Hostname: page-component-669899f699-swprf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-05-07T02:14:48.028Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Learning to cooperate in the shadow of the law

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Roberto Galbiati*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, CNRS-Sciences Po and CEPR, 28 rue des Saints-Pères, 75007 Paris, France
Emeric Henry*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, CNRS-Sciences Po and CEPR, 28 rue des Saints-Pères, 75007 Paris, France
Nicolas Jacquemet*
Affiliation:
Paris School of Economics and University Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne, 106 Bd de l’hopital, 75013 Paris, France

Abstract

Formal enforcement punishing defectors can sustain cooperation by changing incentives. In this paper, we introduce a second effect of enforcement: it can also affect the capacity to learn about the group's cooperativeness. Indeed, in contexts with strong enforcement, it is difficult to tell apart those who cooperate because of the threat of fines from those who are intrinsically cooperative types. Whenever a group is intrinsically cooperative, enforcement will thus have a negative dynamic effect on cooperation because it slows down learning about prevalent values in the group that would occur under a weaker enforcement. We provide theoretical and experimental evidence in support of this mechanism. Using a lab experiment with independent interactions and random rematching, we observe that, in early interactions, having faced an environment with fines in the past decreases current cooperation. We further show that this results from the interaction between enforcement and learning: the effect of having met cooperative partners has a stronger effect on current cooperation when this happened in an environment with no enforcement. Replacing one signal of deviation without fine by a signal of cooperation without fine in a player's history increases current cooperation by 10%; while replacing it by a signal of cooperation with fine increases current cooperation by only 5%.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2024.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Acemoglu, D, Jackson, MO. (2015). History, expectations, and leadership in the evolution of social norms. Review of Economic Studies, 82, 2, 423456. 10.1093/restud/rdu039.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D, Jackson, MO. (2017). Social norms and the enforcement of laws. Journal of the European Economic Association, 15, 2, 245295.Google Scholar
Ali, SN, Bénabou, R. (2020). Image versus information: Changing societal norms and optimal privacy. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 12, 3, 116164.Google Scholar
Azrieli, Y, Chambers, CP, Healy, PJ. (2018). Incentives in experiments: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 126, 4, 14721503. 10.1086/698136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, RM, McCaffrey, DF. (2002). Bias reduction in standard errors for linear regression with multi-stage samples. Survey Methodology, 28, 2, 169179.Google Scholar
Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2011). Laws and norms. NBER WP 17579.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bérgolo, M, Ceni, R, Cruces, G, Giaccobasso, M, Pérez-Truglia, R. (2021). Tax audits as scarecrows. Evidence from a large-scale field experiment. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2021, 1.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (2008). Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine the moral sentiments: Evidence from economic experiments. Science, 320, 5883, 16051609. 10.1126/science.1152110.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cameron, AC, Gelbach, JB, Miller, DL. (2008). Bootstrap-based improvements for inference with clustered errors. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90, 3, 414427. 10.1162/rest.90.3.414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, E, Dal Bó, P. (2014). ‘Do the right thing’: The effects of moral suasion on cooperation. Journal of Public Economics, 117, 2838. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2014.05.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, P, Fréchette, GR. (2011). The evolution of cooperation in infinitely repeated games: Experimental evidence. American Economic Review, 101, 1, 411429. 10.1257/aer.101.1.411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deffains, B, Fluet, C. (2020). Social norms and legal design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 36, 1, 139169.Google Scholar
Dohmen, T, Falk, A, Huffman, D, Sunde, U, Schupp, J, Wagner, GG. (2011). Individual risk attitudes: Measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, 3, 522550. 10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01015.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J, Fehr, D. (2018). Equilibrium selection in similar repeated games: Experimental evidence on the role of precedents. Experimental Economics, 21, 3, 573600. 10.1007/s10683-017-9531-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutta, R, Levine, DK, Modica, S. (2021). Interventions with sticky social norms: A critique. Journal of the European Economic Association., 2021, 1.Google Scholar
Engl, F, Riedl, A, Weber, R. (2021). Spillover effects of institutions on cooperative behavior. Preferences, and Beliefs, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 13, 4, 261299.Google Scholar
Falk, A, Kosfeld, M. (2006). The hidden costs of control. American Economic Review, 96, 5, 16111630. 10.1257/aer.96.5.1611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortin, B, Lacroix, G, Villeval, M-C. (2007). Tax evasion and social interactions. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 11–12, 20892112. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.03.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friebel, G, Schnedler, W. (2011). Team governance: Empowerment or hierarchical control. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 78, 1–2, 113. 10.1016/j.jebo.2010.12.003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbiati, R, Henry, E, Jacquemet, N. (2018). Dynamic effects of enforcement on cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 115, 49, 1242512428. 10.1073/pnas.1813502115.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galbiati, R, Schlag, KH, Van Der Weele, JJ. (2013). Sanctions that signal: An experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 94, 3451. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.08.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galizzi, MM, Whitmarsh, LE. (2019). How to measure behavioural spillovers? A methodological review and checklist. Frontiers in Psychology, 10, 342. 10.3389/fpsyg.2019.00342.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gill, D., & Rosokha, Y. (2020). Beliefs, learning, and personality in the indefinitely repeated Prisoner's dilemma. CAGE online working paper series 489.Google Scholar
Kartal, M., & Müller, W. (2018). A new approach to the analysis of cooperation under the shadow of the future: Theory and experimental evidence. Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, MA, Roch, S. (2007). Upstream reciprocity and the evolution of gratitude. Proceedings of the Royal Society B-Biological Sciences, 274, 1610, 605609. 10.1098/rspb.2006.0125.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Peysakhovich, A, Rand, DG. (2016). Habits of virtue: Creating norms of cooperation and defection in the laboratory. Management Science, 62, 3, 631647. 10.1287/mnsc.2015.2168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sliwka, D. (2007). Trust as a signal of a social norm and the hidden costs of incentive schemes. American Economic Review, 97, 3, 9991012. 10.1257/aer.97.3.999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Der Weele, JJ. (2009). The signaling power of sanctions in social dilemmas. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 28, 1, 103126. 10.1093/jleo/ewp039.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zasu, Y. (2007). Sanctions by social norms and the law: Substitutes or complements?. The Journal of Legal Studies, 36, 2, 379396. 10.1086/511896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar