Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T20:57:35.135Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Who’s fit for the job? Allocating ministerial portfolios to outsiders and experts

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 July 2022

Matthias Kaltenegger
Affiliation:
Department of Government, Universität Wien, Wien, Austria
Laurenz Ennser-Jedenastik*
Affiliation:
Department of Government, Universität Wien, Wien, Austria Universität Mannheim, SFB 884 ‘Political Economy of Reforms’, Mannheim, Germany
*
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Why do parties appoint outsiders and experts to ministerial positions? Extant research offers explanations based on institutional arrangements and external shocks (e.g. political or economic crises). We go beyond such system-level variables to argue that the characteristics of ministerial appointees are a function of the portfolio they are being appointed to. Drawing on theories of political delegation, we argue that outsider and expert appointments to ministerial office are affected by a portfolio’s policy jurisdiction, its financial resources and appointment powers, and the partisan leanings of the ministerial bureaucracy. We test these arguments on all appointments of senior and junior ministers in Austria between 1945 and 2020. The analysis shows that outsiders are more likely to be appointed to ministries with greater party support in the bureaucracy, while experts are more likely appointed to portfolios dealing with high-salience issues.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of European Consortium for Political Research

Introduction

How are members of government selected? The extant literature locates the answer to this question on a single dimension between the poles of party government and technocratic government.

Under party government, ideologically distinct parties compete in elections, the winning parties place party members in government offices, and these partisan ministers then implement the party agenda (or, in coalition governments, some compromise between different party agendas). The popular mandate confers legitimacy on governments (Rose, Reference Rose1974; Katz, Reference Katz, Castles and Wildenmann1986; Blondel and Cotta, Reference Blondel and Cotta2000; Amorim Neto and Strøm, Reference Amorim Neto and Strøm2006; Mair, Reference Mair2008).

By contrast, under technocratic government, expertise provides an alternative source of legitimacy. Government ministers are selected based on their subject-matter knowledge and enact ‘rational’ solutions, unconstrained by short-term popular approval or electoral considerations (Habermas, Reference Habermas1973; Majone, Reference Majone1994; Centeno, Reference Centeno1993; Fischer, Reference Fischer2009; Caramani, Reference Caramani2017; Sánchez-Cuenca, Reference Sánchez-Cuenca2017; Costa Pinto et al., Reference Costa Pinto, Cotta and Almeidad2018; Caramani, Reference Caramani, Bertsou and Caramani2020). Conceptualizing party government and technocratic government as polar opposites on one underlying dimension (McDonnell and Valbruzzi, Reference McDonnell and Valbruzzi2014; Cotta, Reference Cotta2018; Costa Pinto et al., Reference Costa Pinto, Cotta and Almeidad2018; Bertsou and Caramani 2020b), the empirical literature has so far either studied appointments of outsiders (people with no or weak party affiliation) or technocrats, lumping ‘outsiderness’ and expertise together. Footnote 1 We argue that, while correlated, ‘outsiderness’ and expertise should be conceived as two distinct properties of government ministers and that party leaders have different incentives to select outsiders and experts, depending on characteristics of the specific government post they need to fill.

Drawing on theories of political delegation, we present arguments about how portfolio characteristics shape who becomes a minister. More specifically, we argue that issue salience, a ministry’s budgetary and patronage resources, as well as the ideological leanings of the ministerial bureaucracy should affect the probability of outsiders and experts being appointed. We test these expectations with data on post-war ministerial appointments in Austria. Our paper thus contributes novel perspectives on the process of ministerial selection with implications for governments’ legitimacy and effectiveness in parliamentary democracies.

Conceptual premises

Why do parties appoint ministers with varying degrees of ‘outsiderness’ and expertise? A number of studies have examined this question, using system-level explanations such as economic crises (Wratil and Pastorella, Reference Wratil and Pastorella2018; Alexiadou and Gunaydin, Reference Alexiadou and Gunaydin2019) or institutional features of the polity (e.g. semi-presidentialism) (Amorim Neto and Strøm, Reference Amorim Neto and Strøm2006; Schleiter and Morgan-Jones, Reference Schleiter and Morgan-Jones2009). Our paper provides a novel perspective by focusing not just on the number of outsiders and experts appointed, but on the specific role they are given. We therefore theorize how the characteristics of ministerial portfolios shape the appointment of party insiders vs. outsiders and experts vs. non-experts. More specifically, we examine the role of issue salience, financial resources, patronage powers, and bureaucratic support.

Before we delve into the theoretical discussion, three important premises need to be clarified. First, we assume in our discussion that outsiderness and expertise are two independent dimensions. While the literature on technocrats often combines these two dimensions and defines technocrats as experts without political or partisan affiliation (McDonnell and Valbruzzi, Reference McDonnell and Valbruzzi2014), we argue that outsiders are not necessarily experts (Marsh et al., Reference Marsh, ‘t Hart and Tindall2010; Street, Reference Street2012) and insiders are not necessarily non-experts (Lavezzolo et al., Reference Lavezzolo, Ramiro and Fernández-Vázquez2021).

Second, we conceptualize outsiderness in relation to a specific party, not to politics in general, which is in line with the delegational logic of party-based representation (Müller Reference Müller2000 a; Strøm, Reference Strøm2000). While most political insiders are also party insiders, there are cases of political insiders without (strong) attachment to any party. For example, senior bureaucrats or diplomats are highly involved and experienced in the practice of politics (and should therefore count as political insiders), but may be unaffiliated to a party. Another group to which these criteria may apply is party switchers: individuals who used to be party (and thus political) insiders, but whose transition to another party has turned them into party outsiders – at least temporarily.

Third, we do not expect party leaders to have carte blanche when selecting government personnel, but to be constrained in various ways. Besides formal selection rules set out by the constitution (e.g. recruiting ministers from the legislature in Westminster systems or formal appointment powers of the head of state), party leaders need to account for the representativeness of their government team (Rose, Reference Rose1974; Andeweg Reference Andeweg, Blondel and Cotta2000 b) in terms of gender (Goddard, Reference Goddard2019), region (Ennser-Jedenastik Reference Ennser-Jedenastik2013 b), party faction or tendency (Mershon, Reference Mershon2001; Ceron, Reference Ceron2014). Naturally, several other characteristics such as the candidates’ age, their scandal-proneness, their policy preferences and their competence need to be considered as well in the selection process (Rose, Reference Rose1974; Kam et al., Reference Kam, Bianco, Sened and Smyth2010; Bäck et al., Reference Bäck, Debus and Müller2016).

Theoretical framework

We develop our argument from theories of political delegation. Delegation typically means that a principal asks an agent to perform a task that the principal cannot do himself or herself and that the agent may be better equipped to do. The appointment of ministers is a crucial step in the chain of delegation that runs from voters to the bureaucracy (Strøm, Reference Strøm2000). Formally, ministers thus act as agents of the cabinet, yet their more important principal is typically the cabinet party that appoints them (Müller Reference Müller2000 a). In addition, ministers themselves act as principals by delegating tasks to the ministerial bureaucracy whose expertise they require to achieve their policy goals (Huber, Reference Huber2000; Huber and Shipan, Reference Huber, Shipan and Goodin2006). In normative terms, both these steps in the delegation process are essential for parties to make the chain of delegation from voters to the governing apparatus work in parliamentary democracies (Müller Reference Müller2000 a).

$$\rm Cabinet \,(party)$$
$$ \downarrow $$
$$\rm Minister$$
$$ \downarrow $$
$$\rm Bureaucracy$$

All delegation potentially produces agency loss, as agents may deviate from the preferences of their principals (Bendor and Meirowitz, Reference Bendor and Meirowitz2004). Parties typically anticipate the potential for agency loss and thus chose ministerial appointees in ways that mitigate delegation problems (Müller and Meyer, Reference Müller and Meyer2010). Our core theoretical contribution is to argue that both, the political damage from agency loss and the overall risk of agency loss to happen in the first place vary systematically with portfolio characteristics. Some portfolios are substantively or strategically more important to a party (Bäck et al., Reference Bäck, Debus and Dumont2011), which will increase the costs of agency loss. Some are more likely to cause delegation problems, either in general terms or for specific types of appointments. Portfolio characteristics should therefore influence the calculus by which parties appoint outsider and expert ministers.

Insiders vs. outsiders Footnote 2

Choosing insiders over outsiders for government office allows party leaders to minimize problems in the delegation from party to minister. For one, uncertainty with regard to relevant selection criteria (Andeweg Reference Andeweg, Blondel and Cotta2000 b; Müller Reference Müller2000 a; Strøm, Reference Strøm2000) is lower for insiders than for outsiders. In particular, ministerial candidates’ previous party careers will be informative in terms of their competence in various fields, their loyalty to the party and their policy preferences. Secondly, insiders have had years of socialization within the party and have thus internalized the party’s norms, values, and policy commitments, ensuring at least a basic level of ideological congruence with the party agenda (Van Haute and Carty, Reference Van Haute and Carty2012).

In contrast, appointing outsiders to ministerial office is usually a riskier choice. All else equal, information on crucial characteristics of outsider candidates is not as easily accessible and outsider ministers are less socialized into party norms and less steeped in party ideology. Consequently, outsiders are more likely to pursue different issue priorities, to hold deviant policy positions, and should therefore act as less faithful agents of the party in government than partisan appointees would. The appointment of outsiders thus increases the risk of agency loss (Amorim Neto and Strøm, Reference Amorim Neto and Strøm2006; Schleiter and Morgan-Jones, Reference Schleiter and Morgan-Jones2009). While ministers in real-world politics may not act as the policy dictators that, for example, Laver and Shepsle’s portfolio allocation model envisages (Laver and Shepsle, Reference Laver and Shepsle1990; Laver and Shepsle, Reference Laver and Shepsle1996), they still have a substantial impact on policy outcomes (Alexiadou, Reference Alexiadou2016; Bäck et al., Reference Bäck, Müller, Angelova and Strobl2022). Appointing outsiders will therefore produce outcomes further away from a party’s ideal point (and that of its voters).

Despite this obvious disadvantage of outsider appointments for governing parties, they are an empirical fact and the literature has pointed to various reasons why party leaders recruit outsiders for ministerial office. For one, there are instances when party leaders view outsiders’ distance to party policy as an asset – especially, when they seek to shift the party’s position in a policy area (e.g. for electoral reasons or to send signals to investors and creditors in the context of economic crises) (Alexiadou and Gunaydin, Reference Alexiadou and Gunaydin2019). Second, outsiders are, by definition, characterized by a weak or even non-existent power base within the party that appoints them, which allows party leaders to keep them on a shorter leash than insiders, who will often have intra-party networks and factional support. Finally, outsiders may be appointed because of their celebrity status or media savvy (Marsh et al., Reference Marsh, ‘t Hart and Tindall2010; Street, Reference Street2012), thus creating potential electoral benefits.

Notwithstanding these (and potentially other) incentives to choose outsiders over insiders for ministerial office, we argue that party leaders will manage delegation problems associated with outsider appointments – in terms of both delegation steps, from cabinets/parties to ministers and from ministers to the bureaucracy – by selectively placing them in portfolios with specific characteristics.

Experts vs. non-experts

Unlike outsiderness, expertise is always a desirable trait in ministerial candidates. Expert ministers are likely to govern more effectively than non-experts (Alexiadou, Reference Alexiadou2016) and voters prefer to be governed by people who know what they are doing (Lavezzolo et al., Reference Lavezzolo, Ramiro and Fernández-Vázquez2021). Expertise among government personnel also functions as an additional source of political legitimacy, independent of the party label.

Contrary to the insider–outsider dimension, there is thus no trade-off along the expertise dimension. Rather, constraints on expert appointments arise from the limited availability of experts (with ministerial ambitions as well as sufficient compatibility with the party line) or the fact that party leaders may prioritize expertise lower than other requirements such as descriptive representation or maintaining an intra-party power balance. In addition, expertise in ministerial appointees becomes more desirable when bureaucratic expertise is less accessible (e.g. due to the partisan leanings of bureaucrats).

Parts of the literature suggest that the objective demand for experts in ministerial office has increased over the course of the 20th century – in terms of government effectiveness and legitimacy. These studies argue that effective governance requires more and more technical knowledge of systemic characteristics and dynamics, as well as legal frameworks due to the expansion of state regulation into various sectors of economic and social life and the increasing interdependence of economic systems (Meynaud, Reference Meynaud1964; Fischer, Reference Fischer2009; Bertsou and Caramani Reference Bertsou and Caramani2020b). Likewise, as declining trust in and identification with political parties threatens to undermine party-based representation in parliamentary democracies (Müller Reference Müller2000 b; Brunclk and Parzek, Reference Brunclk and Parzek2019), ministers’ individual expertise might serve to compensate the legitimacy deficit of political parties (Habermas, Reference Habermas1973; Costa Pinto et al., Reference Costa Pinto, Cotta and Almeidad2018; Caramani, Reference Caramani, Bertsou and Caramani2020).

While appointing experts (from within or from outside the party organization) will thus undoubtedly be beneficial for party leaders in most instances, we argue that expert appointments, too, are governed by portfolio-specific considerations of agency loss in the delegation from cabinets/parties to ministers and from ministers to the bureaucracy.

Damage from agency loss

We now turn to generating specific expectations about how portfolio characteristics relate to outsider and expert appointments. As outlined earlier, we expect the potential damage from agency loss in a ministerial portfolio to affect party leaders’ choices in ministerial selection. The more valuable a portfolio is to the party, the greater these potential costs, and thus the less willing party leaders should be to take the risk of outsider appointments. As expertise, per se, is not associated with a higher propensity to cause delegation problems, expert appointments should not be affected by damage control considerations. These expectations pertain to the delegation step from cabinets/parties to ministers.

Issue salience

For one, the salience of policy issues within a portfolio’s jurisdiction should affect how party leaders perceive the value of a ministerial portfolio and thus the potential costs associated with agency loss in that ministry. Specifically, the damage from agency loss should be smaller in portfolios that fall outside of a party’s core issue commitments (Bäck et al., Reference Bäck, Debus and Dumont2011). Most real-world parties vary considerably in how much attention they devote to certain issues (Budge and Farlie, Reference Budge and Farlie1983; Green-Pedersen, Reference Green-Pedersen2007) and how competent they are viewed by voters on these issues (Walgrave et al., Reference Walgrave, Lefevere and Nuytemans2009; Lefevere et al., Reference Lefevere, Tresch and Walgrave2015).

For governing parties, failure to deliver on their core issues is likely to be electorally harmful (Schumacher et al., Reference Schumacher, Vis and Van Kersbergen2013). What is more, constituencies inside the party (e.g. trade unionists in social democratic parties, farmers’ organizations in agrarian or Christian democratic parties, or business representatives in conservative and liberal parties) (Allern et al., Reference Allern, Hansen, Marshall, Rasmussen and Webb2021) will react particularly negatively to malperformance on core issues, and might eventually punish party leaders by withholding their support in subsequent electoral campaigns or in party leadership elections. As party leaders will seek to minimize electoral and intra-party damage, we expect outsider appointments to be less common in portfolios that cover a party’s core issues.

Hypothesis 1 Outsider appointments are less common in portfolios that deal with issues of high salience for the appointing party.

Resources

In addition to their policy value for specific parties, ministerial portfolios differ in terms of their access to financial resources (Bojar, Reference Bojar2019). While correlated to some extent with governing parties’ policy priorities – as more money will be budgeted for more important ministries – different government activities also objectively require different sets of resources. For instance, a comparatively modest budget will often suffice to cover the state’s tasks in the field of cultural affairs. In contrast, public expenditures on welfare state programs or education cover a sizeable chunk of most industrialized countries’ economies (Garritzmann and Seng, Reference Garritzmann and Seng2016; Savage, Reference Savage2019). Naturally, these resources are instrumental for governing parties to act on their policy goals (e.g. to implement certain redistributive policies), but they also have the intrinsic value of allowing parties to engage in clientelistic behavior (Batista, Reference Batista2017). Governing parties may pursue the latter in various ways, ranging from typical pork barrel politics to handing out government contracts or licenses to private businesses that are close to the party (Müller, Reference Müller2000). Access to financial resources is thus crucial in determining a portfolio’s value for political parties. As ministers have substantial discretion with regard to how money is spent within their jurisdiction, the impact of agency loss for the party in terms of its policy goals and patronage distribution is greater in portfolios with more extensive access to these resources. Hence, we hypothesize that outsiders are less likely appointed to ministries with larger budgetary resources.

Hypothesis 2 Outsider appointments are less common in portfolios with larger budgetary resources.

Appointment powers

Ministers do not only make policy and spend money, they also make appointments. Most obviously, many civil servants are appointed by ministers (or their subordinates), and these appointment powers are among the most important tools that ministers have to influence the implementation of policy in their jurisdictions (Huber, Reference Huber2000; Huber and Shipan, Reference Huber, Shipan and Goodin2006). But appointment powers go far beyond the core civil service to include, among others, regulatory agencies (Gilardi, Reference Gilardi2005), policy and advisory commissions (Hesstvedt and Christiansen, Reference Hesstvedt and Christiansen2022), and the boards of state-owned enterprises (Ennser-Jedenastik, Reference Ennser-Jedenastik2014). While such appointments can be instrumental in that they may advance a party’s or minister’s policy goals (as the old adage goes: ‘personnel is policy’, see Lewis, Reference Lewis2008, 27), they also have an intrinsic value as private (patronage) goods. They can thus serve a ‘control’ as well as a ‘reward’ purpose (Kopecký et al., Reference Kopecký, Mair and Spirova2012).

Ministerial portfolios differ widely in how much appointment powers they provide. This is largely a function of the number of staff that is directly or indirectly appointed by the minister, but it also depends on the established rules and norms regulating the (non-)politicization of bureaucratic appointments. To be sure, the most valuable positions in terms of controlling policy are top-level administrators (Page and Wright, Reference Page and Wright1999).

No matter whether appointments are viewed as instrumentally (‘control’) or intrinsically (‘reward’) relevant, the value of a ministerial portfolio is clearly affected by its appointment powers. Greater appointment powers may mean greater policy influence and/or a larger pool of jobs to hand out to party loyalists (Meyer-Sahling, Reference Meyer-Sahling2008). In both cases, agency loss becomes more damaging to the party, as the party either suffers in terms of policy implementation or patronage goods (or both). Therefore, we assume that appointment powers are negatively correlated with outsider appointments.

Hypothesis 3 Outsider appointments are less common in portfolios with greater appointment powers.

Risk of agency loss

Notwithstanding how parties manage varying levels of potential damage from agency loss, portfolio characteristics should also affect how party leaders evaluate the risk associated with expert appointments in a particular ministry (delegation from cabinet/parties to ministers) and a portfolio’s propensity to cause problems in the delegation from the minister to the bureaucracy. We expect such portfolio-specific risk evaluations to condition party leaders’ choices in terms of outsider and expert appointments.

Issue salience

Besides the implications of issue salience for outsider appointments outlined earlier, the relative importance of a ministry’s policy jurisdiction for a governing party will determine the risk associated with expert appointments. Specifically, expertise is more likely to be present in or available to a party on issues of high salience. Parties have stronger links to interest groups that represent core voter constituencies and central issue demands (Otjes and Rasmussen, Reference Otjes and Rasmussen2017; Allern et al., Reference Allern, Hansen, Marshall, Rasmussen and Webb2021). Also, parties’ issue attention is linked to their ties with interest groups (Otjes and Green-Pedersen, Reference Otjes and Green-Pedersen2021). The supply of politically compatible experts will therefore be greater in policy areas that are central to the party. As parties will be able to recruit from a pool of experts that are politically and ideologically aligned, expert appointments will involve a lower risk of agency loss in portfolios that cover core policy issues, all else equal.

Hypothesis 4 Expert appointments are more common in portfolios that cover issues of high salience for the appointing party.

Bureaucratic support

As argued above, ministers depend on bureaucrats to be effective (Huber, Reference Huber2000). In particular, ministers facing a politically hostile ministerial bureaucracy run a higher risk of having their policy agenda sabotaged than ministers sharing common goals with their civil service. This phenomenon has been termed the ‘ally principle’: politicians are more likely to delegate tasks and grant discretion to bureaucratic agents who share their preferences (Bendor and Meirowitz, Reference Bendor and Meirowitz2004; Huber and Shipan, Reference Huber, Shipan and Goodin2006). After all, policy outcomes are assumed to be a function of politicians’ and bureaucrats’ ideal points.

Party leaders thus have incentives to act strategically and take bureaucratic preferences into account when recruiting individuals for ministerial office (Bertelli and Feldmann, Reference Bertelli and Feldmann2007). In particular, they will seek to contain the risk of agency loss by appointing partisan insiders to ministries with a more hostile bureaucracy, whereas ministries with a high proportion of co-partisan bureaucrats may see more outsider appointments.

Hypothesis 5 Outsider appointments are more common in portfolios with high party support in the bureaucracy.

Likewise, we expect bureaucratic support in a ministry to affect expert appointments. After all, the central purpose of delegating tasks to the bureaucracy is to tap into its expert knowledge (Huber, Reference Huber2000). Loyal bureaucrats will happily assist ministers with their know-how and will have little reason to exploit their informational advantage over the minister to obstruct party policy (Huber and Shipan, Reference Huber, Shipan and Goodin2006). Ministers facing a hostile bureaucracy, however, cannot expect the same level of cooperation, which will constrain their access to the bureaucracy’s expertise (Müller, Reference Müller, Page and Wright2007). In the latter scenario, expertise on part of the minister should be an important asset for parties to counteract potential sabotage by the ministerial bureaucracy. Party leaders will thus have stronger incentives to appoint experts to portfolios where their ministers face a potentially non-cooperative civil service than in ministries where bureaucrats share the party’s policy goals. Following this line of reasoning, we expect expert appointments to be more likely in portfolios with low bureaucratic support for the nominating party. Table 1 provides a summary of the hypotheses, expected effects of the independent variables and the respective theoretical reasoning.

Table 1. Summary of hypotheses, expected effects of independent variables, and theoretical reasoning

Hypothesis 6 Expert appointments are more common in portfolios with low party support in the bureaucracy.

Case selection and data

To answer our research question we study the appointments of Austrian post-war ministers and junior ministers (1945–2020). Austria is a typical party democracy, resembling many other parliamentary democracies regarding key characteristics of the political system. In terms of outsider appointments, it is an unlikely case compared to other countries, given Austrian parties’ organizational strength and traditionally strong roots in society (Müller and Philipp, Reference Müller and Philipp1987; Andeweg Reference Andeweg, Blondel and Cotta2000 a; Scarrow et al., Reference Scarrow, Webb and Poguntke2017). Findings on outsider appointments should thus be likely to generalize to other European parliamentary democracies. Notwithstanding change over time due to the state of modernization and integration in supranational organizations, we expect the overall demand for expertise in ministerial office to be similar across contemporary democracies. However, Austria should be a critical case in terms of the relationship between outsiderness and expertise. Given political parties’ dominant role in society and state – and their linkages to corporatist interest organizations in particular (Ennser-Jedenastik, Reference Ennser-Jedenastik2017) – Austrian parties should have larger recruitment pools for experts within the party (that is, insiders who are also experts) than governing parties in other countries. As a consequence, the correlation between outsiderness and expertise should be modest compared to other countries, where expertise may be more exclusively confined to outsider appointees. The Austrian case therefore provides a particularly suitable empirical basis to disentangle the drivers of outsider and expert appointments. We analyze original data on the career trajectories of cabinet members, collected from three online sources: the official website of the Austrian Parliament, Wikipedia, and the Munzinger biographical data base.

In line with most of the extant literature, ministers and junior ministers without elected public office or party affiliation prior to their appointment are classified as outsiders (McDonnell and Valbruzzi, Reference McDonnell and Valbruzzi2014; Cotta, Reference Cotta2018; Bertsou and Caramani Reference Bertsou, Caramani, Bertsou and Caramani2020 a). Furthermore, we also code as outsiders those ministers who held public office for or were affiliated to any party other than the nominating party before their appointment (e.g. party switchers).

We then define occupational areas where expertise can be acquired for each ministerial portfolio and code ministers as experts when their area of expertise matches the portfolio they are appointed to. For instance – amongst other things – a prior position in the central bank qualifies a minister as an expert finance minister, the education portfolio requires a career in the educational system, lawyers and judges are experts for the justice portfolio, diplomats are considered foreign policy experts and a career in business (e.g. management positions), business associations or trade unions qualifies a minister as an expert for the economic affairs and employment portfolios. We also coded individuals with jobs in the state bureaucracy that relate to their ministry, with sub-national executive offices matching their portfolio’s policy jurisdictions, with leading functions in related parliamentary committees and with academic careers in corresponding fields as expert ministers. Footnote 3 Using these detailed portfolio-specific measures for expertise, we seek to extend the scope of previous empirical studies on the topic (McDonnell and Valbruzzi, Reference McDonnell and Valbruzzi2014; Alexiadou, Reference Alexiadou2016; Costa Pinto et al., Reference Costa Pinto, Cotta and Almeidad2018; Bertsou and Caramani Reference Bertsou and Caramani2020 b) and to anticipate the biases towards economic training and the natural sciences that exist in the extant literature (Bertsou and Caramani Reference Bertsou, Caramani, Bertsou and Caramani2020 a).

To test Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 4 we operationalize parties’ core issues based on issue salience in election manifestos. Specifically, we build on the Austrian National Election Study’s coding of electoral manifestos (Müller et al., Reference Müller, Dolezal, Ennser-Jedenastik and Winkler2012; Dolezal et al., Reference Dolezal, Ennser-Jedenastik, Müller and Winkler2016), assigning issue-areas to every portfolio and recording the proportion dedicated to these areas in each manifesto (Bäck et al., Reference Bäck, Debus and Dumont2011; Ecker et al., Reference Ecker, Meyer and Müller2015). In cases where two or more policy portfolios are combined in one ministry, we use the sum of the salience scores of all portfolios bundled in a ministry to accurately reflect the post’s value to the party. We utilize individual ministries’ shares of the overall budget (across all portfolios within a cabinet) to measure portfolios’ budgetary resources (Hypothesis 2). Given that there are only minor variations across the annual budgets of individual ministries within the same cabinet, we use the financial resources budgeted for each ministry in the second year of the government’s tenure. This information was extracted from annual reports (Bundesrechnungsabschluss) published by the Austrian Court of Audit, which are available for the years 1961–2021. Footnote 4 Due to skewness of the issue salience and budgetary resources measures, we use the logged versions of both variables in our regression models. To operationalize ministers’ appointment powers (Hypothesis 3) we use two indicators. First, we count the number of departments (Sektionen) Footnote 5 per ministry as listed in the Amtskalender, the official registry of state institutions and public administration. Footnote 6 Second, we code a dummy variable that equals one for the few ministries that control the bulk of appointments to state-owned enterprises: finance, economic affairs, state industries, and infrastructure (Ennser-Jedenastik Reference Ennser-Jedenastik2013 a). Parties’ support in the bureaucracies of each ministry (Hypothesis 5, Hypothesis 6) is measured based on the results of staff representatives’ elections which are available for the years 1967–2020. In these elections, all public employees at the federal level elect their representatives from party lists.

In addition to the main explanatory variables, we include various controls in our statistical models. To account for residual differences in the ‘objective’ value of ministerial portfolios (e.g. stemming from the prestige associated with specific portfolios), we use portfolio salience ratings by Druckman and Warwick (Reference Druckman and Warwick2005). Footnote 7 Moreover, we include a dummy variable for ministries that are the traditional domains of the Austrian social partnership: social affairs, economic affairs, health, and agriculture. Due to the close linkages between corporatist interest organizations (unions, chambers) and the two (erstwhile) major parties, SPÖ and ÖVP (Ennser-Jedenastik, Reference Ennser-Jedenastik2017), there is a large pool of partisans with high levels of expertise in these domains. Hence, we expect these ministries to have fewer outsider and more expert appointments.

As the party leader of a governing party – who typically also receives the most valuable government post available to the party – plays a crucial role in nominating ministerial candidates (Andeweg Reference Andeweg, Blondel and Cotta2000 b; Strøm et al., Reference Strøm, Müller and Smith2010), we account for party leaders’ career trajectories in the statistical models. We expect outsider appointments to be more likely when the party leader did not take the traditional party route to office as such leaders should have smaller personal networks within the party organization than traditional party leaders would. We therefore include a dummy variable indicating whether the party leader was a member of the party executive before appointment to government office.

Anticipating likely differences in ministerial selection dynamics between first-round appointments (usually following elections and coalition negotiations) and appointments in cabinet reshuffles, we incorporate a dummy for cabinet reshuffles in our regression models. We also use control variables for appointments to two types of junior minister posts to account for different job-requirements in terms of insiderness and expertise that the roles senior minister, co-partisan junior minister and watchdog junior minister might entail. For instance, while insiders should be a better fit for the watchdog role (e.g. monitoring a coalition partner in the best interest of the party) than outsiders, experts might be a good choice for junior ministers supporting a co-partisan senior minister.

Finally, we include fixed effects for decades and parties in all statistical models to account for variation due to party-specific factors and time trends.

Analysis

We first present some descriptive information. Figure 1 displays the percentage of four ministerial types over time: non-expert insiders, expert insiders, expert outsiders, and non-expert outsiders. Outsider appointments were relatively common in the immediate post-war period (around 20%), as new elites that were untarnished by the preceding twelve years of authoritarian rule were sought after. Once the political system had stabilized, outsider appointments became a more marginal phenomenon. Only from around 2000 has there been a significant increase to, again, one in five appointments in the recent decade.

Figure 1. Minister types over time and for selected portfolios (1945–2020).

Expert appointments (which include insiders) are more common in general. They experience a first peak during the social democratic single-party cabinets of the 1970s, then again during the grand coalitions of the 1990s, and reach an all-time high in the 2010s. This increase holds when excluding the non-partisan cabinet Bierlein that was installed following the 2019 ‘Ibiza affair’ and the subsequent vote of no confidence in the first cabinet of Sebastian Kurz.

Looking across portfolios Footnote 8 there is a significant gradient between those that do not typically feature expert ministers (Interior, Finance, Defense) and those that do (Justice, Social Affairs, Agriculture). Given the significant prosecutorial powers of the minister of justice (he or she can give instructions to all public prosecutors in individual cases), this position has often been filled with non-partisans (and thus outsiders). Outsiders were also common in the finance ministry during the early post-war period.

To illustrate the relationship between outsider and expert status, Table 2 shows a cross-tabulation of the two variables. There is a moderately strong and statistically significant correlation between the two (Cramèr’s V is 0.34, $p \lt 0.001$ ). This largely reflects the fact that there are hardly any non-expert outsiders Footnote 9 : While 26% of expert appointments are also outsider appointments, the same is true for only 3% of non-expert appointments. Overall, the largest group by far are non-expert insiders who make up more than half of all appointments.

Table 2. Outsider and expert appointments (1945–2020)

Next, we present binary logistic regressions with outsider and expert status as the dependent variables (Table 3). Footnote 10 To account for heterogeneity between and dependence within governments, we specify cabinet-level random effects and cabinet-clustered standard errors. Models I and III use all available data points, whereas Models II and IV exclude appointments to junior minister positions (JMs) from the analysis.

Table 3. Explaining outsider and expert appointments (1967–2020)

Note: Cabinet-clusteredstandard errors in parentheses.

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.

Note that the variable ‘party support in bureaucracy’ is only available from 1967 (when elections for employee representatives were introduced). In addition, the variable has some missing data points in later years, for example, when a ministry was newly created (often through splits and mergers). In such cases, the variable only has values after the next round of elections which take place every four (up until 1999) or five (after 1999) years.

Let us first examine the results pertaining to outsider appointments. In Models I and II, we find no statistically significant effects for issue salience and thus no support for Hypothesis 1. Outsiders are no more likely to be appointed to portfolios dealing with high- or low-salience issues. Likewise, results are inconclusive with regard to our expectation that ministries controlling greater budgets see fewer outsider appointments Hypothesis 2. While coefficients are negative in Models I and II, as expected, they do not reach conventional levels of statistical significance. Footnote 11

We also find no significant effects for appointment power, at least in the full model. Neither the number of departments nor the indicator for portfolios controlling the bulk of potential patronage appointments yield significant coefficients in Model I. Only when excluding junior ministers (who have no appointment powers) do we find a positive effect of the number of departments (counter to Hypothesis 3). While patronage powers sustain a negative impact on outsider appointment (in line with Hypothesis 3) in Model II, the effect is insignificant. Overall, there is thus only limited evidence in support of Hypothesis 3.

The strongest finding in Models I and II pertains to the effect of party support in the bureaucracy. Here we find a statistically significant positive effect that is in line with Hypothesis 5: As predicted by the ally principle, greater party support among bureaucrats is associated with more outsider appointments. What is more, Figure 2 shows that this effect is by no means small. Across the empirical range of the party support variable, the predicted probability of an outsider appointment increases from below five to around 33%. This result holds when limiting the sample to experts or first appointments (thus excluding re-appointments of ministers in subsequent cabinets) or when examining only SPÖ or only ÖVP ministers (who, together, constitute the vast majority of appointments). Our analysis thus yields strong support for the expectation that the partisan leanings of the bureaucracy are correlated with the probability of outsiders being chosen as ministers.

Figure 2. Predicted probabilities of outsider and expert appointments for selected independent variables (based on Models I and III).

Next, we turn to expert appointments. Model III yields strong evidence that experts are more likely to be appointed to high-salience portfolios as measured by manifesto data, thus supporting the argument that such appointments are less risky in salient portfolios. This result holds when limiting the sample to senior ministers (Model IV). As the graph in Figure 2 shows, the probability of an expert appointment increases from around 40% to around 60% when moving from a low-salience issue (2% of the manifesto) to a high-salience one (a third of the manifesto). Parties are thus more likely to put experts into portfolios that they deem more electorally important, as predicted by Hypothesis 4. Finally, there is no effect of party support among ministerial bureaucrats on the probability of experts being appointed to a portfolio and thus no support for Hypothesis 6. Hence, while nominating parties use loyal bureaucracies to monitor outsider ministers (as well as insider ministers to deal with bureaucracies of a different political leaning) (Hypothesis 5), they do not employ expert ministers to minimize the potential for sabotage posed by a hostile body of bureaucrats.

Among control variables we find substantial effects of the social partnership portfolio variable on outsider and expert appointments, as expected. Likewise, outsider appointments are less likely in cabinet reshuffles (Models I and II) and under party leaders who worked their way to government through the party machine (Model II). Unexpectedly, we also find pronounced negative effects of the junior minister post variables (co-partisan and watchdog) on expert appointments in Model III, while outsider appointments are not affected.

Discussion and conclusion

This paper contributes novel perspectives to the study of ministerial appointments. Conceptualizing outsiderness and expertise as independent dimensions, the paper identifies distinct drivers of outsider and expert appointments based on theories of political delegation. By demonstrating how portfolio characteristics condition appointments of different types of ministers this study also extends the scope of the existing literature, which largely focuses on country and cabinet-level explanations.

The empirical analysis supports the theoretical argument that nominating parties anticipate the potential for agency loss in individual portfolios and select ministerial candidates accordingly. Outsiders are more likely appointed to portfolios where a friendly ministerial bureaucracy might contain deviations from the party agenda. Likewise, parties minimize delegation problems by appointing experts to portfolios where they have access to larger pools of ideologically compatible experts, while refraining from expert appointments elsewhere. Only one of three expectations derived from that line of reasoning, namely that expert ministers are more likely appointed to portfolios with a high risk of sabotage by the ministerial bureaucracy, is not supported by the statistical models.

In contrast, a portfolio’s value to the party in terms of policy, budgetary resources and appointment powers does not affect outsider appointments – at least not in a statistically significant way. Parties are thus no more willing to make risky appointments to portfolios where the stakes are comparatively low than to ministries where agency loss comes at a higher cost. Overall, our findings therefore indicate that, while parties minimize the risk of agency loss when making ministerial appointments, they avoid taking chances even for portfolios where the potential damage from agency loss is relatively small.

Due to specific characteristics of the case, studying Austria provides the opportunity to disentangle drivers of outsider and expert appointments, which are independent in theory, yet correlated empirically. This correlation is asymmetric, though: Most outsiders in our sample are experts, yet most experts are not outsiders. Thus, the appointment of ministers who cannot claim legitimacy from a party mandate needs to be justified on the basis of their portfolio-specific qualification. While results on both variables – outsiderness and expertise – should generalize reasonably well to other parliamentary democracies with multiparty systems, the high level of politicization in the Austrian ministerial bureaucracy and the social partnership model may constrain their external validity. Comparative research will therefore be required to test the validity of the findings in other contexts.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773922000285.

Acknowledgements

Matthias Kaltenegger gratefully acknowledges funding from the Austrian Science Fund (FWF) (grant no. P33596). Laurenz Ennser-Jedenastik gratefully acknowledges funding from the European Research Council (grant. no 945501) and from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG, German Research Foundation) – project ID 139943784 – SFB 884.

Footnotes

1 For notable exceptions see Alexiadou (Reference Alexiadou2016), Alexiadou and Gunaydin (Reference Alexiadou and Gunaydin2019) and Lavezzolo et al. (Reference Lavezzolo, Ramiro and Fernández-Vázquez2021).

2 Given the two dimensions of outsiderness and expertise, it would, in theory, be possible to build our argument with respect to four types of ministers: expert and non-expert insiders, expert and non-expert outsiders. Yet, this would require theorizing the effects of the independent variables on the prevalence of each of the four ministerial types and thus make our argument unwieldy. For the benefit of theoretical clarity, we thus put forward our hypotheses with respect to the two dimensions independently of each other.

3 For additional information on our expertise measure, please consult the online appendix, Table A8.

4 These reports can easily be obtained from the Austrian parliament’s website: https://www.parlament.gv.at/PAKT/RGES/.

5 Ministries are divided into departments (Sektionen), subdepartments (Gruppen), divisions (Abteilungen), and subdivisions (Referate) (Liegl and Müller, Reference Liegl, Müller, Page and Wright1999).

7 In cases where two or more portfolios are bundled in one ministry, we use the salience rating of the most important portfolio. This is because some relatively unimportant portfolios – which are frequently bundled with portfolios of higher value – are not included in the Druckman and Warwick (Reference Druckman and Warwick2005) expert survey. Using the sum of the salience ratings for bundled portfolios would thus introduce bias due to missing values for such ‘secondary’ portfolios. Note, however, that maximum portfolio salience and total portfolio salience are closely correlated (r=0.79).

8 We present numbers for those nine portfolios that remain relatively stable over longer periods of time and thus provide at least N $ \gt $ 30 in terms of appointments.

9 There are idiosyncratic reasons for the twelve appointments of non-expert outsiders in our data-set that go beyond our theoretical model. For instance, Austria’s first post-war cabinet included a member of the resistance movement ‘O5’ who was neither a partisan at the time nor a policy expert.

10 As an alternative, we present multinomial logit models predicting three ministerial types (non-expert insiders, expert insiders, and expert outsiders) in Table A3 in the online appendix. The substantive conclusions are identical to the ones presented here.

11 Note that the issue salience and budget share variables correlate (r=0.51). Still, eliminating either variable from the estimation does not alter the result for the other one.

References

Alexiadou, D. (2016), Ideologues, Partisans, and Loyalists: Ministers and Policymaking in Parliamentary Cabinets, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexiadou, D. and Gunaydin, H. (2019), ‘Commitment or expertise? Technocratic appointments as political responses to economic crises’, European Journal of Political Research 58(3): 845865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allern, E.H., Hansen, V.W., Marshall, D., Rasmussen, A. and Webb, P.D. (2021), ‘Competition and interaction: Party ties to interest groups in a multidimensional policy space’, European Journal of Political Research 60(2): 275294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amorim Neto, O. and Strøm, K. (2006), ‘Breaking the parliamentary chain of delegation: Presidents and non-partisan cabinet members in European democracies’, British Journal of Political Science 36(4): 619643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andeweg, R.B. (2000a), ‘Party government, state and society: Mapping boundaries and interrelations’, in Blondel, J. and Cotta, M. (eds.), The Nature of Party Government. A Comparative Perspective, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 3855.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andeweg, R.B. (2000b), ‘Political recruitment and party government’, in Blondel, J. and Cotta, M. (eds.), The Nature of Party Government. A Comparative Perspective, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 119140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H., Debus, M. and Dumont, P. (2011), ‘Who gets what in coalition governments? predictors of portfolio allocation in parliamentary democracies’, European Journal of Political Research 50(4): 441478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Batista, M. (2017), ‘Taking portfolios difference seriously: a composite measure based on policy, office, and budget in Brazil’, Brazilian Political Science Review 11(1): e0006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H., Debus, M. and Dumont, P. (2011), ‘Who gets what in coalition governments? Predictors of portfolio allocation in parliamentary democracies’, European Journal of Political Research 50(4): 441478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H., Debus, M. and Müller, W.C. (2016), ‘Intra-party diversity and ministerial selection in coalition governments’, Public Choice 166(3-4): 355378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H., Müller, W.C., Angelova, M. and Strobl, D. (2022), ‘Ministerial autonomy, parliamentary scrutiny and government reform output in parliamentary democracies’, Comparative Political Studies 55(2): 254286.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bendor, J. and Meirowitz, A. (2004), ‘Spatial models of delegation’, American Political Science Review 98(2): 293310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertelli, A. and Feldmann, S.E. (2007), ‘Strategic appointments’, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 17(1): 1938.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertsou, E. and Caramani, D. (2020a), ‘Measuring technocracy’, in Bertsou, E. and Caramani, D. (eds.), The Technocratic Challenge to Democracy, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertsou, E. and Caramani, D. (eds.) (2020b), The Technocratic Challenge to Democracy, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blondel, J. and Cotta, M. (2000), The Nature of Party Government: A Comparative European Perspective, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bojar, A. (2019), ‘With a little help from my friends: Ministerial alignment and public spending composition in parliamentary democracies’, Political Research Exchange 1(1): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunclk, M. and Parzek, M. (2019), ‘When are technocratic cabinets formed?’, Comparative European Politics 17(5): 759777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budge, I. and Farlie, D.J. (1983), Explaining and Predicting Elections: Issue Effects and Party Strategies in 23 Democracies, London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Caramani, D. (2017), ‘Will vs. reason: The populist and technocratic forms of political representation and their critique to party government’, American Political Science Review 111(1): 5467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caramani, D. (2020), ‘Introduction’, in Bertsou, E. and Caramani, D. (eds.), The Technocratic Challenge to Democracy, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Centeno, M.A. (1993), ‘The new leviathan: The dynamics and limits of technocracy’, Theory and Society 22(3): 307335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ceron, A. (2014), ‘Gamson rule not for all: Patterns of portfolio allocation among Italian party factions’, European Journal of Political Research 53(1): 180199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa Pinto, A., Cotta, M. and Almeidad, P.T. (2018), Technocratic Ministers and Political Leadership in European Democracies, Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cotta, M. (2018), ‘Technocratic government versus party government? Non-partisan ministers and the changing parameters of political leadership in european democracies’, in A. Costa Pinto, M. Cotta and P. T. d. Almeida (eds.), Technocratic Ministers and Political Leadership in European Democracies, Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 267–288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dolezal, M., Ennser-Jedenastik, L., Müller, W.C. and Winkler, A.K. (2016), ‘Analyzing manifestos in their electoral context: A new approach applied to Austria, 2002–2008*’, Political Science Research and Methods 4(3): 641650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Druckman, J.N. and Warwick, P.V. (2005), ‘The missing piece: Measuring portfolio salience in Western European parliamentary democracies’, European Journal of Political Research 44(1): 1742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ecker, A., Meyer, T.M. and Müller, W.C. (2015), ‘The distribution of individual cabinet positions in coalition governments: A sequential approach’, European Journal of Political Research 54(4): 802818.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ennser-Jedenastik, L. (2013a), ‘Die Parteipolitische Besetzung von Spitzenfunktionen in Österreichischen Staatsunternehmen: Eine Quantitative Analyse’, Österreichische Zeitschrift für Politikwissenschaft 42(2): 125143.Google Scholar
Ennser-Jedenastik, L. (2014), ‘Political control and managerial survival in state-owned enterprises’, Governance 27(1): 135161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ennser-Jedenastik, L. (2017), ‘Die personelle Verflechtung zwischen Sozialpartnern und Bundesregierung in Österreich, 1945–2015’, Austrian Journal of Political Science 45(3).Google Scholar
Ennser-Jedenastik, L.P. (2013b), ‘Portfolio allocation within parties: The role of regional party branches’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 19(3): 309327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, F. (2009), Democracy and Expertise: Reorienting Policy Inquiry, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garritzmann, J.L. and Seng, K. (2016), ‘Party politics and education spending: challenging some common wisdom’, Journal of European Public Policy 23(4): 510530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilardi, F. (2005), ‘The institutional foundations of regulatory capitalism: the diffusion of independent regulatory agencies in Western Europe’, The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598(1): 84101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goddard, D. (2019), ‘Examining the appointment of women to ministerial positions across Europe: 1970–2015’, Party Politics (Online First).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green-Pedersen, C. (2007), ‘The growing importance of issue competition: The changing nature of party competition in Western Europe’, Political Studies 55(3): 607628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habermas, J. (1973), Legitimationsprobleme im Spätkapitalismus, Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp.Google Scholar
Hesstvedt, S. and Christiansen, P.M. (2022), ‘The politics of policy inquiry commissions: Denmark and Norway, 1971-2017’, West European Politics 45(2): 430454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J.D. (2000), ‘Delegation to civil servants in parliamentary democracies’, European Journal of Political Research 37(3): 397413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J.D. and Shipan, C.R. (2006), ‘Politics, delegation, and bureaucracy’, in Goodin, R.E. (ed.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Science, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 256272.Google Scholar
Kam, C., Bianco, W.T., Sened, I. and Smyth, R. (2010), ‘Ministerial selection and intraparty organization in the contemporary British parliament’, American Political Science Review 104(2): 289306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, R.S. (1986), ‘Party government: A rationalistic conception’, in Castles, F.G. and Wildenmann, R. (eds.), Visions and Realities of Party Government, Berlin: de Gruyter, pp. 3171.Google Scholar
Kopecký, P., Mair, P. and Spirova, M. (2012), Party Patronage and Party Government in European Democracies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M.J. and Shepsle, K.A. (1990), ‘Coalitions and cabinet government’, American Political Science Review 84(3): 873890.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M.J. and Shepsle, K.A. (1996), Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lavezzolo, S., Ramiro, L. and Fernández-Vázquez, P. (2021), ‘The will for reason: voter demand for experts in office’, West European Politics 44(7): 15061531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lefevere, J., Tresch, A. and Walgrave, S. (2015), ‘Introduction: Issue ownership’, West European Politics 38(4): 755760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D.E. (2008), The Politics of Presidential Appointments. Political Control and Bureaucratic Performance, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liegl, B. and Müller, W.C. (1999), ‘Senior officials in Austria’, in Page, E.C. and Wright, V. (eds.), Bureaucratic Elites in Western European States, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 90120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mair, P. (2008), ‘The challenge to party government’, West European Politics 31(1-2): 211234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Majone, G. (1994), ‘The rise of the regulatory state in Europe’, West European Politics 17: 77101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsh, D., ‘t Hart, P. and Tindall, K. (2010), ‘Celebrity politics: The politics of the late modernity?’, Political Studies Review 8(3): 322340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonnell, D. and Valbruzzi, M. (2014), ‘Defining and classifying technocrat-led and technocratic governments’, European Journal of Political Research 53(4): 654671.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mershon, C. (2001), ‘Party factions and coalition government: portfolio allocation in Italian Christian Democracy’, Electoral Studies 20: 555580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer-Sahling, J.-H. (2008), ‘The changing colours of the post-communist state: The politicisation of the senior civil service in hungary’, European Journal of Political Research 47(1): 133.Google Scholar
Meynaud, J. (1964), La Technocratie. Mythe ou Réalité, Paris: Les Éditions Payot.Google Scholar
Müller, W.C. (2000), ‘Patronage by national governments’, in The Nature of Party Government: A Comparative Perspective, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Müller, W.C., Dolezal, M., Ennser-Jedenastik, L. and Winkler, A.K. (2012), ‘AUTNES Coding Instructions for Manifestos,’ Retrieved from http://data.autnes.at/datadownload.htm.Google Scholar
Müller, W.C. and Philipp, W. (1987), ‘Parteienregierung und Regierungsparteien in Österreich.’, Österreichische Zeitschrift für Politikwissenschaft 16(3): 277302.Google Scholar
Müller, W.C. (2000a), ‘Political parties in parliamentary democracies: Making delegation and accountability work’, European Journal of Political Research 37(3): 309333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, W.C. (2000b), ‘Wahlen und die Dynamik des österreichischen Parteiensystems seit 1986’, in Plasser, F., Ulram, P.A. and Sommer, F. (eds.), Das österreichische Wahlverhalten, Vol. 21. Schriftenreihe des Zentrums für Angewandte Politikforschung, Wien: Signum, pp. 1354.Google Scholar
Müller, W.C. (2007), ‘The changing role of the Austrian civil service: The impact of politicisation, public sector reform, and Europeanisation’, in Page, E.C. and Wright, V. (eds.), From the Active to the Enabling State, London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 3862.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, W.C. and Meyer, T.M. (2010), ‘Meeting the challenges of representation and accountability in multi-party governments’, West European Politics 33(5): 10651092.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otjes, S. and Green-Pedersen, C. (2021), ‘When do political parties prioritize labour? issue attention between party competition and interest group power’, Party Politics 27(4): 619630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otjes, S. and Rasmussen, A. (2017), ‘The collaboration between interest groups and political parties in multi-party democracies: Party system dynamics and the effect of power and ideology’, Party Politics 23(2): 96109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, E. and Wright, V. (1999), Bureaucratic Elites in Western European States, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, R. (1974), The Problem of Party Government, London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, L. (2019), ‘The politics of social spending after the great recession: The return of partisan policy making’, Governance 32(1): 123141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scarrow, S.E., Webb, P.D. and Poguntke, T. (eds.) (2017), Organizing Political Parties: Representation, Participation, and Power, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schleiter, P. and Morgan-Jones, E. (2009), ‘Party government in Europe? Parliamentary and semi-presidential democracies compared’, European Journal of Political Research 48(5): 665693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, G., Vis, B. and Van Kersbergen, K. (2013), ‘Political parties’ welfare image, electoral punishment and welfare state retrenchment’, Comparative European Politics 11(1): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sánchez-Cuenca, I. (2017), ‘From a deficit of democracy to a technocratic order: The postcrisis debate on Europe’, Annual Review of Political Science 20(1): 351369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Street, J. (2012), ‘Do celebrity politics and celebrity politicians matter?’, The British Journal of Politics and International Relations 14(3): 346356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K. (2000), ‘Delegation and accountability in parliamentary democracies’, European Journal of Political Research 37(3): 261290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K., Müller, W.C. and Smith, D.M. (2010), ‘Parliamentary Control of Coalition Governments’, Annual Review of Political Science 13(1): 517535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Haute, E. and Carty, R.K. (2012), ‘Ideological misfits: A distinctive class of party members’, Party Politics 18(6): 885895.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walgrave, S., Lefevere, J. and Nuytemans, M. (2009), ‘Issue ownership stability and change: How political parties claim and maintain issues through media appearances’, Political Communication 26(2): 153172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wratil, C. and Pastorella, G. (2018), ‘Dodging the bullet: How crises trigger technocrat-led governments’, European Journal of Political Research 57(2): 450472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Summary of hypotheses, expected effects of independent variables, and theoretical reasoning

Figure 1

Figure 1. Minister types over time and for selected portfolios (1945–2020).

Figure 2

Table 2. Outsider and expert appointments (1945–2020)

Figure 3

Table 3. Explaining outsider and expert appointments (1967–2020)

Figure 4

Figure 2. Predicted probabilities of outsider and expert appointments for selected independent variables (based on Models I and III).

Supplementary material: PDF

Kaltenegger and Ennser-Jedenastik supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Kaltenegger and Ennser-Jedenastik supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 291.4 KB