines 3–8). In Attalid Asia Minor, earmarking created new sources of revenue, even as it obscured a community’s loss of autonomy or the transfer of its surplus to the imperial center. At once parasitic and redistributive, earmarking never involved the complete destruction of a city’s tax base or any of its means of cultural reproduction. On the contrary, as both the Korragos Decree and the Toriaion Dossier show, the Attalids preferred to employ earmarking in order to reconstitute or reorganize cities, or in the case of Apollonioucharax, a katoikia. Chiefly by rationalizing the impact of royal power on civic finance, this age-old administrative practice contributed to the success of the Attalid imperial project.

Footnotes

1 D1 = I.Prusa 1001. Trans. Austin 2006, no. 235. ἔδοξεν τῇ βουλῇ καὶ τῶι δήμῳ· Μενέμαχος Ἀρχελάου εἶπεν· ἐπεὶ Κόρραγος Ἀριστομάχου Μακεδών, τεταγμένος στρατηγὸς τῶν καθ’ Ἑλλήσποντον τόπων, διατελεῖ τὴμ πᾶσαν σπουδὴν καὶ εὔνοιαν προσφερόμενος εἰς τὸ συναύξεσθαι τὸν δῆμον, καὶ κοινῇ καὶ ἰδίᾳ τοῖς ἐντυγχάνουσιν τῶν πολιτῶν εὔχρηστον αὐτὸ[ν] παρασκευάζει, ὑπό τε τὴν παράληψιν τῆς πόλεως ἠξίωσεν τὸν βασιλέα ἀποδοθῆναι τούς τε ν[ό]μους καὶ τὴν πάτριον πολιτείαν καὶ τὰ ἱερὰ τεμένη καὶ τὸ εἰς τὰ ἱερὰ καὶ πόλεως διοίκησιν ἀργύριον καὶ τὸ τοῖς νέοις ἔλαιον καὶ τὰ ἄλλα ἅπερ ἐξ ἀρχῆς ὑπῆ[ρ]χεν τῶι δήμῳ, ἐνδεῶς τε ἀπαλλασσόντων τῶν πολιτῶν διὰ τὸν πόλεμον παρ[ά] τε αὐτοῦ ἐχαρίσατο εἰς τὰς δημοτελεῖς θυσίας βοῦς καὶ ἱερεῖα, καὶ τῷ βασιλε[ῖ] μνησθεὶς ἐξεπορίσατο σῖτον εἰς σπέρμ[α] καὶ διατροφήν, καὶ τὰς ἰδίας ἑκάστῳ τῶν πολιτῶν κτήσεις συνέσπευσεν διαμεῖ[ναι] τοῖς τε μὴ ἔχουσιν δοθῆναι ἐκ τοῦ βασιλικοῦ̣, καὶ ἀτελείας ἐπικεχωρημένης πασῶν τῶν προσόδων ὑπὸ τοῦ βασιλέως ἐτῶν τριῶν ἔσπευσεν καὶ ἄλλα δύο ἔτη ἐπιδοθῆναι, βουλόμενος εἰς εὐδαιμονίαν καὶ ἐπίδοσιν καταστῆσαι τοὺς πολίτας, ἀκόλουθα πράσσων τ[ῇ] τοῦ βασιλέως προαιρέσει· ἵνα δὲ καὶ ὁ δῆμος φα[ί]νητα<ι> ἀποδιδοὺς χάριτας ἀξίας τοῖς αὐτὸν εὐεργετοῦσιν, δεδόχθαι τῶι δήμῳ· [ἐπαινέσαι τε] Κόρραγον τὸν στρατηγὸν κα[ὶ στεφανῶσαι αὐτὸν] χρυσῶι στεφ[άνῳ — — — — — —

2 The unnamed city is commonly identified as Apollonia-on-the-Rhyndakos. On its relationship with the Attalids, see Aybek and Dreyer Reference Aybek and Dreyer2016, 12–14. For the identification of Korragos with Livy’s Corragus Macedo (38.13.3, cf. 42.67.4), see, I.Prusa 1001 ad loc.

3 D1, lines 12–13.

4 Holleaux (1924, 29) already recognized the rhetoric. On similar per sempre arguments, see Boffo 2013, 230. Cf. in CID 4 104, line 7, the tendentious claim of the city of Delphi to rights “comparable to what they have always had (καθὼς πάτριον αὐτοῖς ἐξ ἀρχῆς [ἦν]),” with commentary of Lefèvre, ad loc. Further on ἐξ ἀρχῆς, see Chaniotis Reference Chaniotis, Harris and Rubinstein2004, 192–93, esp. n. 35; Ager Reference Ager1996, nos. 37, 74, 126, and 129A.

5 D1, line 11.

6 Holleaux 1924, 25. Holleaux’s axiom that the practice always signifies an Attalid presence is no longer valid. It is twice attested under Antiochos III: SEG XXXIX 1285, from Sardis (213 BCE), and SEG XXXVII 849, from Herakleia-under-Latmos (196–193). Cf. also in this regard a case from Ptolemaic Halikarnassos, P.Cair.Zen. 59036. Three thousand drachmas in the royal bank, owed to Alexandria for the tax of the stephanos (crown), are applied provisionally to the city’s trierarchy.

7 Holleaux 1924, 25: “subvention réguliere.”

8 See Black, Hashimzade, and Myles Reference Black, Hashimzade and Myles2012, s.v. “earmarking”: “A linkage between a particular tax and a particular type of state expenditure. In the UK, for example, television license revenue goes to support the British Broadcasting Corporation.”

9 Source for data: Bringmann et al. Reference Bringmann, von Steuben, Ameling and Schmidt-Dounas1995. For high counts of the Attalids, see already Laum 1964, 14. The strength of the epigraphical habit in Asia Minor may have favored documentation of Attalid gifts, but not enough to invalidate the global pattern. The Seleukids had held the same inscription-rich territory for over a century, while the Ptolemies and the Antigonids both turn up enough in civic epigraphy to make the absence of their earmarks meaningful.

10 Source for data: Bringmann et al. Reference Bringmann, von Steuben, Ameling and Schmidt-Dounas1995. For the notion of Attalid miserliness in Polybius’ account of the reaction to the Rhodian earthquake, see Holleaux 1923. Holleaux suggests that Polybius has in mind the gifts of Eumenes II and Attalos to Delphi (Syll.3 671 and 672).

11 On prosodoi, see Gauthier 1976, 7–19.

12 See, e.g., the Athenian Grain-Tax Law of 374/3, which earmarks revenue for the stratiotika fund (Stroud 1998, lines 53–55). Stroud (1998, 78) writes: “Thus the 8 1/3% tax on the grain from the islands and the pentekoste eventually produced in Athens revenue that was earmarked in advance for this specific purpose.”

13 Just so, Rostovtzeff 1930, 605–6; Jones Reference Jones1971, 55.

14 Carruthers Reference Carruthers, Smelser and Swedberg2005, 356 (paraphrasing a textbook definition of Joseph Stiglitz); Von Reden Reference Radt, Pirson and Scholl2010, 1–6.

15 Earlier scholarship focused on the ways in which premodern or primitive societies mark money, supposedly in contradistinction to modern societies. For the modern world, see Zelizer Reference Zelizer1997.

17 Monopoly status was rare if not inconceivable in ancient monetary systems. Indeed, as Chapter 3 emphasizes, contrary to what is often claimed, the Attalids did not achieve it with the introduction of the cistophoric system. Even in the United States, it did not obtain for much of the nineteenth century.

19 Zelizer 1989 and Reference Zelizer1997. For a review of scholarship on the social meaning of money and its relevance for ancient economic history, see Boldizzoni Reference Boldizzoni2011, 160–61.

20 Zelizer Reference Zelizer1997, 21–25.

21 Douglas Reference Douglas and Firth1967. Indeed, tracking the movement of funds was a particular preoccupation of public finance in the Greek polis. See Fröhlich 2004a, 439; and on sacred finance in particular, see Von Reden Reference Radt, Pirson and Scholl2010, 156–85.

22 Walker and Carnegie Reference Walker and Carnegie2007 (on Australia of 1850–1920).

23 Zelizer Reference Zelizer1997, 25.

24 On this type of association and its administration, see Aneziri 2012, 72–73.

25 IG II2 1289. See SEG LII 132 (resuming Sosin 2002) for the conclusion that the orgeones did not prohibit the renting of the land as such, but only a certain kind of leasehold. For a new edition of the complete text and similar conclusions, see Papazarkadas 2004–9, 91–95.

26 RC 3, lines 72–94, esp. 73. For interpretation, see Gabrielsen 2011, 238–45. Gabrielsen (2011, 241) argues that the 1,400 gold staters were “excluded from the total revenue of the city,” i.e., from what Antigonos could tax. On the agency of these cities, see further Boehm Reference Boehm2018, 20–21, 102.

27 τὸ τοῖς νέοις ἒλαιον (line 12). The finances of the civic gymnasium are treated in Chapter 5.

28 Thomas Corsten (I.Prusa 1001) understands a single fund (“Kasse”) linked to two different public goods, sacred and profane. Cf. the decree of Colophon for Polemaios, SEG XXXIX 1243 Column V lines 51–53, in which it is equally difficult to distinguish grammatically a joint fund from a single-purpose one: ἀπὸ τῆς φυλακῆς καὶ τῆς διοικήσεως. For P. J. Rhodes (2007, 356) the term dioikesis does not refer to a “fund” at all, if by fund we mean treasury (contra Schuler 2005). It is the remainder of a subvention after earmarked funds have been taken out.

29 Similarity of script: Herrmann and Malay Reference Herrmann and Malay2007, 53.

30 The ordering of B before A was first suggested by Wörrle 2009, 427 n. 76; developed by Thonemann 2011a. This solves certain major problems of interpretation, but it opens up others. In general, the corporate identity of Apollonioucharax is curiously absent from the entire text. One place to look for it might be in the expression ἐπεὶ δημόται ἐσμέν, which Thonemann translates unsatisfactorily as “because we are poor” (Side B lines 10–11). Also left somewhat incomplete is his interpretation of the final lines of Side B, which clearly do not represent the voice of Apollonioucharax. He makes no mention of the stray letters below the text on Side B, engraved and then deleted, which Herrmann and Malay read tentatively as [α]ὐτὸς̣ ἒ̣κ̣οψα Ἱέρων (“Hieron engraved it himself”). Finally, on this interpretation Apollonioucharax seems to reprimand Eumenes for failing to return certain dependent villages to the katoikia. The tone of the reproach is striking and deserves further consideration.

31 [ - - 10 - -]ΡΕ[ - - 12 - - το]ύτων δὲ τῶν ΑΝ[ - - 12 - -][.]δριαι ἐπιγέγραπ[ται . . 3-4 . . ὑ]πάρχειν τὰ φιλάνθρωπ[α - - 8 - -] νας τῶν συναναφερομένων λιποστρατῆσαι ἐν τῷ β΄ καὶ λ΄ ἔτει περιελεῖν, ὑπάρχειν δὲ ταὐτὰ τοῖς ἄλλοις· τὴν ἀσυλίαν τοῦ Διὸς τοῦ Στρατίου ὑπάρχειν, ἀντὶ τῶν προσυνκεχωρημένων σταδίων ἑπτὰ ἔσται ἐπὶ στάδια δέκα· καὶ ἵνα Βάκχιος ὁ ἱερεὺς ποῇ στέφανον χρυσοῦν, τὰ ἀναφερόμενα ὀφειλήματα τὰ ἐν ἡμῖν ἀργυρικὰ ἢ σιτικὰ ἕως τοῦ τρίτου ἔτους ἀπολῦσαι, εἰ μή τινες πράξαντές τινα αὐτοὶ κατεισχήκασι· περὶ τῶν ἐνπεπυρισμένων καὶ καθειλκυσμένων οἰκίων ἐν τῶι προαστίῳ προνοηθῆναι, ἵν᾽, ἐπεὶ δημόται ἐσμέν, μεταδοθῇ τι εἰς τὴν κατασκευὴν αὐτῶν· Σιβλοην κώμην τὴν πρότερον οὖσαν ἡμετέραν, περὶ ἧς γέγραπται, ἵνα διορθωσαμένων ἡμῶν τὴν τιμὴν Μελεάγρῳ τῷ ἠγορακότι αὐτὴν δραχμῶν vac. ΥΜΗ – C ἀποδοθῇ, κομίσασθαι νῦν ἄνευ τιμῆς, ὅπως ὑπάρχωσιν αἱ ἐξ αὐτῆς πρόσοδοι εἴς τε τὰς τοῦ Διὸς τοῦ Στρατίου καὶ τὰς ὑπὲρ ὑμῶν συντελουμένας θυσίας καὶ διαμένῃ ἡμῖν ἱερὰ καὶ ἀτελής· τὸ δὲ ἀργύριον δοθῆναι ὑπὲρ αὐτῆς ἐκ τοῦ βασιλικοῦ τῶι Μελεάγρῳ· εἰς τὰ ἐλλείποντα τοῖς κλήροις καὶ προσδομ⟨ήμ⟩ασιν δοθῆναι κώμας· ἐπ⟨ε⟩ὶ αἱ πρότερον ἀφαιρεθεῖσαι ἡμῶν οὐκ ἀποκατεστάθησαν ὃν τρόπον συνεκεχωρήκεις, παραδεῖξαι Θιλευδον καὶ Πλαζειρα κατοικίας κυνηγῶν, τοὺς δ᾽ ἐν τούτοις μετάγειν εἰς ἃς ἂν κρίνῃ κατοικίας Λυκῖνος ὁ γεωδότης. – συντετάχαμεν γὰρ τούτῳ ἐπιβλέψαντι παραδεῖξαι.

32 [- - - ca.15 - - -]ΤΙ[- - - ca.8 - - - ἀπο]δείξεις ἐν [τῷ πο]λέμῳ Κουρνουβευδος· τοὺς δ᾽ ἐν τούτῳ τῷ τόπῳ κατοικοῦντας Μυσοὺς [ἐπενόου]ν εἰς Καστωλλὸμ μετάγειν, ἐπεὶ και[νὴ γῆ (?) παν]τελῶς [ὑ]πάρχει ἐκεῖ περισσή· ἐντυχόντων δ’ ἐ[μοὶ e.g. τῶν ἀπὸ] τοῦ Ἀπ[ολ]λωνιουχάρακος καὶ φασ[κόντων ἐπὶ (?) - ca.4 -]δ[- ca.4 -] τῆς χ[ώ]ρας εὐχαριστεῖν, ἐπεὶ δὲ ο[ἱ κατοικ]οῦντες ἐν τῶι Κ[ουρ]νουβευδει Μυσοὶ κατ[- - - ca.9 - - -]καὶ γεγόνασιν α[ὐ]τοῖς συνήθεις, βούλεσθ[αι - - - ca.10 - - -]αι ὅπως ἂ[ν] δι᾽ ἑαυτοὺς δοκῶσιν· ἐγὼ ? καὶ [- - - ca.12 - - -]ν ἀπ̣[ο]δεξάμενος τὴν εὐγνωμοσύ[νην καὶ με[τρι]ότ[η]τα α[ὐ]τῶν, τοῦτο μὲν συνεχώρησα ὡς ἠξί̣ουσαν, Λυκίνωι δ[ὲ] τῶι γεωδότῃ συνετάξαμεν [φροντίζ]ειν ὅθεν δ[υ]ναίμεθα χώραμ προσορίσαι αὐτοῖς· ἐπεὶ δὲ κατεφθ[ι]μένοι πέρυσι ὑπὸ τῶμ πολεμίωμ πολλῆς προμη[θεί]ας ἄξιοι εἰσίν, συγχωρῶ πρὸς οἷς ἐπεχωρήσαμεμ πένθ᾽ ἔτεσιν ἀτελείαν αὐτοῖς καὶ ἄλλων πέντε, καθὰ καὶ τοῖς ἐγ Καδοοις Μυσοῖς συν[ε]χωρήσαμεγ, καὶ ἀπὸ τριῶν τὴγ καταγραφὴν γ[ί]γνεσθαι· ὅταγ γὰρ ἀναγκαιοτέρα χρεία γίνητα[ι], αὐτοὶ διὰ τὴμ προθυμίαγ καὶ εὔνοιαν οἶδ᾽ ὅτι δώσ[ου]σιν πλείονας σ⟨τ⟩ρατιώτας· καὶ τῆς ἐφ᾽ ἔτους δεκ[α]τείας παρεθήτωσαμ πάντες, ὁμοίως δὲ καὶ οἷς τὰ εἴσφορα ἐπιγέγραπται· ἐπεὶ περὶ τὴν τοῦ χωρίου οἰκοδομίαγ γίνονται, καὶ ἡμεῖς λατύπου[ς] ὡμολογήκαμεν αὐτοῖς χορηγήσειν. vac. Γ vac.

33 I.Thespiai 58–61.

34 Polyb. 18.16.1–2. The sale/redemption seems to be the resolution of the transaction known in Greek as prasis epi lusei. To raise money for the First Macedonian War, the Sikyonians appear to have mortgaged property to outsiders, before defaulting. See Walbank 1957–79, ad loc.

35 Zeus “the army leader”: Henrichs, New Pauly sv. “Zeus.” On the Anatolian origin of the cult, see Parker 2017, 103. On the supposed inexistence of asylia outside of the polis: Rigsby Reference Rigsby1996, 20.

36 Chaniotis Reference Chaniotis and Chaniotis2010, no. 266; cf. Ricl 2011, 144 n. 3.

37 Lemaire Reference Lemaire2002, 183.

38 Thonemann 2011a, 8–9.

39 Herrmann and Malay Reference Herrmann and Malay2007, 51.

40 For διορθοῦσθαι, see discussion of Gauthier 1989, 20: “payer ou régler une somme due” (emphasis added). Cf. Thonemann’s translation of Side B lines 13–14: “it will be restored (ἀποδοθῇ) when we repay (διορθωσαμένων) to Meleagros the price (τὴν τιμήν) at which he bought it (ἠγορακότι).”

41 Angelos Chaniotis (Reference Chaniotis, Harris and Rubinstein2004, 203–4) treats the legitimacy of interstate sales of territory with regard to transactions between different kings and between kings and cities or koina (e.g., Attalos I and the Aetolians over Aegina in 210), but he does not discuss any between private individuals and kings.

42 Mileta Reference Mileta2008, 8–19.

43 See Hedrick Reference Hedrick1999, 421.

44 In her study of Greek foundations, the legal historian Anneliese Mannzmann (Reference Mannzmann1962, 147–51) identifies this tendency toward unlimited temporal horizons as “Verewigungstendenz.”

45 OGIS 265. For the designation of Temnos as “tributary” in this period, see Allen Reference Allen1983, 111; Allen’s sovereignty rubric, however, is based solely on the dubious criterion of “independent coinage.”

46 RC, 195–96, invoking Holleaux, Louis Robert, and Rostovtzeff for the Pergamene “financial policy.”

47 Piejko Reference Piejko1987, 724; Piejko 1989, 401.

48 RC, 197.

49 Noted by Fränkel, I.Pergamon 157.

50 For a harsh critique of Piejko’s method, see Gauthier 1989, 171–78. For the finance of Attalid stoa building, see Kaye 2016.

51 For a discussion of paralepsis, see the remarks of Corsten, I.Prusa 1001.

52 I.Ephesos 3407 and 3408. On archaeology, see Meriç 2004. Regnal date: SEG LX 1257. Onomasticon: Aybek and Dreyer 2012, 212.

53 I.Metropolis, 50–7; Jones 2004, 476.

54 SEG XXVI 1238.

55 Strabo 13.1.14. It is difficult to discern from Strabo’s report of Parion’s sycophancy (therapeia) whether the Attalid arbitration might have been in any sense formal. With kings, Sheila Ager (2007, 50) argues, “The line between arbitral and arbitrary is quite fuzzy.” On the other hand, for Dreyer and Engelmann, as well as Jones, the tax farmers are royal, which necessarily implies an Attalid role in the dispute’s resolution.

56 Jones 2004, 476.

57 This interpretation is also consistent with the translation of Virgilio Reference Virgilio2004, 264.

58 Scholarship has advanced two different versions of this model of royal-civic relations that posits minimal interaction. The earlier model presented strong kings, unconcerned with the local affairs of cities. See, e.g., Rostovtzeff 1941. More recently, scholars have tended to see a vibrant Hellenistic city, which can act unilaterally or in concert with other cities, setting its own priorities without royal approval or participation. Here see, e.g., A. Chankowski 2009.

59 Courtier: Jean and Louis Robert BE (1939) no. 400; Kephisodoros does not meet the formal criteria for inclusion in the catalogue of courtiers of Savalli-Lestrade 1998.

60 BMC 47. W. H. Buckler (MAMA 6, 173) suggests that the moneyer was the son of Kephisodoros, but the downdating of this second series of Apameian bronze to the late 90s–50s BCE by Ashton 2016 excludes the possibility. Also, if a kinsmen, he was not a homonymous one, since the BMC reading of ΑΡΙΣΤΑ/ΚΗΦΙΣ has proven correct (Ashton 2016, 423 n. 61).

61 The nature of that benefaction was obscured so long as the beginning of line 12 was read: [καὶ τοῦ δήμου, ἀργ]υρίου, and so on; and line 13 was read: [τῶι ταμίαι (?) τῶι ἐν τ]ῶι πολέμωι, and so on. The king belongs in line 12 and the demos belongs in line 13, for which see Jean and Louis Robert BE (1939) no. 400. Robert (1960, 124) gives a date of 168–166, which rests on the identification of the war mentioned in one of the crucial lines as the Galatian War. For confirmation of the date on the basis of royal titulature, see also Thonemann 2003, 104–5.

62 Savalli-Lestrade 2010, 73.

63 For the Attalid mediation, see RC 53.

64 However, for a date ca. 210, see Le Guen Reference Le Guen2001, 202–10.

65 P. J. Rhodes (2007, 360–61) seems to cast the intervention as extraordinary, while as Stefano Fanucchi (DOI: 10.25429/sns.it/lettere/GEI0041) notes, the future participle δοθησομένων reveals that these contributions were regular.

66 Sosin Reference Sosin2004. See also Domingo Gygax 2009, 176, arguing for a Delphic initiative designed to obtain benefactions from the king by proleptically offering excessive honors.

67 For the date of the co-regency, based on these documents, see Hansen Reference Hansen1971, 127. For the Attalid endowments at Delphi, see now Jacquemin et al. Reference Jacquemin, Mulliez and Rougemont2012, nos. 165–68.

68 For “Alexanders,” see Knoepfler Reference Knoepfler1997. On the reduction of the Attic standard and the monetary situation in the Aegean in this period, see Chapter 3.

69 Sosin Reference Sosin2004, 195–96.

70 Ed. pr.: Manganaro 2000; see also Fröhlich 2004b on the administration of the gift. See Hamon 2008 on Kyme’s political history and institutions, vicissitudes between Seleukid and Attalid influence and control.

71 Dates: SEG LIV 1230; Claude Brixhe BE (2001) no. 373.

72 See Hamon 2008, 86, 104. These key terms marked the decree with solemnity. Decrees deemed “for defense and security” formed a distinct class of public documents of importance at Kyme. It is conjectured that the historical context is a major incursion of Galatians in the second quarter of the third century.

73 On the Attalids and their workshops, see Robert 1984, 496–99.

74 The key documents are I.Kyme 12 and SEG LIV 1229. Epigraphists have dated both variously, with Hamon (2008, 102–5) arguing most recently for roughly the same third-century context as the Philetairos dossier SEG LIV 1230. See also Claude Brixhe and Philippe Gauthier BE (2005) no. 396.

75 For tribal organization in the military context at Kyme, see Kunnert Reference Kunnert2012, 301; for archaeological evidence for the convention of the king’s name alone as an emblem on Macedonian shields, see Sekunda Reference Sekunda2012, 18.

76 Cf. Bresson 2000, 183–206, on the “recommended price (kathestekuia time).”

77 Andrzej Chankowski (Reference Chankowski, Fröhlich and Müller2010, 321 n. 10) adduces the inscription as evidence for a robust civic army in the Hellenistic polis. A. Chankowski 2009, moreover, insists on the independence of polis armies in Hellenistic Asia Minor. The dossier from Kyme would seem to nuance those claims, as soldiers don a uniform that bears the dynast’s name, and military preparedness is predicated on fiscal coordination with the Attalid state.

78 In fact, the case of Kyme’s strategeia shows just how diverse civic institutions were in cities under Pergamene control. The Attalids, contrary to an old scholarly hypothesis, did not impose the strategeia on city governments. See Hamon 2008, 64–69.

79 Scholarship has tended to focus on the issue of the integration of non-Hellenes, the enchorioi of line 27 (cf. in line 27 of ed. pr.’s text and translation ἐν̣ χωρίοις “in the fortified places,” corrected by Schuler 1999, 128–29). Cf. Virgilio 2008, on a mostly indigenous population. At issue is whether Toriaion provides a paradigm for the assimilation of non-Hellenes into Hellenistic urban foundations or refoundations on the polis model. For Kennell Reference Kennell2005, it is the paradigm.

80 If Thonemann (2008, 51–52) is correct in assigning a so-called cistophoric countermarking authority to Toriaion, the site became for several decades a major administrative center.

81 The grant of idioi nomoi has – rightly or wrongly –prompted many commentators to compare the situation of the population of Toriaion to that of the Jewish settlers moved to Phrygia and Lydia by Antiochos III (Joseph. AJ 12.151). Gruen (2002, 17) has argued for the authenticity of the grant of Antiochos III.

82 On royal documents in polis archives, see Boffo 2013, esp. 205–7. While Gauthier (Reference Gauthier and Hatzopoulos1993, 48) considers royal validation of the laws and decrees of the polis unremarkable, several key examples are Attalid. These include the documents referred to in OGIS 329, honors for Cleon, the Pergamene governor of Aegina. From Olbasa in the Milyas, the decree in honor of the governor Sotas was also sent to Attalos II for review (SEG XLIV 1108).

83 Philippe Gauthier BE (1999) no. 509. Gauthier points out that the photo of the ed. pr. is illegible. According to Herrmann and Malay (Reference Herrmann and Malay2007, 58 n. 76) the inscription from Taşkuyucak (D2) exhibits the same mistake (or phonological ambiguity?) on Side B lines 16–17.

84 Here, one has to decide whether ἐπιτηδ̣είους is a substantive, i.e., a commission of men “ready” to craft laws, divide up tribes, etc.; or rather an adjective referring to the nomoi (line 31). The most recent editor, Bencivenni (2003, 124–25) understands nomoi as the referent.

85 There is debate over whether the gymnasium predates the foundation of the polis of Toriaion. See Philippe Gauthier BE (1999) no. 509; Savalli-Lestrade 2005, 14–15; Kennell Reference Kennell2005, 14.

86 For example, at Aphrodisias, see Chaniotis Reference Chaniotis and Chaniotis2010, 461.

87 Robert, Carie II, 303–12 no. 167.

88 Robert, Carie II, 307.

89 Schuler 1999, 129 n. 21.

90 Papyrological lexicon: Robert, Carie II, 310–11, e.g., διάπτωμα (shortfall), which appears just three times in Syll.3, but is a very common term in accounts on papyrus, e.g., P.Tebt. 3.2 894 Fr5, r, 2 line 8.

91 Pamphilos brokered a formal agreement with Rhodes: synthekai (lines 12–13). For Rhodian taxation of Apollonia Salbake, see Robert, Carie II, 306–9. Compare Erythrai, which passed a psephisma for dioikesis in the first half of the second century (I.Erythrai 112 line 114). According to Schuler (2005, 397), this template for the apportionment of public money best approximates what we would call a budget, and Pamphilos employed it at Apollonia.

92 Cf. the argument of the citizens of Sardis before Antiochos III (SEG XXXIX 1285 lines 8–10). The Sardians seem to know what taxes “other cities (allai poleis)” pay on workshops. Cf. also the suggestions of Schuler (2004a, 185–87) that civic elites modeled gymnasia at home on what they observed abroad.

93 See Migeotte 2006 on planification of public spending.

94 For this form of name-day cult (ἡμέρα ἑπώνυμος), see Habicht 1970, 156.

95 RC, 217.

96 Wiegand 1911, 27.

98 On earmarking and sanctuaries, see V. Chankowski Reference Chankowski, Andreau and Chankowski2011, 144–59. See also Pafford 2013, for priests’ intensive differentiation of monies deposited as cult fees in thesauros boxes.

100 Byzantine Greek may provide a wider semantic field for administrative pronoia, as the word comes to mean “maintenance” or “pension.” See Bartusis Reference Bartusis2012, 14–31; further on pronoia as a Byzantine fiscal concept, see Kazhdan Reference Kazhdan1995.

101 E.g., RC 53 Fragment II A line 2; SEG IV 632 line 4.

102 Mourgues 1995, 432.

103 On SEG XII 511, see also SEG LIV 1473. See also, e.g., SEG LXII 1489 line 16, from Rhodiapolis.

104 SEG LX 1257 line 7.

105 The language of pronoia alone may not give away the Attalid authorship of documents, but I do think it can be used to support dating royal documents to the second century. To give an Attalid example, Syll.3 270 is a letter of a certain King Attalos to the Cretan city of Aptera. The phrase πρόνοιαν ποῆται (“demonstrates providence”; line 3) suggests Attalos II or III. Inscriptions from the city of Pergamon: I.Pergamon 167 line 9; MDAI(A) 33 (1908) 375,1 lines 13–14.

106 Cf. Savalli-Lestrade 2003 on the elaboration of royal decisions.

Figure 0

Graph 1.1 Philanthropic foundations of the Hellenistic world.

(data from Bringmann et al. 1995)
Figure 1

Graph 1.2 Royal gifts of money.

(data from Bringmann et al. 1995)
Figure 2

Graph 1.3 Royal gifts of grain.

(data from Bringmann et al. 1995)
Figure 3

Figure 1.1 View of the Ilgın Plain, vicinity of ancient Toriaion, with Nodalar Höyük in the middle ground.

(© Yalburt Yaylas? Archaeological Landscape Research Project)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Eating with the Tax Collectors
  • Noah Kaye, Michigan State University
  • Book: The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
  • Online publication: 02 March 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009279567.002
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Eating with the Tax Collectors
  • Noah Kaye, Michigan State University
  • Book: The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
  • Online publication: 02 March 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009279567.002
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Eating with the Tax Collectors
  • Noah Kaye, Michigan State University
  • Book: The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
  • Online publication: 02 March 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009279567.002
Available formats
×