Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T14:11:31.085Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Dismantling the “Jungle”: migrant relocation and extreme voting in France

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 June 2022

Paul Vertier
Affiliation:
LIEPP and Sciences Po, Paris, France
Max Viskanic
Affiliation:
LIEPP and IC Migrations, Paris, France
Matteo Gamalerio*
Affiliation:
Institut d'Economia de Barcelona (IEB), University of Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Large migrant inflows have spurred anti-immigrant sentiment, but can small inflows have a different impact? We exploit the redistribution of migrants after the dismantling of the “Calais Jungle” in France to study the impact of the exposure to few migrants, which we estimate using difference-in-differences and instrumental variables. We find that in the presence of a migrant center (CAO), the growth rate of vote shares for the main far-right party (Front National (FN), our proxy for anti-immigrant sentiment) between 2012 and 2017 is reduced by about 12 percentage points. This effect, which crucially depends on the inflow's size, points toward the contact hypothesis (Allport, 1954).

Type
Original Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Political Science Association

1. Introduction and background

In recent years, the number of asylum applications in the European Union increased from 431,000 in 2013 to 627,000 in 2014 and approximately 1.3 million in 2015 (Eurostat, 2016). Given the high numbers of migrants reaching Europe and the future increased immigration projections both across and within countries, anticipating how natives respond when interacting with immigrants is crucial. Migrants will influence the labor force's composition, interact with natives in many commercial transactions, and influence politics both on the supply and demand side.

The considerable rise in the number of asylum applications and the difficulties experienced by European countries in redistributing asylum seekers across countries have drawn media, politicians, and scholars’ attention. However, the existing literature has provided contradictory evidence, as some studies show that immigration increases the support for far-right parties (Otto and Steinhardt, Reference Otto and Steinhardt2014; Mendez and Cutillas, Reference Mendez and Cutillas2014; Barone et al., Reference Barone, D'Ignazio, de Blasio and Naticchioni2016; Halla et al., Reference Halla, Wagner and Zweimueller2017; Harmon, Reference Harmon2017; Viskanic, Reference Viskanic2017; Brunner and Kuhn, Reference Brunner and Kuhn2018; Edo et al., Reference Edo, Giesing, Oztunc and Poutvaara2019), while others find opposite results (Lonsky, Reference Lonsky2020; Gamalerio et al., Reference Gamalerio, Luca, Romarri and Viskanic2022). Specifically for refugee and asylum seekers, Hangartner et al. (Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019) and Dinas et al. (Reference Dinas, Matakos, Xefteris and Hangartner2019) show that exposure to migrants on the Greek islands, but no contact with them, increases hostility of natives toward them and voting for the extreme right-wing party “Golden Dawn”. In contrast, Steinmayr (Reference Steinmayr2020) shows that the interaction between migrants and natives in Upper-Austria has led to a decrease in votes for the Extreme Right. Additionally, Dustmann et al. (Reference Dustmann, Vasiljeva and Damm2019) show that the effects of refugee relocation on voting behavior in Denmark differ across rural and urban areas.

This evidence calls for further research on the mechanisms behind these results. Specifically, what is missing in the existing literature is an analysis of the potential role of the immigration inflows’ size. It is poorly understood if small immigration inflows shape the anti-immigrant sentiment of natives differently than large inflows. This difference is particularly salient in the setting of asylum seekers’ migration. This knowledge gap makes it more challenging to develop efficient relocation schemes for refugees across and within countries. Many national and local governments refuse to host refugees and asylum seekers as they fear a rise in anti-immigrant resentment in places supposed to host the migrants. Hence, understanding whether the effect of refugee migration inflows changes with their size can inform policymakers.

A few reasons can explain this knowledge gap. First, it is challenging to separate the direct effect on voting behavior from the indirect effect through mediating variables. In many of the studies above, the effects are likely to be indirect. Large migration waves are likely to affect different intermediate variables, such as amenities, public spending, the labor market, or the local economy, which in turn affect voting. Therefore, identifying the direct effects is empirically challenging, as it requires settings in which indirect effects are negligible. Second, collecting information on the size and duration of exposure to migrants is a hard task that may require many hours of work. Third, migration inflows are not random, as many economic factors can affect locational choices (Ravenstein, Reference Ravenstein1885). Hence, one needs a source of exogenous variation in the migrants’ final location. The same requirement applies to the case of asylum seekers (Neumayer, Reference Neumayer2005; Hangartner et al., Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019).

Our setting enables us to deal with these challenges. We focus on the dismantling of the Calais “Jungle”, an encampment in the North of France. In October 2016, this illegal camp reached 6400 inhabitants (Le Monde, 2016), shortly before the government closed it and relocated the migrants in other areas of the country. Between October 2015 and 2016, the government relocated the migrants to more than 300 migrant centers called Centres d'Accueil et d'Orientation (CAOs).

This setting presents important advantages that we exploit in the analysis below. First, it is unlikely that the relocation affected the local economy. CAOs hosted the migrants for a short period (typically less than 3 months), during which they did not have the right to work. Besides, the central government paid the cost of the relocation. These conditions enable us to study the effect of direct contact between migrants and natives while excluding potential indirect effects. Consistent with this claim, in the analysis below, we show that migrants’ did not affect the local economic activity. Second, we collected information about CAOs’ location through a systematic analysis of local newspapers (Factiva) and combined them with a dataset that was publicly released by CIMADE (the main association helping migrants) on 24 October 2016. We also collected precise information on CAOs’ size. Among the municipalities that hosted a CAO, we find that, on average, these centers could host 31 migrants at the same time, which means 16 migrants per 1000 inhabitants.Footnote 1

Third, this framework enables us to link municipality-level variation in exposure to migrants to electoral outcomes. Specifically, we exploit the fact that the 2017 French presidential election was held after dismantling the Calais “Jungle”. We use the change in the FN municipal-level vote shares from the 2012 and 2017 presidential elections as the main outcome in our analysis and as a proxy for anti-immigrant sentiment. During the campaign, the rhetoric of the FN was anti-immigrant, referring continuously to the migrant crisis. The FN diffused this anti-immigrant stance through general and social media, public gatherings, and the party's election manifesto.Footnote 2

Finally, this setting allows us to deal with the potential endogeneity of CAOs’ location. More in detail, we estimate the effect of CAOs on electoral outcomes in two ways. First, we run a difference-in-differences model that exploits the fact that we do not observe different parallel trends in the elections before the dismantling between municipalities with and without a CAO. However, given the potential involvement of local governments in the allocation process, we cannot consider the assignment of CAOs as random.

Indeed, the French government could have chosen the location of CAO centers exploiting information unobservable to us. We rely on an instrumental variable (IV) approach based on pre-existing (i.e., built before the dismantling of the Calais Jungle) buildings that can accommodate groups of people to deal with this challenge. Specifically, we use two types of buildings that we combine in one instrument. First, we consider the number of “Holiday Villages” (“Village Vacances” in French) located in a municipality.Footnote 3 We expect a positive correlation between the presence of a CAO and a holiday village because one of the criteria used for choosing CAOs’ location was potential additional space in those holiday villages. Specifically, given that the “Jungle” was shut down mostly in October 2016, the holiday villages would be unoccupied at that time and could thus be used as temporary shelters for migrants. Besides, holiday villages were built mainly in the 1970s, much before the current migrant surge that led to the creation of the CAOs, and certainly not to host migrants.

Second, in line with the recent literature (Steinmayr, Reference Steinmayr2020; Gamalerio et al., Reference Gamalerio, Luca, Romarri and Viskanic2022), we consider the number of buildings such as homes for the elderly, disabled, drug addicts, and orphans that can accommodate groups of people. The idea behind using these buildings in constructing the instrument is that the government considered several venues, with a strong emphasis on buildings that could commodate groups of people. Besides, these buildings were built before the dismantling of the Calais Jungle and for reasons different than hosting migrants. Our instrument is equal to the sum of the number of these buildings plus holiday villages. Crucially, we show how the instrument correlates with electoral outcomes only for the presidential elections between 2012 and 2017 when the buildings could accommodate migrants due to the Calais Jungle dismantling. In contrast, we do not find any correlation between the instrument and electoral outcomes for the elections between 2007 and 2012. Thus, the exclusion restriction assumption (i.e., the assumption that the instrument must affect the dependent variable only through the endogenous treatment variable) appears plausible in this context. In addition, our regressions consider many potential covariates that control for municipal sociodemographic features and local politicians’ characteristics.Footnote 4

Depending on the approach considered, our main results show that the growth in FN's vote shares between the 2012 and 2017 presidential elections was between 4 and 12 percentage points lower in municipalities that hosted a CAO. Looking at the IV results, as the average increase of FN's votes over this period corresponded to about 20%, they indicate that the increase of FN vote in municipalities with a CAO was 40% of the growth rate in municipalities without a CAO. Our interpretation of these findings is that citizens developed greater acceptance toward migrants. The fact that we observe an increase in the vote shares received by the far-left party Front de Gauche, which had a more open stance toward migrants, but a similar political platform to the FN on other issues, further confirms our interpretation of the results. In contrast, the evidence appears to rule out that mobilization of voters and changes in electoral turnout drive our results. Besides, we find spillover effects on neighboring municipalities.

Importantly, our analysis shows that municipalities with smaller CAOs drive the main results. Our difference-in-differences estimates suggest that the municipalities in which CAOs negatively affected the FN vote shares hosted approximately less than 47 migrants per 1000 inhabitants. The IV estimates indicate a threshold of about 32 migrants per 1000 inhabitants. Above these thresholds, CAO's estimated average effect on FN vote shares switches sign and eventually becomes both positive and statistically significant for very large CAOs. This finding is consistent with the evidence that large inflows contributed to the rise of right-wing parties in many western countries.

Our paper provides three main contributions. First, the event study analyzed led to proper direct contact between natives and migrants, not to a short and transient exposure. Since migrants were not allowed to work, and the government covered the costs, our setting allows us to estimate the effect of direct contact while ruling out potential indirect impacts. As outlined in the next section, we believe this setting meets some of the conditions described by contact theory (Allport, Reference Allport1954), such as authorities’ role in supporting the contact between natives and immigrants. Therefore we expect a decrease in anti-immigrant sentiments.

Second, our analysis reveals that the negative effect can potentially become positive in municipalities with many migrants. This evidence suggests that natives may perceive the inflow of new immigrants as a threat to their social, cultural, and economic hegemony when the number of migrants received overcomes a certain threshold. As suggested by “realistic group conflict theories” (Blumer, Reference Blumer1958; Campbell, Reference Campbell1965; Blalock, Reference Blalock1967; Bobo, Reference Bobo1983; Quillian, Reference Quillian1995; Taylor, Reference Taylor1998; Sidanius and Pratto, Reference Sidanius and Pratto1999; Lahav, Reference Lahav2004), this perceived threat can potentially determine a rise in prejudice and anti-immigrant sentiment. However, given that migrants could not work, we do not think that the perceived threat generated by big CAOs should be due to economic concerns related to the potential competition in the labor market (Bobo and Hutchings, Reference Bobo and Hutchings1996; Scheve and Slaughter, Reference Scheve and Slaughter2001; Mayda, Reference Mayda2006). In the context studied, it is more likely that natives perceive the opening of too big CAOs as a threat to their identity and cultural dominance (Golder, Reference Golder2003). In addition, large CAOs may have made fostering contact between natives and immigrants more complicated, leaving the natives affected only by a pure exposure effect not counterbalanced by contact, which can explain the rise in anti-immigrant sentiments (Hangartner et al., Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019; Dinas et al., Reference Dinas, Matakos, Xefteris and Hangartner2019). Third, the evidence provided in this paper has a clear and direct policy implication. It suggests that governments should develop a more proportional relocation mechanism (Bansak et al., Reference Bansak, Hainmueller and Hangartner2017), redistributing refugees in a more homogeneous and diffuse way.

2. Conceptual framework

This section summarizes the main theories that drive our empirical analysis on the effect of the contact between immigrants and natives. It also briefly describes the predictions that originate from these theories and how they apply to our context. For more detailed reviews on these theories see the works of Paluck and Green (Reference Paluck and Green2009), Hainmueller and Hopkins (Reference Hainmueller and Hopkins2014), Hangartner et al. (Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019), and Dustmann et al. (Reference Dustmann, Vasiljeva and Damm2019).

We refer to two theories. The first is contact theory (Allport, Reference Allport1954), which describes how the direct contact between immigrants and natives can reduce anti-immigrant sentiments when the following four conditions are met: equal status between the two groups, common goals, intergroup cooperation, and the support of authorities. However, as suggested by the literature (Hangartner et al., Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019), it is difficult to find natural experiments and event studies in which all these conditions are simultaneously met. Besides, the literature has shown how direct contact can potentially reduce prejudice, even when only a subset of these conditions is met (Pettigrew and Tropp, Reference Pettigrew and Tropp2006; Paluck et al., Reference Paluck, Green and Green2019). Specifically, some scholars have suggested and provided evidence that contact between migrants and natives can increase knowledge about the outgroup, leading potentially to a reduction in prejudice (Pettigrew and Tropp, Reference Pettigrew and Tropp2008; Barlow et al., Reference Barlow, Paolini, Pedersen, Hornsey, Radke, Harwood, Rubin and Sibley2012).

The second stream of theories is the one that Campbell (Reference Campbell1965) labeled “realistic group conflict theories” (Blumer, Reference Blumer1958; Blalock, Reference Blalock1967; Bobo, Reference Bobo1983; Sidanius and Pratto, Reference Sidanius and Pratto1999). According to this theoretical framework, natives can potentially perceive the inflow of a sufficiently big group of immigrants as a threat to their social, cultural, and economic dominance. This threat can then lead to an increase in prejudice against the outside group and a rise in anti-immigrant sentiment. Consistent with these intuitions, Taylor (Reference Taylor1998) suggests that an increase in the outside group's size can lead to a rise in prejudice. Besides, Quillian (Reference Quillian1995) and Lahav (Reference Lahav2004) indicate that the largest is the size of the outside group, the highest is the threat perceived by the members of the dominant group.

Besides these two main theories, recent evidence in the literature (Hangartner et al., Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019; Dinas et al., Reference Dinas, Matakos, Xefteris and Hangartner2019) shows how the effect of exposure to migrants without contact can lead to an increase in prejudice and exacerbate anti-immigrant sentiments. For example, as documented by Hangartner et al. (Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019) for the case of the Greek islands, exposure without contact can exacerbate anti-immigrant sentiments when the arrival of big numbers of migrants can generate disruptions in natives’ everyday life. This disruption could be simply represented by authorities’ inability to provide basic services such as waste collection and medical support while dealing with the inflow of migrants. Natives can then perceive this disruption of everyday life as a threat to social order, leading to an increase in prejudice.

Which predictions can we generate from these theories that can guide the empirical analysis in the context of the Calais “Jungle” dismantling? According to the original formulation of the contact theory (Allport, Reference Allport1954), the contact between natives and immigrants should lead to a decrease in anti-immigrant attitudes when the four conditions described above apply. However, more recent investigations of the theory suggest that a subset of these conditions can lead to a reduction in anti-immigrant attitudes (Pettigrew and Tropp, Reference Pettigrew and Tropp2006; Paluck et al., Reference Paluck, Green and Green2019). In our setting, national and local governments had an essential role in managing the dismantling and the relocation of migrants. Hence, given the involvement of national and local authorities in supporting the contact between natives and immigrants, we can expect the opening of CAO centers to reduce the FN's vote shares. Besides, the small immigration inflows generated on average by the opening of CAO centers should have increased the likelihood of contact and intergroup cooperation. Finally, the contact between natives and a small group of migrants should have increased the knowledge about the outside group, potentially generating a prejudice reduction (Pettigrew and Tropp, Reference Pettigrew and Tropp2008; Barlow et al., Reference Barlow, Paolini, Pedersen, Hornsey, Radke, Harwood, Rubin and Sibley2012). Thus, based on the general features of the event studied in this paper, we expect the effect on the FN's vote shares to be negative.

On the other hand, we know that CAOs centers’ size was heterogeneous across municipalities, with some receiving more migrants than others. Hence, following the intuitions of the “realistic group conflict theories” (Campbell, Reference Campbell1965) and the evidence on the effect of exposure without contact (Hangartner et al., Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019; Dinas et al., Reference Dinas, Matakos, Xefteris and Hangartner2019), we can expect the baseline effect of the opening of CAOs centers on FN's vote shares to be heterogeneous across the size. Specifically, we can expect this effect to become smaller and eventually become positive when the centers’ size becomes sufficiently big. For example, natives may perceive the inflow of many migrants as an economic or cultural threat, or large inflows may make contact with migrants more complicated, leaving the natives to be affected only by a pure exposure effect. In conclusion, given the theoretical intuitions provided by the contact theory, the “realistic group conflict theories”, and the recent literature on the pure effect of exposure, we expect the effect of the CAO centers on FN's vote shares to change with the inflow size.

3. Institutional framework and data

3.1 Migrants and the Calais “Jungle”

The Calais “Jungle” was a migrant camp, which first took form in the late 1990s and grew following the European migrant crisis in 2014–2015, reaching a peak of more than 7000 inhabitants in 2015 (Figure 1). Therefore, the government decided to dismantle the camp progressively starting from October 2015 by creating CAOs, temporary reception centers established to deal with this crisis. These centers aim at receiving migrants who have not yet started procedures to obtain refugee status. They receive bed and board but no separate financial assistance. The average cost to the government is 25 Euros a day (Ministère de l'Intérieur, 2017). Migrants are meant to stay in CAOs only for a short period, usually three months, and then move to other reception centers.Footnote 5 Migrants who have started a procedure to obtain refugee status are redirected to the CADA (Centres d'Accueil pour Demandeurs d'Asile) while awaiting a decision. Between 2015 and 2017, the CADA places increased to 40,000 places (La Cimade, 2017). Other structures were also created over time, such as the AT-SA (Accueil Temporaire du Service de l'Asile—6000 places), the HUDA (Hebergement d'Urgence des Demandeurs d'Asile—15,000 places), the CPH (Centre Provisoire d'Hebergement—2300 places), and PRAHDA (Programme d'Accueil et d'Hebergement des Demandeurs d'Asile—5351 places) (La Cimade 2017).

Figure 1. Evolution of the number of migrants in the Calais camp.

The dismantling occurred between October 2015 and October 2016. The government reported having relocated 13,366 migrants of those more than 7000 inhabitants in October 2016. This event received considerable media attention (Figure 2, shows mentions for “Jungle de Calais”). To the best of our knowledge, the French government did not provide official information on the location of the CAOs. The total number of CAOs is also uncertain, with different government sources citing different numbers (more details on request). To circumvent this issue, we combine the manual collection of information with a public database released by CIMADE in October 2016. Using Factiva, we systematically searched for articles mentioning the terms “CAO” for each French départment. When available, we recorded the number of migrants. This procedure enabled us to recover 291 CAOs. We combined this information with a dataset provided by CIMADE, listing 210 centers and their capacity. The union of these two datasets results in 349 centers, close to the government's number in January 2017, namely 365 (Ministère de l'Intérieur, 2017). Therefore, there should be only a few CAOs missing, if at all. Hence, since we probably assign some treated municipalities to the control group, we would slightly underestimate our treatment effect.

Figure 2. Google Trends for the expession “Jungle de Calais”.

We also create a measure of CAO capacity through the following procedure. For CAOs recorded only in our manually collected dataset, we define a CAO's capacity as the maximum number of migrants ever recorded among all articles mentioning it. For CAOs belonging only to the CIMADE dataset or our manually collected dataset and the CIMADE dataset, the capacity is measured using the number of beds in the CIMADE dataset.Footnote 6 This measure of capacity cannot give information about the total number of migrants or the length of their stay. However, it informs about the maximum number of migrants that could be hosted at any point in time.

The second challenge is that the criteria of allocation of the CAOs have not been clearly defined, making the use of an instrumental variable approach important to validate the results. Even though the government announced that the allocation of CAOs across regions would be based on “socio-demographic criteria” (Ministère de l'Intérieur, 2017), no comprehensive list of factors was provided, except for the fact that the Parisian agglomeration and Corsica would be excluded.

Finally, the last issue to consider is the extent to which the mayors were involved in the allocation process. Although many mayors were contacted to receive migrants (Le Monde, 2015; Association des Maires de France, 2016), during the final dismantling, the Minister of Interior, entrusted the final decision to the local representatives of the government, i.e., the préfets.Footnote 7 The préfets would first identify suitable premises without prior consultation and then negotiate with the mayors. Even though mayors’ compliance is not generally observed, we exploit additional information about a list of mayors who publicly declared their willingness to welcome migrants. We use this list of mayors as an additional control variable in the analysis below.

3.2 French presidential elections

French presidential elections have been held every five years since 2002, using a two-round majoritarian system. If no candidate receives more than 50% of the expressed votes, a second-round is held between the two candidates with the largest shares. Our main outcome of interest is the share of votes received by the FN candidates in the first round of the presidential election. Figure 3 shows the geographic repartition of FN voters between 2012 and 2017. The FN's strongholds are the south-eastern and north-eastern parts of France. In those areas, more than 30% of the population voted for FN both in 2012 and 2017. One can also see that the FN vote increased substantially between 2012 and 2017 (by 20% on average).

Figure 3. FN vote shares in the first round of 2012 and 2017 presidential elections, (a) FN vote share—2012, (b) FN vote share—2017.

4. Empirical specifications

4.1 Difference-in-differences approach

The first approach that we use is the following difference-in-differences model:

(1)$$\log( FN) _{i, t} = \gamma_{0} + \gamma_{1} CAO_{i} + \gamma_{2} 2017_{t} + \gamma_{3} CAO_{i}\cdot 2017_{t} + \gamma_{k} X_{k, i, t} + \xi_{i, t}$$

Where log(FN) i,t is the log of FN votes shares in municipality i and presidential election at time t, with t = 2017, 2012; CAO i is a dummy equal to 1 if the municipality i has a CAO, and 2017t = 1 for the 2017 presidential election. In the vector X k,i,t, we find k control variables for municipality i and year t, outlined in the data described in the online Appendix. Specifically, we use all the socio-economic controls, political and administrative characteristics, and mayors’ demographics. We cluster the standard errors at the municipality level. The coefficient of interest is γ3, which captures the effect of CAO on the dependent variable. Then we modify equation (1) in the following version with municipal and year of election fixed effects:

(2)$$\log( FN) _{i, t} = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} CAO_{i}\cdot 2017_{t} + \beta_{k} X_{k, i, t} + \delta_{i} + \lambda_{t} + \xi_{i, t}$$

Where the municipal FE δi control for all the municipal characteristics that do not change over time, and the year of election FE λt control for temporal shocks that hit all the municipalities at the same time. The coefficient of interest in Equation 2 is β 1. Given the logarithmic form used for the dependent variable, we interpret the coefficients as the percentage change in electoral outcomes between the 2017 and 2012 presidential elections. Finally, we describe the main assumptions of the difference-in-differences model in the Appendix.

4.2 Instrumental variable approach

As explained in the Appendix, OLS and diff-in-diff models may underestimate the effect of CAOs. To circumvent these potential biases, we propose to instrument CAOs location with the presence at the municipal level of pre-existing (i.e., built before the dismantling of the Calais Jungle) buildings that can accomodate groups of individuals. We use two different types of buildings, which we combine in one instrument. First, we collect data on the number of holiday villages. Second, in line with the recent literature (Steinmayr, Reference Steinmayr2020; Gamalerio et al., Reference Gamalerio, Luca, Romarri and Viskanic2022), we collect data on the number of group accommodation buildings such as homes for elderly, disabled, drug addicts, and orphans. The idea behind the construction of the instrument is that the government considered several types of venues, with a strong emphasis on buildings that could commodate groups of people. We start the IV analysis with the following first stage regression:

(3)$$CAO_{i} = \gamma_0 + \gamma_1GroupBuildings_{i} + \gamma_k X_{k, i} + \varepsilon_{i}$$

where GroupBuildings i is equal to the sum of the number of group accommodation buildings plus holiday villages located in municipality i. Then, we run the following second stage regression:

(4)$$\Delta FN \equiv \log( FN_{2017}) _{i}-\log( FN_{2012}) _{i} = \beta_0 + \beta_1\hat{CAO_{i}} + \beta_k X_{k, i} + \eta_{i}$$

Where log(FN 2017) i − log(FN 2012) i is the difference of log voting shares for the FN between 2017 and 2012 elections; $\hat {CAO_{i}}$ is the predicted value of CAO i obtained from the first stage regression, while X k,i are k control variables for municipality i, described in the Appendix. Specifically, we use all the socio-economic controls and their evolutions, log distance to the closest permanent migrant center, the evolution in the number of CADA places between 2012 and 2016, log hotel rooms, political and administrative characteristics, and mayors’ demographics. The standard errors are clustered at the département level. Finally, this IV approach relies on two main assumptions, described in the Appendix.

5. Empirical results

5.1 Baseline results

Table 1 reports the baseline results of our analysis. In panel A, we report the results of the difference-in-differences analysis. Across the five columns, we add covariates, year of election FE, and municipal FE. The variable of interest is the interaction term between CAO and the dummy variable for the 2017 presidential elections. The coefficients are stable across the different specifications. They indicate that CAOs reduce by 4 percentage points the change of FN vote shares between the 2017 and 2012 elections. Considering spillover effects in column 5, we can see that localities in a 5 or 10 km radius experienced a negative impact on the FN vote, but not as strong as the municipalities with a CAO.

Table 1. Main results on the impact of migrants on the Front National vote

Difference-in-differences estimates in panel A, instrumental variables estimates in panel B. Variables reported in the table: CAO = 1 for a migrant center in the municipality; 2017 = 1 for 2017 presidential election; the rings (ring5_CAO, ring10_CAO, ring15_CAO) in panel A denote municipalities within the 5, 10, and 15 km radius respectively; group buildings = number of village vacances and group accommodation buildings in the municipality; coastal = 1 for municipalities on the coast; log hotel rooms = log of the total number of hotels in the municipality. Control variables in panel A: municipality sociodemographic characteristics, the mayor's party, and personal characteristics. Control variables in panel B: municipality sociodemographic characteristics (in 2013 and evolution between 2006 and 2013), coastal dummy variable, the log of the number of hotel rooms, whether the municipality volunteered to receive migrants, the log of distance to the closest permanent migrant center, the evolution of the number of places in CADAs, the mayor's party and personal characteristics. In column 4 of panel B, the only control variables in regressions are the coastal dummy variable, the log of the number of hotel rooms and regions FE. Standard errors clustered at the municipality level in parentheses in panel A. Standard errors clustered at the département level in parentheses in panel B. Significance levels: *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.

Moving to the instrumental variables approach in panel B, the reduced form coefficient in column 1 indicates that our instrument negatively correlates with the growth in FN votes shares between 2017 and 2012. Crucially, the same thing does not happen if we look at the change between the 2012 and 2007 elections, as shown in the pre-trends analysis in the Appendix. In column 2, we get a first-stage regression with F-statistics that are above the customary values indicated by the weak instrument guidelines given in Stock and Yogo (Reference Stock and Yogo2005). Looking at the IV coefficients in columns 4–5, we get an even more negative and highly significant effect. As we previously discussed, not instrumenting the allocation of CAOs could bias our estimates toward zero. When we run the IV strategy controlling only for our proxy for overall tourism (i.e., the log of the number of rooms in hotels and the dummy variable for municipalities on the coast), a CAO's presence decreases the growth rate of FN votes by 8.6 percentage points (column 4). The coefficient does not change much when adding the other controls (column 5). As we can see from column 5, a CAO's presence decreases FN votes’ growth rate by 12 percentage points. Since the FN vote increased by 20% on average in French municipalities between 2012 and 2017 (corresponding to a change of 5.1 points if we look at shares as outcome variables rather than logs), this estimation suggests that the growth rate of FN vote in municipalities with a CAO was 40% of the growth rate in municipalities without a CAO.

In Table 2, we investigate what impact the relocation of migrants had on votes for the extreme left-wing party Front de Gauche and electoral turnout. In columns 1–2, we provide the results of the diff-in-diff analysis. In columns 3–4, the results of the IV analysis. The results are very clear for what concerns the vote shares of the FG (columns 1 and 3).Footnote 8 Both diff-in-diff and IV estimates indicate a positive effect of CAOs on FG votes shares. Conversely, the results are contradictory for the electoral turnout, with the diff-in-diff analysis indicating a negative effect and the IV one a positive impact. Hence, while it is clear that the votes lost by the FN due to CAOs went to the major left-wing pro-immigrant party, it is not clear which exactly is the role of electoral turnout and voters’ mobilization. However, in the Appendix, we provide evidence that rules out that our results are due to a mobilization story or changes in electoral turnout.

Table 2. Effect of migrant relocation on extreme-left wing votes and turnout

Difference-in-differences estimates in columns 1–2, instrumental variables estimates in columns 3–4. Variables reported in the table: CAO = 1 for a migrant center in the municipality; 2017 = 1 for 2017 presidential election. Control variables in columns 1–2: municipality sociodemographic characteristics, the mayor's party, and personal characteristics. Control variables in columns 3–4: municipality sociodemographic characteristics (in 2013 and evolution between 2006 and 2013), coastal dummy variable, the log of the number of hotel rooms, whether the municipality volunteered to receive migrants, the log of distance to the closest permanent migrant center, the evolution of the number of places in CADAs, the mayor's party and personal characteristics. Standard errors clustered at the municipality level in parentheses in columns 1–2. Standard errors clustered at the département level in parentheses in columns 3–4. Significance levels: *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.

5.2 Heterogeneous effects of migrant relocation

We conduct regressions showing heterogeneous effects in Table 3. We focus on the size of the immigration inflow generated by the opening of CAOs, for which we can find the descriptive statistics about the distribution in the bottom panel of Table 3. We run the heterogeneity analysis for the diff-in-diff (columns 1–2), and the IV (columns 3–4) approaches. In the IV analysis, we instrument the interaction term with the interaction between the instrument and the inflow size. We measure the size of the inflow as the capacity of the CAO per 1000 inhabitants. We standardize this variable so that it takes mean 0 and standard deviation 1.Footnote 9

Table 3. Heterogeneous effects of the impact of migrants on the Front National vote

Difference-in-differences estimates in columns 1–2, instrumental variables estimates in columns 3–4. Variables reported in the table: CAO = 1 for a migrant center in the municipality; 2017 = 1 for 2017 presidential election; ${CAO-migrants\over Population} =$ number of migrants in CAO every 1000 inhabitants. We standardize the variable so that it takes mean 0 and standard deviation 1. Control variables in columns 1–2: municipality sociodemographic characteristics, the mayor's party, and personal characteristics. Control variables in columns 3–4: municipality sociodemographic characteristics (in 2013 and evolution between 2006 and 2013), coastal dummy variable, the log of the number of hotel rooms, whether the municipality volunteered to receive migrants, the log of distance to the closest permanent migrant center, the evolution of the number of places in CADAs, the mayor's party and personal characteristics. Standard errors clustered at the municipality level in parentheses in columns 1–2. Standard errors clustered at the département level in parentheses in columns 3–4. Significance levels: *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. The bottom panel reports the descriptive statistics on the distribution of the size of CAOs.

Interestingly, the FN's vote share's negative effect is reduced in places where more migrants were allocated. The analysis of the intensive margin yields important results for the understanding of electoral reaction to migrant inflows. We find that FN's negative effect is stronger in municipalities with fewer migrants per inhabitant hosted in the CAOs. Looking at the diff-in-diff results, we estimate that municipalities that decreased their FN vote upon receiving migrants were those that, on average, hosted less than 47 migrants per 1000 inhabitants, which corresponds to 12 standard deviations in the distribution of CAOs capacity (a standard deviation being equal to 3.96). In the IV results, the estimated threshold is approximately 32 migrants per 1000 inhabitants (i.e., 8 standard deviations). Above these thresholds, CAO's estimated average effect on FN vote switches sign and eventually becomes positive and statistically significant for very large CAOs. This result is in line with the literature on the impacts of immigrants’ large inflows on political outcomes. This evidence indicates that, while small immigration inflows can reduce prejudice, inflows above a certain threshold can produce the opposite effect, suggesting a potential “Tipping point”.

5.3 Contact theory versus realistic group conflict theories versus pure exposure effect

We think that the negative baseline effect in Table 1 is in line with contact theory (Allport, Reference Allport1954), which suggests that the contact between natives and immigrants should lead to a decrease in anti-immigrant attitudes when certain conditions apply. The anecdotal evidence on the CAOs’ experience seems to confirm this idea. When collecting our data on the location of the CAOs, we came across many examples that suggest that the interactions between migrants and local populations were generally successful. While at the onset of the dismantling process, protests seemed to be widespread (La Depeche, 2016), and sometimes violent (La Croix, 2016), several articles mention that local populations regret migrants have to leave after only a few months, even within municipalities where protests took place initially (Liberation, 2017; Charente Libre, 2018). Many forms of interactions emerged, through charity dinners (La Nouvelle Republique du Centre Ouest, 2017), car-pooling (Liberation, 2017), or football games. Officials of small municipalities argued that the arrival of migrants revitalized football teams in rural areas, which lacked players to compete in amateur leagues (20 Minutes, 2016). Although we cannot systematically analyze those events, they do not seem rare and repeatedly appear in newspapers. A map released by Le Monde (2017b) shows that initiatives helping migrants being integrated were far from scarce.

Conversely, the results in Table 3 indicate that CAO centers’ negative effect on FN votes shares can turn positive when the centers’ size reaches a certain threshold. We believe that this evidence indicates that natives can perceive the inflow of new immigrants as a threat to their social, cultural, and economic hegemony when their number is too large. This evidence is consistent with the “realistic group conflict theories”. For this event study, we think that the potential threat generated by large CAOs should be due to cultural rather than economic concerns. In Table 4, we use data from Trendeo - Observatoire de l'investissement et de l'emploi (2017), which reports the number of job creations and destructions at the municipality level from January 2009 to June 2017, to test the potential economic consequences. As shown in Table 4, we do not find any significant relationship between the presence of a CAO and net job creation (columns 1 and 3). Besides, controlling for net job creation per inhabitant does not affect our diff-in-diff and IV estimates (columns 2 and 4). Therefore it is more likely that when entering in contact with a large group of outsiders, natives perceived the opening of big CAOs as a threat to their identity and cultural dominance. In addition, an alternative or perhaps coexisting explanation to the “realistic group conflict theories” story is the one based on the recent evidence on the pure effect of exposure without contact (Hangartner et al., Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019; Dinas et al., Reference Dinas, Matakos, Xefteris and Hangartner2019). Specifically, big CAO centers may have made contact between natives and migrants more complicated, leaving the natives to be affected by a pure exposure effect, potentially leading to an increase in prejudice.

Table 4. Effect of migrant relocation on net job creation

Difference-in-differences estimates in columns 1–2, instrumental variables estimates in columns 3–4. Variables reported in the table: CAO = 1 for a migrant center in the municipality; 2017 = 1 for 2017 presidential election; NJC = net job creation rate per 1000 inhabitants; NJC Post−10/2016 = net job creation rate per 1000 inhabitants after October 2016. Control variables in columns 1–2: municipality sociodemographic characteristics, the mayor's party, and personal characteristics. Control variables in columns 3–4: municipality sociodemographic characteristics (in 2013 and evolution between 2006 and 2013), coastal dummy variable, the log of the number of hotel rooms, whether the municipality volunteered to receive migrants, the log of distance to the closest permanent migrant center, the evolution of the number of places in CADAs, the mayor's party, and personal characteristics. Standard errors clustered at the municipality level in parentheses in columns 1–2. Standard errors clustered at the département level in parentheses in columns 3–4. Significance levels: *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.

6. Conclusion

We have tried to answer important questions regarding the electoral impact of migrants’ relocation after the dismantling of the Calais “Jungle”. We find a negative effect on the FN's vote shares, consistent with the contact hypothesis. We provide some anecdotal evidence that supports this claim. We also provide empirical evidence on the heterogeneity behind the baseline effect. We show that the effect can potentially turn positive for municipalities that received a larger number of migrants, which is consistent with “realistic group conflict theories”. Given that CAO centers did not have any local economic impact, we think that large reception centers’ positive effect on FN votes shares is likely due to cultural and identitarian rather than economic concerns. In conclusion, this paper gives some indication also on the allocation mechanisms of migrants. Small numbers seem to decrease prejudice against them. Overall, our results suggest that there is a difference in perceived immigration through the media compared to real immigration. The electoral reaction to actual migration seems to depend crucially on the size of the inflow.

Acknowledgments

This work is supported by a public grant overseen by the French National Research Agency (ANR) as part of the “Investissements d'Avenir” program LABEX LIEPP (ANR-11-LABX-0091, ANR-11-IDEX-0005-02) and the IdEx Université Paris Cité (ANR-18-IDEX-0001). We thank Yann Algan, Diane Bolet, Bjoern Brey, Julia Cagé, Guillaume Chapelle, Anthony Edo, Jean-Benoît Eyméoud, Roberto Galbiati, Ian Gordon, Sergei Guriev, Emeric Henry, Rachel Kranton, Ilyana Kuziemko, Mario Luca, Thomas Piketty, Panu Poutvaara, Paul Seabright, David Strömberg, Simon Weber, Ekaterina Zhuravskaya as well as participants at the Sciences Po Lunch Seminar, the CEPII Conference on Immigration in OECD countries, the 11th Cesifo Workshop in Political Economy, the Graduate Conference on Populism at the LSE, the lunch seminar in the PSPE Group at the LSE, the 3rd Workshop in Political Economy at the University of Bolzano, the Applied Lunch Seminar at PSE, and the IEB Workshop on Political Economy for useful comments.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2022.26.

Footnotes

1 These numbers (16 migrants per 1000 inhabitants or 0.016 migrants per capita) give an idea of how small was the inflow of migrants generated by CAOs. For example, in the context studied by Hangartner et al. (Reference Hangartner, Dinas, Marbach, Matakos and Xefteris2019) and Dinas et al. (Reference Dinas, Matakos, Xefteris and Hangartner2019), the Greek islands were receiving between 1 and 4 asylum seekers per capita, with a few of them receiving more than 4 per capita.

2 See La Croix (2017), BBC (2017), and Le Monde (2017a) amongst others.

3 “Holiday Villages” are structures owned by a public company managed by the state to be used by their employees to go on holiday. Since those structures were mostly empty during the dismantling, the central government used them to host migrants. In some cases, these structures were not used, but they were still kept as an alternative solution if collective houses or other empty flats did not prove sufficient.

4 We also control for the overall tourism level. We think it is important to control for the overall tourism level because touristic municipalities may follow different electoral trends than non-touristic ones. This fact could generate doubts about alternative channels through which holiday villages may affect electoral outcomes besides CAOs.

5 The general rule was that migrants had to move to other receptions centers, and in particular CADA centers. However, we cannot exclude that some migrants remain to live in the municipality where the CAO was established in few specific cases. However, we do not have specific data on these cases.

6 Reassuringly, even though our capacity measure is not defined in the same way, its internal consistency seems warranted. To check it, we compare, among CAOs observed in both datasets, the maximum number of sheltered migrants observed in our manually collected dataset and the capacity registered in the CIMADE dataset. Excluding outliers for which the difference between the two measures is more than two standard deviations away from the mean in absolute value, i.e., less than 10% of cases, the correlation between the two measures is 88%. Therefore, our capacity measure is likely to indicate the number of migrants that were actually sheltered in CAOs.

7 The préfets have authority at the level of the département.

8 We do not carry out a separate analysis for electoral outcomes for the center-left and center-right parties because the candidacy of Emmanuel Macron, an ex-socialist minister and centrist, makes it difficult to compare those votes with the election in 2012.

9 We could not find information on the capacity for a small number of municipalities with a CAO. These municipalities appear to be small towns for which it is more complicated to recover information. Hence, we replace the missing information with the smaller value taken by the distribution of the capacity of CAOs. If we repeat the analysis dropping these municipalities with missing information, the results do not change. Results can be made available upon request.

References

20 Minutes (2016) Calais “Jungle”: what if migrants could save football in French rural areas?.Google Scholar
Allport, G (1954) The nature of prejudice. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Association des Maires de France (2016) Ouverture de cao: Bernard Cazeneuve promet un dialogue approfondi avec les maires de france [cao openings: Bernard Cazeneuve pledges to an “in-depth” dialogue with the mayors].Google Scholar
Bansak, K, Hainmueller, J and Hangartner, D (2017) Europeans support a proportional allocation of asylum seekers. Nature Human Behaviour 1, 0133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barlow, F, Paolini, S, Pedersen, A, Hornsey, M, Radke, H, Harwood, J, Rubin, M and Sibley, C (2012) The contact caveat: negative contact predicts increased prejudice more than positive contact predicts reduced prejudice. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 38, 16291643.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Barone, G, D'Ignazio, A, de Blasio, G and Naticchioni, P (2016) Mr. Rossi, Mr. Hu and politics. The role of immigration in shaping natives’ voting behavior. Journal of Public Economics 136, 113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
BBC (2017) France: le front national fait peur aux immigrés.Google Scholar
Blalock, H (1967) Toward a theory of minority-group relations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Blumer, H (1958) Race prejudice as a sense of group position. Pacific Sociological Review 1, 37.Google Scholar
Bobo, L (1983) Whites—opposition to busing: symbolic racism or realistic group conflict?. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 45, 11961210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bobo, L and Hutchings, V (1996) Perceptions of racial group competition: extending Blumer's theory of group position to a multiracial social context. American Sociological Review 61, 951972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunner, B and Kuhn, A (2018) Immigration, cultural distance and natives’ attitudes towards immigrants: evidence from Swiss voting results. Kyklos—International Review for Social Sciences 71, 2858.Google Scholar
Campbell, D (1965) Ethnocentric and other altruistic motives. In David Levine (ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
Charente Libre (2018) The sudden departure of 12 exiled brakes confolens heart.Google Scholar
Dinas, E, Matakos, K, Xefteris, D and Hangartner, D (2019) Waking up the golden dawn: does exposure to the refugees crisis increase support for extreme-right parties?. Political Analysis 17, 244254.Google Scholar
Dustmann, C, Vasiljeva, K and Damm, A (2019) Refugee migration and electoral outcomes. The Review of Economic Studies 86, 20352091.Google Scholar
Edo, A, Giesing, Y, Oztunc, J and Poutvaara, P (2019) Immigration and electoral support for the far-left and the far-right. European Economic Review 115, 99143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eurostat (2016) Asylum statistics.Google Scholar
Gamalerio, M, Luca, M, Romarri, A and Viskanic, M (2022) Refugee reception, extreme-right voting, and compositional amenities: evidence from Italian municipalities. Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golder, M (2003) Explaining variation in the success of extreme right parties in Western Europe. Comparative Political Studies 36, 432466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, J and Hopkins, D (2014) Public attitudes towards immigration. Annual Review of Political Science 17, 225249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halla, M, Wagner, A and Zweimueller, J (2017) Immigration and voting for the extreme right. Journal of the European Economics Association 15, 13411385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hangartner, D, Dinas, E, Marbach, M, Matakos, K and Xefteris, D (2019) Does exposure to the refugee crisis make natives more hostile?. American Political Science Review 113, 442455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harmon, N (2017) Immigration, ethnic diversity and political outcomes: evidence from Denmark. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 120, 10431074.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Cimade (2017) Etat des lieux du dispositif d'accueil des demandeurs d'asile.Google Scholar
La Croix (2016) In Forges-les-Bains, high tension upon installation of migrants.Google Scholar
La Croix (2017) En conscience, au nom de notre foi, voter front national, c'est non [in consciousness, and in the name of our faith, we won't vote for the front national].Google Scholar
La Depeche (2016) Several protests organized against the arrival of migrants in French municipalities.Google Scholar
Lahav, G (2004) Public opinion toward immigrants in the European Union: does it matter?. Comparative Political Studies 37, 11511183.Google Scholar
La Nouvelle Republique du Centre Ouest (2017) A nice and rich encounter with the migrants.Google Scholar
Le Monde (2015) Comment la France se prépare à accueillir les réfugiés [how France is getting ready to welcome the refugees].Google Scholar
Le Monde (2016) “Jungle” de Calais : le démantèlement débutera lundi à l'aube’ [Calais “Jungle”: the dismantling will begin monday at dawn].Google Scholar
Le Monde (2017a) En mettant l'accent sur l'immigration, Marine le Pen cherche à mobiliser sa base électorale.[by putting the emphasis on immigration, Marine le Pen aims at mobilizing her electoral basis.].Google Scholar
Le Monde (2017b) A participatory map of solidarity initiatives towards migrants.Google Scholar
Liberation (2017) We are going the migrants when the CAO closes.Google Scholar
Lonsky, J (2020) Does immigration decrease far-right popularity? Evidence from Finnish municipalities. Journal of Population Economics 34, 97139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayda, A-M (2006) Who is against immigration? A cross-country investigation of individual attitudes toward immigrants. Review of Economics and Statistics 88, 510530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mendez, I and Cutillas, I (2014) Has immigration affected Spanish presidential elections results?. Journal of Population Economics 27, 135171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ministère de l'Intérieur (2017) L'action de l'etat à calais.Google Scholar
Neumayer, E (2005) Bogus refugees? The determinants of asylum migration to Western Europe. International Studies Quarterly 49, 389409.Google Scholar
Otto, AH and Steinhardt, MF (2014) Immigration and election outcomes ? Evidence from city districts in Hamburg. Regional Science and Urban Economics 45, 6779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paluck, E and Green, D (2009) Prejudice reduction: what works? A review and assessment of research and practice. Annual Review of Psychology 60, 339367.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Paluck, E, Green, S and Green, D (2019) The contact hypothesis re-evaluated. Behavioral Public Policy 3, 129158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettigrew, T and Tropp, L (2006) A meta-analytic test of intergroup contact theory. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 90, 751.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pettigrew, T and Tropp, L (2008) How does intergroup contact reduce prejudice? Meta-analytic tests of three mediators. European Journal of Social Psychology 38, 922934.Google Scholar
Quillian, L (1995) Prejudice as a response to perceived group threat: population composition and anti-immigrant and racial prejudice in Europe. American Sociological Review 60, 586611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ravenstein, E (1885) The laws of migration. Journal of the Statistical Society of London 48, 167235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheve, K and Slaughter, M (2001) Labor market competition and individual preferences over immigration policy. Review of Economics and Statistics 83, 133145.Google Scholar
Sidanius, J and Pratto, F (1999) Social Dominance: An Intergroup Theory of Social Hierarchy and Oppression. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinmayr, A (2020) Contact versus exposure: refugee presence and voting for the far-right. Review of Economics and Statistics 103, 310327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stock, J and Yogo, M (2005) Testing for weak instruments in linear iv regression. In Andrews DWK. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 80–108.Google Scholar
Taylor, M (1998) How white attitudes vary with the racial composition of local populations: numbers count. American Sociological Review 63, 512535.Google Scholar
Trendeo - Observatoire de l'investissement et de l'emploi (2017)Google Scholar
Viskanic, M (2017) Fear and loathing on the campaign trail: did immigration cause Brexit? Working Paper.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Evolution of the number of migrants in the Calais camp.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Google Trends for the expession “Jungle de Calais”.

Figure 2

Figure 3. FN vote shares in the first round of 2012 and 2017 presidential elections, (a) FN vote share—2012, (b) FN vote share—2017.

Figure 3

Table 1. Main results on the impact of migrants on the Front National vote

Figure 4

Table 2. Effect of migrant relocation on extreme-left wing votes and turnout

Figure 5

Table 3. Heterogeneous effects of the impact of migrants on the Front National vote

Figure 6

Table 4. Effect of migrant relocation on net job creation

Supplementary material: PDF

Vertier et al. supplementary material

Vertier et al. supplementary material 1

Download Vertier et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 347.7 KB
Supplementary material: File

Vertier et al. supplementary material

Vertier et al. supplementary material 2

Download Vertier et al. supplementary material(File)
File 32.7 KB
Supplementary material: Link

Vertier et al. Dataset

Link