Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T02:58:41.727Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The CEO Horizon Problem and Managerial Slack in China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 May 2018

Junxiong Fang
Affiliation:
Fudan University, China
Lerong He*
Affiliation:
The College at Brockport, State University of New York, USA Fuzhou University, China
Martin J. Conyon
Affiliation:
Bentley University, USA
*
Corresponding author: Lerong He ([email protected])
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This study investigates how CEO behavior and incentives change during the CEO's final years in office, known as the horizon problem. We examine how the horizon problem alters managerial slack, a measure of operational inefficiency and managerial value diversion. Using data on Chinese publicly traded firms between 2003 and 2011, we find that managerial slack increases in the last two years of CEO tenure compared to earlier years. We also show that the increase in managerial slack in CEO final years in office is smaller in privately controlled firms than in state-owned enterprises, smaller in firms with CEO equity ownership and more independent boards compared to those without. We conclude that higher quality corporate governance mechanisms ameliorate the perverse incentives associated with the CEO horizon problem, and reduce CEOs’ tendency to increase managerial slack during their final years in office.

摘要:

摘要:

本文考察CEO任职期限效应, 即CEO离职前的行为和动机变化。具体而言, 本文研究CEO任职期限问题对企业组织冗余和管理者侵占挪用公司资产的影响。基于2003-2011年中国上市公司的样本, 本研究发现, 相比以前年份, CEO离职前最后两年的组织冗余显著更高。进一步研究表明, CEO任职期限效应对组织冗余的影响在民营上市公司, 以及董事会独立性高和管理层持股的企业中较弱。综上所述, 本文指出良好的公司治理机制有助于缓解CEO任职期限效应所导致的委托代理问题, 从而减轻CEO在临近离职时为满足自身利益通过浪费或挪用公司资产而导致组织冗余增加的现象。

यह शोध अध्ययन यह अनुसंधान करता है कि किस प्रकार कॉर्पोरेट मुख्य अधिशासी के अंतिम दिनों में उनके व्यवहार और प्रोत्साहन में परिवर्तन होता है, जिसको दिग्मंडलीय चुनौती कहा जाता है. हमने यह परीक्षण किया है कि किस प्रकार दिग्मंडलीय चुनौती प्रबंधकीय शिथिलता को बदलती है, जो की परिचालन क्षमता सम्बद्ध प्रबंधकीय मूल्य विपथन के मानक हैं. चीन की सार्वजनिक सूचीबद्ध कंपनियों का 2003 से 2011 के बीच के आंकड़ों के आधार पर हमने यह पाया की आरम्भिक वर्षों की तुलना में प्रबंधकीय शिथिलता अंतिम दो वर्षों में बढ़ जाती है. साथ ही हमने यह पाया की ऑफिस के अंतिम दो वर्षों की प्रबंधकीय शिथिलता निजी स्वामित्व वाली फर्मों में राजकीय स्वामित्व वाली फर्मों की तुलना में कम होती है. प्रबंधकीय शिथिलता मुख्य अधिशासी के इक्विटी स्वामित्व व बोर्ड की स्वतंत्रता से इस से इतर परिस्थितियों वाली फर्मों से कम होती है. हमारा यह निष्कर्ष है की उच्च स्तरीय कॉर्पोरेट प्रशासन तंत्र मुख्य अधिशासी सम्बद्ध दिग्मंडलीय चुनौती से जुड़े विकृत प्रोत्साहन को सुधारता है और साथ ही मुख्य अधिशासी के ऑफिस के अंतिम वर्षों में प्रबंधकीय शिथिलता बढ़ने की प्रवृत्ति को कम करता है.

Resumo:

RESUMO:

Este estudo investiga como o comportamento e os incentivos dos CEOs mudam durante os anos finais do cargo de CEO, conhecido como o problema do horizonte.

Examinamos como o problema do horizonte altera a folga gerencial, uma medida de ineficiência operacional e desvio de valor gerencial. Usando dados sobre empresas chinesas de capital aberto entre 2003 e 2011, constatamos que a folga gerencial aumentou nos últimos dois anos de gestão do CEO em comparação com anos anteriores. Além disso, constatamos que o aumento da folga gerencial nos anos finais de gestão do CEO é menor em empresas de controle privado do que em empresas estatais, menor em empresas com participação acionária do CEO e com conselhos independentes em comparação com aqueles que não possuem. Concluímos que mecanismos de governança corporativa de melhor qualidade diminuem os incentivos perversos associados ao problema do horizonte de CEO e reduzem a tendência dos CEOs de aumentar a folga gerencial durante seus últimos anos no cargo. Nossa conclusão indica que mecanismos de governança corporativa de melhor qualidade diminuem os incentivos perversos associados ao problema do horizonte do CEO e reduzem a tendência dos CEOs de aumentar a folga gerencial durante seus últimos anos no cargo.

Аннотация:

АННОТАЦИЯ:

В данной работе исследуется, каким образом поведение и мотивы генерального директора меняются в течение последних лет его работы, – явление, известное как проблема горизонта. Мы изучаем, как проблема горизонта влияет на управленческую слабость, т.е. меру оперативной неэффективности и снижения управленческой пользы. На основании данных из китайских публичных компаний в период с 2003 по 2011 годов, мы обнаруживаем, что управленческая слабость возрастает в последние два года работы на посту генерального директора по сравнению с предыдущими годами. Кроме того, мы устанавливаем, что увеличение управленческой слабости в последние годы работы на позиции генерального директора менее значительно в частных компаниях, чем на государственных предприятиях; а также в компаниях с долей собственности у генерального директора и с более независимыми советами директоров по сравнению с теми компаниями, где нет ни того, ни другого. Мы делаем вывод о том, что более качественные механизмы корпоративного управления смягчают нежелательные мотивы, связанные с проблемой горизонта у генерального директора, и уменьшают склонность руководителей к увеличению управленческой слабости в течение последних лет их работы.

КЛЮЧЕВЫЕ СЛОВА: сменяемость генеральных директоров, Китай, корпоративное управление, проблема горизонта, слабость

Resumen:

RESUMEN:

Este estudio investiga cómo cambian el comportamiento del CEO y los incentivos durante los últimos años del CEO en el cargo, conocido como el problema del horizonte. Examinamos cómo el problema el horizonte altera la holgazanería gerencial, una medida de ineficiencia operacional y desviación del valor gerencial. Utilizando datos de empresas chinas listadas en bolsa entre el 2003 y el 2011, encontramos que la holgazanería gerencial aumenta en los dos últimos años de la tenencia del cargo como CEO en comparación con los años anteriores. Además. Encontramos que el aumento en la holgazanería gerencial del CEO en los últimos años en el cargo es menor en empresas de capital privado que en empresas de propiedad del estado, en las empresas pequeñas en donde el CEO tiene capital accionario y en empresas con juntas más independientes en comparación con las que no lo tienen. Concluimos que los mecanismos de gobierno corporativo de mayor calidad mejoran los incentivos perversos asociados con el problema del horizonte del CEO, y reduce la tendencia del CEO a aumentar la holgazanería gerencial durante los últimos años en la posición.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The International Association for Chinese Management Research 2018 

INTRODUCTION

A fundamental conflict between managers and shareholders is that managers’ decision horizons are often shorter than shareholders’ investment horizons. Because managers overvalue immediate short-term outcomes and paybacks relative to long-term results, they tend to make more conservative strategic choices and underinvest in R&D, new technologies, durable assets, and projects with deferred payoffs (Martin, Wiseman, & Gomez-Mejia, Reference Martin, Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia2016; Matta & Beamish, Reference Matta and Beamish2008; Souder & Shaver, Reference Souder and Shaver2010). Such myopic decisions guided by managers’ personal intertemporal preferences, while being optimal from a managerial perspective, may turn out to be suboptimal for their organizations (Laverty, Reference Laverty1996; Miller, 2002). As a result, managerial short-termism gives rises to the agency problem when managers sacrifice long-term interests of shareholders to seek their own short-term private gains (Fama, Reference Fama1980; Jensen, Reference Jensen1986).

The problem of managerial short-termism may intensify when managers approach their retirement or are about to leave their organizations (i.e., job separations). Because managers’ decision horizon is constrained by their expected tenure within the organization, the ‘no tomorrow’ feature of the employment contract will incentivize managers to engage in opportunistic and myopic activities (Conyon & Florou, Reference Conyon and Florou2006; Dechow & Sloan, Reference Dechow and Sloan1991). Extant research has documented that departing executives tend to reduce R&D spending (Bebchuk & Stole, Reference Bebchuk and Stole1993; Gibbons & Murphy, Reference Gibbons and Murphy1992), decrease advertising and capital investment (Dechow & Sloan, Reference Dechow and Sloan1991), avoid risky strategies such as investing in radical innovation (Xu & Yan, Reference Xu and Yan2014) and conducting international acquisition (Matta & Beamish, Reference Matta and Beamish2008), or engage in unethical earnings management to boost short-term profits (Antia, Pantzalis, & Park, Reference Antia, Pantzalis and Park2010). These phenomena are often labeled as ‘the horizon problem’ (Hambrick & Mason, Reference Hambrick and Mason1984).

Most research on the horizon problem is built on the premise of asymmetric and incomplete information between corporate managers and external stakeholders (Fama, Reference Fama1980). Because the managerial labor market rewards executives based on their abilities assessed through near-term firm performance, managers have incentives to select projects with high near-term returns, cut down expenditure, or use accounting accruals to artificially boost short-term earnings so as to improve the labor market evaluation of their value and to increase their personal payoffs in their current positions as well as subsequent job opportunities after turnover or retirement (Brickley, Linck, & Coles, Reference Brickley, Linck and Coles1999; Narayanan, Reference Narayanan1987). Departing managers may also obtain private benefits by shirking their duties or directly diverting firm resources for personal gain (Bebchuk & Jolls, Reference Bebchuk and Jolls1999). Lott (Reference Lott1990), for example, documents that politicians who are about to leave office are associated with worse attendance rates and increased shirking. Managerial shirking and value diversion, however, are rarely examined in the extant literature. The primary reason is that managers cannot easily engage in blatant shirking or apparent self-dealing without being penalized in most advanced economies with sophisticated corporate governance mechanisms. The presence of the ‘ex post settling-up’ logic in the executive labor market indicates that the market will eventually recognize and penalize managerial shirking and wrongdoings, and thus lessens managers’ incentives to engage in such behaviors (Fama, Reference Fama1980).

However, the efficient market premise may not always prevail, particularly in an emerging economy with institutional voids. Many firms in emerging countries do not have effective internal and external corporate governance systems in place to successfully detect, penalize, and subsequently discourage managerial shirking and value diversion. In addition, the managerial labor market in these countries often is incapable of properly accessing and rewarding executives based on their performance (He, Shaw, & Fang, Reference He, Shaw and Fang2017). In these circumstances, managerial shirking and value diversion may be prevalent if the departing manager's short-term gains from shirking or self-dealing considerably outweigh long-term penalties imposed by the managerial labor market (Cai, Fang, & Xu, Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011). This type of managerial opportunism may impose an even larger loss for shareholders than the situation examined in prior literature when managers trade off long-term benefits for short-term gains, since shareholders do not even benefit in the short-run, let alone long-term, in this case. The main objective of our article, therefore, is to explicitly investigate whether the horizon problem will result in accentuated managerial shirking and value diversion in an emerging economy context, an important research question yet to be addressed by existing literature. We argue that short-term orientation triggered by the horizon effect when the CEO approaches job separation may cause the CEO to shirk or to divert more firm resources due to the lack of long-term accountability and effective monitoring, which in turn escalates operational inefficiency and the level of managerial slack (Williamson, Reference Williamson1991). Our article thus significantly extends the scope of prior literature on the horizon problem that has largely focused on performance outcomes to study a novel and important process variable, namely operational efficiency as reflected by the level of managerial slack.

In this article, managerial slack is defined as a reflection of wasteful corporate practices including excess expenditure, lax management, and overinvestment (Jensen, Reference Jensen1986, Reference Jensen1993). Managerial slack promotes personal utility of managers at the expense of shareholders, thus it is an indicator of organizational inefficiency and a deviation from profit maximization (Williamson, Reference Williamson1964, Reference Williamson1991). Although popular in the economics and finance literature, this concept stands in sharp contrast with the view of management scholars who typically consider slack as excess resources for organizational changes (Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963; March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958). From this viewpoint, organizations with abundant slack are more likely to support resource consuming activities such as innovation and new strategic initiatives, while those with little slack are substantially restricted in terms of flexibility and the range of available options (Cheng & Kesner, Reference Cheng and Kesner1997; Singh, Reference Singh1986). Generally speaking, both camps agree that slack is an excess resource that can be spent at the discretion of management, but they disagree about whether or not slack resources will be expended wisely to enhance firm value or abused by managers to increase their private benefits. To reconcile these two contrasting perspectives, and to isolate operational inefficiency and managerial private benefits from legitimate and value-enhancing expenditure in slack, we also make an important methodological contribution to the literature by utilizing a statistical residual method to identify managerial slack as deviations from the optimal slack level that is constructed based on economic fundamentals. We examine two fundamental research questions: First, is there a spike in managerial slack right before the CEO departure? Second, is the horizon effect manifested through managerial slack mitigated by more robust corporate governance arrangements?

Our research is conducted in China, an important transition economy. In spite of the rapid development of China's equity market and its pivotal role in world economy, investor protection is still significantly weaker in China compared to more advanced economies (Shen, Zhou, & Lau, Reference Shen, Zhou and Lau2016). Compared to their western counterparts, Chinese executives have considerably more latitude to engage in excessive consumption of firm resources for their private interests that they would not be able to have if shareholders were powerful or institutions were better designed to prevent managerial opportunism (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Gul, Cheng, & Leung, Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011). This specific institutional context and its effect on managerial motivation and decision-making thus provide us a unique opportunity to unearth consequences of the horizon effect on managerial slack.

Davis (Reference Davis2005) suggests that the most relevant and promising corporate governance research should seek to understand the institutional context in which it occurs. This is particularly viable for firms having to comply with a constantly changing institutional environment in transitional economies (Peng, Reference Peng2003; Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson, & Peng, Reference Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson and Peng2005). We thereby employ an institution-based contingency framework to examine how context-specific situational factors may affect managerial motivations and choices, and subsequently influence the magnitude of the horizon problem and its impact on managerial slack during institutional transition. Our study considers diverse ownership structures of Chinese listed firms that affect the degree of shareholder protection (Shleifer & Vishny, Reference Shleifer and Vishny1997). We also incorporate major corporate governance reforms in executive compensation design and board structure occurring in our sample period. The utilization of these contingencies enables our study to provide a more comprehensive theoretical explanation and empirical examination of the horizon problem during institutional transition, thus extends beyond prior studies that have relied on data of developed economies with more efficient market infrastructures, more mature managerial labor markets, and more stable and sophisticated corporate governance systems (e.g., Barker & Mueller, Reference Barker and Mueller2002; Matejka, Merchant, & Stede, Reference Matejka, Merchant and Stede2009; McClelland, Barker III, & Oh, Reference McClelland, Barker and Oh2012).

HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT AND INSTITUTIONAL BACKGROUND

Managerial Slack and the Horizon Problem

Williamson's (Reference Williamson1964) theoretical model defines managerial slack as excess costs, staff, and compensation consumed by management at their own discretion. Specifically, managers may increase their personal utility by adding extra organizational staff, by consuming non-essential perquisites such as lavishly furnished offices, luxurious cars, private jets, or large expense accounts, and by making discretionary investments on pet projects, as well as by shirking on their jobs (Jensen, Reference Jensen1986, Reference Jensen1993). From this perspective, excess managerial slack becomes an agency problem, since it contributes to managerial utility at the cost of shareholder value. The potential misappropriation of firm resources for individual usage is particularly severe in China given its weak institutional environment and nascent financial reporting systems to protect shareholder interests (Shen et al., Reference Shen, Zhou and Lau2016; Su, Xu, & Phan, Reference Su, Xu and Phan2008). Cai et al. (Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011), for example, observe that Chinese executives have a lot of ‘grease money’ at their discretion to serve their private interests. In particular, publicly traded Chinese firms are not required to disclose detailed selling and general administrative expenses (SG&A) as they are in more advanced economies. Items such as business travel expenses, business entertainment expenses, business supply expenses, and company vehicle expenses thus can all be disguised in an aggregated number (Gul et al., Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011). Even for firms that have chosen to voluntarily report spending on these categories, the disclosure is often in a lump-sum format, which makes it extremely difficult for corporate boards and internal and external auditors to distinguish between legitimate business expenses and managerial excess. In addition, although all business expenses require receipts for reimbursement, accounting practices in China are rather inexact and managers may be reimbursed for almost any kind of entertainment and travel expenditure for any purpose, sometimes even with fake or inflated receipts (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011). Such practices create significant information asymmetries between managers and shareholders, thus pose a major challenge for shareholders to protect their interests from managerial opportunism (Luo, Zhang, & Zhu, Reference Luo, Zhang and Zhu2011).

The use of slack to divert firm resources to serve personal benefits may become more severe during executives’ final years in office. Because managers’ decision horizons are shorter than those of shareholders, managers tend to pursue short-term gains that serve their own interests at the expense of long-term benefits that are optimal for shareholders (Laverty, Reference Laverty1996). Such a temporal myopia problem is intensified when managers are about to leave the firm. When the managers’ control of firm resources is coming to an end with the termination of their employment contracts, their incentives to promote shareholder value also diminish (Dechow & Sloan, Reference Dechow and Sloan1991). In essence, because managers care less about the consequences of their decisions on firm value after their departure, they have a larger tendency to engage in opportunistic self-dealing activities to achieve short-term gains at the expense of shareholders (Casamatta & Guemel, Reference Casamatta and Guembel2010).

Previous empirical studies show that departing executives often make decisions that are not in the best interest of shareholders, including making investments that boost current earnings at the expense of future earnings (Murphy & Zimmerman, Reference Murphy and Zimmerman1993), reducing beneficial long-term R&D spending (Bebchuk & Stole, Reference Bebchuk and Stole1993), cutting down valuable advertising and capital expenses (Dechow & Sloan, Reference Dechow and Sloan1991), engaging in earnings management to increase short-term profits (Antia et al., Reference Antia, Pantzalis and Park2010; Huson, Tian, Wiedman, & Wier, Reference Huson, Tian, Wiedman and Wier2012), or refraining from beneficial international acquisitions or other investments (Matta & Beamish, Reference Matta and Beamish2008). Since the horizon problem may intensify and accentuate self-serving behavior of the departing executive, we argue that it will lead to a spike in managerial slack in a CEOs’ final years in office either as a result of excess consumption of firm resources or lack of effective control due to job shirking. This gives rise to the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1: Managerial slack will be higher in the CEO's final years in office compared to earlier years.

Corporate Governance and Managerial Slack

Slack may not always be detrimental to firm value. As March and Simon (Reference March and Simon1958: 187) explicitly note, ‘when an organization has slack money or manpower not committed to ongoing programs, various specializations of function may arise with respect to commitment to new programs and program elaboration’. The thrust of this argument is that innovation and corporate change require and consume resources. Organizations with abundant slack are thus more likely to support these activities, while those without it could not afford to do so (Cheng & Kesner, Reference Cheng and Kesner1997; Singh, Reference Singh1986). This viewpoint emphasizes the performance enhancing role of slack and presumes that managers are intrinsically motivated to care about shareholder interests. From the perspective of agency theory, whether self-interested managers will deploy slack wisely to maximize shareholder value or misappropriate it to withdraw private benefits is dependent on the presence of corporate governance mechanisms to monitor managerial activities and to constrain their opportunism (Jensen, Reference Jensen1993). We then proceed to discuss whether corporate governance mechanisms will mitigate the impact of the horizon effect on managerial slack.

A unique characteristic of the Chinese stock market is that a significant proportion of listed firms are State Owned Enterprises (SOEs), in which the State still retains sufficient shares and control (Delios, Wu, & Zhou, Reference Delios, Wu and Zhou2006; Haveman & Wang, Reference Haveman and Wang2013). This characteristic can be traced back to the original intent of the Chinese public exchange markets, which were established in the early 1990s as a vehicle to help SOEs raise much-needed financial capital. Consequently, the Chinese capital market demonstrates a significant bias in favour of SOEs over non-SOEs for a long period of time (Ding, Zhang, & Zhang, Reference Ding, Zhang and Zhang2007). Although SOEs are nominally owned by citizens of the country, they are actually controlled by politicians or by managers appointed by politicians through political processes. These politician managers typically have very low incentives and limited capabilities to monitor their firms because their personal interests and career reputation are far less linked to firm performance compared to their private counterparts (Chang & Wong, Reference Chang and Wong2009; Li, Xia, Long, & Tan, Reference Li, Xia, Long and Tan2012). In addition, maximizing shareholder value may not be the ultimate goal of SOEs who often pursue other social and political objectives such as providing employment and maintaining social stability (Stan, Peng, & Bruton, Reference Stan, Peng and Bruton2014). Consequently, the extant Chinese corporate governance literature has argued that state ownership weakens investor protection, and SOEs possess lower corporate governance quality and severer agency conflicts than their privately controlled counterparts. For example, compared to privately controlled firms, Chinese SOEs are associated with a smaller CEO pay-for-performance sensitivity (Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2011; Firth, Fung, & Rui, Reference Firth, Fung and Rui2006), a smaller and often insignificant relationship between CEO turnover and firm performance (Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2012; Kato & Long, Reference Kato and Long2006; Shen & Lin, Reference Shen and Lin2009), and are less likely to penalize executives for corporate fraud either in terms of dismissal or compensation reduction (Chen, Cumming, Hou, & Lee, Reference Chen, Cumming, Hou and Lee2016; Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2016). Because the executive labor market is less sensitive to firm performance and managerial misconduct when evaluating SOE managers, SOE managers’ future career opportunities and other long-term payoffs are less likely to be affected by these factors, which exaggerates their short-term orientation. As a result, we expect that the CEO horizon problem will be more serious in SOEs.

Pertinent to organizational slack, Stan et al. (Reference Stan, Peng and Bruton2014) contend that SOEs are far less efficient in utilizing firm resources than privately controlled firms. This is first due to the fact that SOEs are often sheltered from the market as a result of soft budget constraints, i.e., they will typically be bailed out by the government with subsidies, additional bank loans, and other financial support in the event of financial distress instead of going bankrupt or being taken over (Kornari, Maskin, & Roland, Reference Kornai, Maskin and Roland2003). SOEs may also enjoy specific protection in certain industries where government regulations set high entry barriers for potential entrants. Limited product-market competition in these industries thus provides low incentives for SOE managers to improve operational efficiency (Hermalin, Reference Hermalin1992; Scharfstein, Reference Scharfstein1988). In other words, the lack of market for corporate control mechanisms to discipline SOE managers leads to larger abuse of organizational slack for these managers to obtain private benefit (Hart, Reference Hart1983; Stan et al., Reference Stan, Peng and Bruton2014). Finally, SOEs often possess worse internal control systems compared to privately controlled firms. As a result, they are unable to impose more stringent reimbursement policies to better discern and subsequently discourage illegitimate business expenditure, and to curtail unwarranted travel and entertainment expenses as well as other excessive consumption of firm resources (Feng, Li, & McVay, Reference Feng, Li and McVay2009). Taken together, we expect that SOEs are not only more vulnerable to the CEO horizon problem, departing SOE managers are also more likely to exploit managerial slack to obtain personal gains compared to their private counterparts. We thereby make the following prediction:

Hypothesis 2: The increase of managerial slack in the CEO's final years in office will be larger in SOEs compared to those in non-SOEs.

Agency theory suggests that managerial equity ownership is an important mechanism to align managerial interests with those of shareholders and to ameliorate agency problems (Jensen & Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1976; Jensen & Murphy, Reference Jensen and Murphy1990). CEOs with a high equity stake in their companies have strong incentives to operate efficiently and to promote activities that increase firm value, precisely because this increases the value of their own share-based investments (Jensen & Warner, Reference Jensen and Warner1988). In contrast, CEOs with small or no equity ownership are much less motivated to diligently perform their tasks and also bear little cost when diverting firm resources, since a reduction in firm value only has a minor impact on their personal wealth. CEO equity ownership has been traditionally low in Chinese listed firms, but has experienced a noticeable increase in recent years. For instance, Conyon and He (Reference Conyon and He2012) document that only about one-fifth of public company CEOs owned shares of their firms in 2005, and this figure has gradually risen to about 30% in 2010. Such an increase is mainly due to two reasons. On the one hand, considerably more privately controlled companies are now listed in the Chinese stock market. Many founders who own a significant proportion of their firms still serve as CEOs (Cai, Luo, & Wan, Reference Cai, Luo and Wan2012). On the other hand, the grant of equity incentives including stock options and restricted stocks becomes permissible in 2006 for both SOEs and non-SOEs (Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2012). As a result, an increasing number of Chinese listed firms started to offer their executives equity incentives in an attempt to better align these managers’ personal wealth with those of shareholders.

The extant literature has demonstrated that managerial equity ownership is an important mechanism to mitigate the horizon problem. An early study by Dechow and Sloan (Reference Dechow and Sloan1991) shows that the linkage between CEO wealth and firm value established through CEO equity ownership serves as an alternative mechanism to align managerial interests with those of shareholders as career concerns diminish. Gibbons and Murphy (Reference Gibbons and Murphy1992) draw the same conclusion that stock-based incentives help better link managerial wealth with long-term, instead of short-term, firm outcomes. Recent studies in the management field likewise indicate that CEO equity incentives are effective in mitigating executives’ temporal myopia to encourage a long-term orientation (Martin et al., Reference Martin, Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia2016; Matta & Beamish, Reference Matta and Beamish2008). By the same token, we expect that CEO equity ownership links CEOs’ personal interests with their firms’ long-term outcomes and thus reduces CEOs’ tendency to abuse managerial slack before turnover and consequently alleviates the horizon problem. This leads to the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3: The increase of managerial slack in the CEO's final years in office will be smaller in firms with CEO equity ownership compared to those without.

Apart from equity ownership, the board of directors plays an essential role in protecting and promoting shareholder interests. Specifically, a board of directors has fiduciary duties to safeguard shareholder interests and to control managerial opportunism by engaging in key organization decisions such as hiring, evaluating, compensating, and firing top management (Hermalin & Weisbach, Reference Hermalin and Weisbach1988). Board capability to effectively monitor and discipline top management is affected by board composition (Finkelstein, Hambrick, & Cannella, Reference Finkelstein, Hambrick and Cannella2009). In particular, a board independent from CEO influences tends to possess higher monitoring quality. There is evidence that an independent board is more likely to discipline CEOs for poor firm performance and link CEO compensation to firm performance in both the western context (e.g., Boyd, Reference Boyd1994; Dalton, Daily, Ellstrand, & Johnson, Reference Dalton, Daily, Ellstrand and Johnson1998; Krause & Semadeni, Reference Krause and Semadeni2014; Weisbach, Reference Weisbach1988) and the Chinese context (e.g., Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2011, Reference Conyon and He2012; Firth et al., Reference Firth, Fung and Rui2006; Shen & Lin, Reference Shen and Lin2009). Pertinent to managerial slack, Chen, Lu, and Sougiannis (Reference Chen, Lu and Sougiannis2012) show that US firms with better corporate governance quality, including those with more independent boards, are associated with a smaller degree of managerial diversion measured by asymmetric SG&A costs. Importantly, board independence also helps alleviate the CEO horizon problem. Conyon and Florou (Reference Conyon and Florou2006), for example, find that firms with more independent boards are associated with larger capital expenditures in years leading to CEO retirement compared to firms with less independent boards.

The independent director system was introduced to Chinese listed firms in 2001 with the enactment of Guidelines of Establishing the Independent Director System in Listed Companies by the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC). According to this guideline, all Chinese listed firms have to ensure that their boards comprise at least one-third of independent directors by June 30, 2003. This requirement was then restated in the Code of Corporate Governance issued by CSRC in 2002. Chinese listed firms have subsequently introduced more independent directors to their boards to comply with such requirements (Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2011). Firth, Wong, and Xin (Reference Firth, Wong and Xin2016) show that the director labor market is effective in China and independent directors do play their monitoring roles. Specifically, they document that independent directors are more likely to leave high-risk fraud-prone firms to avoid regulatory sanctions and to preserve their social status and reputation in the director labor market. We therefore predict that firms with more independent boards are more likely to carry out vigilant monitoring to constrain CEO opportunism, which we argue will lessen the increase of managerial slack induced by the horizon problem. Consequently, we predict that:

Hypothesis 4: The increase of managerial slack in the CEO's final years in office will be smaller in firms with an independent board compared to those without.

DATA AND METHODS

Data and Sample Selection

Data on managerial slack, board and ownership structure, CEO turnover, CEO compensation, as well as financial and market information, are obtained from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research database (CSMAR) provided by GuoTaiAn Information Service (GTA). The CSMAR data cover all firms listed in Chinese Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges and have been widely used in previous Chinese corporate governance studies.

We first identify CEO turnover between 2003 and 2011, which is the event whenever the general manager or the chairperson of the board leaves the position and the firm.[Footnote 1] Within firms experiencing CEO turnovers, we pinpoint the last fiscal year the CEO maintains control of a firm following Huson et al. (Reference Huson, Tian, Wiedman and Wier2012). Specifically, if a CEO exit (i.e., transition out of the firm) happens before June 30 of the year, we code the year before exit as the final year ‘t’. If the exit happens after June 30 of the year, we code the exit year as ‘t’. We next code years before the exit year as ‘t-1’, ‘t-2’, and ‘t-3’, respectively. We require each firm to have four years’ data, including two years immediately prior to turnover (t, t-1) and two non-final years (t-2, t-3). We then label the CEO's final years using a dummy variable ‘Final Years’, which is set to one for year t and year t-1 and zero for years t-2 and t-3. Our full sample, for which we have complete information on all firm level independent and control variables, consists of 1,278 firms experiencing CEO turnovers with a total of 5,758 firm year observations.

Measures of Managerial Slack

We measure managerial slack using residuals from a regression model that determines the expected (or normal) level of general administrative (G&A) expenses. Under the Chinese Accounting Standards, G&A is reported in a firm's income statement, which includes all expenses related to headquarter activities except for selling expenses and financial expenses. We first follow Luo et al. (Reference Luo, Zhang and Zhu2011)’s measurement of managerial perks to exclude less discretional items including bad debt expenses, unrealized holding gain or loss for inventory, the amortization of intangible assets, and compensation of administrative staff including those of top executives, from this aggregate G&A measure. The remaining items capture expenses related to office supplies, traveling, vehicle usage, communication, insurance, benefit allowance, training, board-related activities, as well as other incidental spending such as consulting fees and litigation fees. All these expenditures are controlled by CEOs and could be deployed at their discretion. The logarithm of the remaining G&A expenditure is denoted as ‘Log (G&A)’ to apply in our baseline model.

The next step is to calculate managerial slack as the deviation from the normal level of G&A expenditure. We expect that the optimal level of slack (or G&A expenditure) is influenced by firm characteristics such as firm size, the scale of tangible assets, employment intensity, asset intensity, R&D intensity, advertising intensity, firm performance, firm growth potential, cross-listing status, as well as regional, industry, and macroeconomic factors (Anderson, Banker, Huang, & Janakiraman, Reference Anderson, Banker, Huang and Janakiraman2007; Banker, Huang, & Natarajan, Reference Banker, Huang and Natarajan2011). Subsequently, we define our baseline model as follows:

(1) $$\begin{equation} \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} Log{\left( {G\& A} \right)_{i,t}} = \alpha + {\beta _1}Log{\left( {Sales} \right)_{i,t}} + {\beta _2}PP{E_{i,t}}/Asse{t_{i,t}} + {\beta _3}Emp\_Intensit{y_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\beta _4}Asset\_Intensit{y_{i,t}} + {\beta _5}R\& D\_Intensit{y_{i,t}} + {\beta _6}Adv\_Intensit{y_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\beta _7}Sales\_Growt{h_{i,t}} + {\beta _8}Sales\_Decreas{e_{i,t}} + {\beta _9}Retur{n_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\beta _{10}}Cross - listin{g_{i,t}} + {\beta _{11}}Develope{d_{i,t}} + \Sigma Industry + \Sigma Year + \varepsilon \end{array} \end{equation}$$

Here the subscripts ‘i’ and ‘t’ indicate firm and year, respectively. Log (Sales) is firm size measured as the logarithm of total sales. PPE/Asset indicates tangible asset intensity calculated as property, plant, and equipment costs divided by total assets. Emp_Intensity measures employment intensity calculated by dividing the number of employees to total sales. Asset_Intensity is calculated as the assets to sales ratio. R&D_Intensity is calculated as the annual R&D expenditure divided by total sales. Similarly, Adv_Intensity is calculated as annual advertising expenditure divided by total sales. Sales_Growth is the annual sales growth ratio, and Sales_Decrease is a dummy variable indicating whether the firm experiences a sales decline. Return is the annualized stock returns indicating the firm's market performance. Cross_listing is a dummy variable that is equal to one if the firm is cross-listed on the Hong Kong stock exchange or other overseas stock exchanges and zero otherwise, which is used to control for the influence of different regulatory regimes (Ferris, Kim, & Noronha, Reference Ferris, Kim and Noronha2009). Developed is a dummy variable that measures whether the firm's headquarters is located in a developed region or not.[Footnote 2] This measure captures regional difference in regulatory environment and market infrastructure in China. We also control for the industry influence by including a series of industry dummy variables constructed using CSIC industry classification codes. Finally, we include a set of year dummy variable to control for changes in regulatory environment and macroeconomic conditions that may also affect the optimal slack level. To make the best prediction about the expected reasonable level of slack, we estimate β coefficients in Equation 1 by utilizing financial information of all listed firms between 2001 and 2011 instead of restricting to our turnover sample. Our estimation results are reported in Appendix I.

Residuals obtained from this regression are abnormal G&A expenditure calculated as differences between actual G&A expense and predicted G&A expense, which are used to construct our main measure of ‘Managerial Slack’. Such a residual method has the following key advantages over other methods applied in previous literature. First, G&A or SG&A expenditure scaled by assets or sales has been utilized in prior literature to measure absorbed slack, i.e., resources that have been absorbed by the organization but may be redeployed and recovered through increased efficiencies (e.g., Ju & Zhao, Reference Ju and Zhao2009; Singh, Reference Singh1986). However, a size scaled G&A expenditure is insufficient to isolate organizational inefficiency and managerial diversion from legitimate performance-enhancing functions of G&A expenditure, since many other factors that we identified above also affect the optimal level of G&A expenditure. Second, total G&A expenditure is applied to measure the magnitude of executive perks in China, a construct similar to our definition of managerial slack (Adithipyangkul, Alon, & Zhang, Reference Adithipyangkul, Alon and Zhang2011). This aggregate method is still unable to distinguish between the legitimate and illegitimate components of perks embedded in total G&A expenditure. Third, some studies use voluntarily disclosed itemized expenditure to measure executive perks (Chen, Li, & Liang, Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016; Gul et al., Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011).[Footnote 3] However, using voluntarily disclosed data significantly reduces the available sample size. For example, Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016) estimate that less than 50% of listed Chinese firms in their sample chose to disclose perk-related expenses. In addition, these disclosed items still mix normal business expenditure with managerial slack. For example, business travel expenses might be completely legitimate and wisely used by managers to build relationships with suppliers and buyers, while it might also be abused by managers to enjoy private benefits. Finally, the sample quality may be contaminated due to self-selection bias. That is, only firms without excessive consumption of managerial slack would choose to disclose these items in detail, while firms with suspicious expenditure may refrain from reporting these details but opt to hide them in the aggregate G&A term. We therefore contend that our measure of managerial slack is better than methods used in previous studies to capture the underlying construct.

Within our sample period we note that the average total G&A expense is roughly 77.05 million RMB. After deducting predicted normal business expenses of 73.29 million RMB, average abnormal executive expenses, i.e., managerial slack, are as high as 3.75 million RMB, about seven times of average executive pay (0.5 million). This estimate is consistent with Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016)’s estimate of discretional managerial expenditure in China, which they defined as managerial perks. Using voluntarily disclosed expenditure data, they report that total managerial perks are roughly eight times of average executive compensation in their sample of Chinese listed firms.

Since the residual method we propose here might be sensitive to the choice of the underlying baseline model, we also use three alternative methods to capture the construct of managerial slack. First, we follow Luo et al. (Reference Luo, Zhang and Zhu2011) to create an asset scaled measure of G&A expense by substituting the ‘Log (G&A)’ measure in Equation 1 with ‘G&A/Asset’ in our baseline model and then use residuals from this new model to capture managerial slack. It is denoted as ‘Slack-Scaled by Asset’. Next, we follow the procedure proposed in Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Lu and Sougiannis2012) to capture abnormal selling, general, and administrative costs (SG&A) by replacing ‘Log (G&A)’ with log value of total SG&A costs excluding certain non-discretionary items. Residuals from this model are labeled as ‘Slack-SG&A’. Finally, we obtain a narrower measure of G&A expense using ‘other cash flows related to operating activities’ reported in the cash flow statement. This item typically includes management expenses related to business travel such as entertainment and vehicle usage (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011). We use the logarithm of this cash expense as the dependent variable in Equation 1 and obtain residuals on abnormal cash flow labeled as ‘Slack-Cash Expense’. Similar to our main measure of managerial slack, we use financial information for all listed firms between 2001 and 2011 to construct baseline models in these alternative measures. We argue that the combination of these different measures provides a more solid approach to fully appreciate whether there is excess managerial slack in CEO final years in office.

Independent and Control Variables

As we noted above, we use variable ‘Final Years’ to capture CEOs’ final years in office. It is equal to 1 if the year is one of the last two years prior to CEO turnover (year t, year t-1), and 0 if it is year t-2 or year t-3. Because a forced CEO turnover lack of an advance notice may reduce the opportunity for the CEO to shirk or to consume on-the-job private benefits, we also use a fine-grained turnover measure that excludes all forced turnover events to define CEO final years in office as a robustness check.[Footnote 4]SOE’ is a dummy variable indicating whether the firm is a state-owned enterprise. ‘CEO Share’ is a dummy variable measuring the presence of CEO equity ownership. ‘Indep. Board’ is a dummy variable capturing whether the board has more than one third of outside directors. We next create three sets of interaction variables by interacting SOE, CEO Share, and Independent Board with Final Years respectively to estimate moderating roles of these corporate governance variables.

Our model also consists of other control variables that may influence the magnitude of managerial slack and horizon problem (e.g., Finkelstein et al., Reference Finkelstein, Hambrick and Cannella2009; Shen & Lin, Reference Shen and Lin2009). First, Adithpyangkul et al. (Reference Adithipyangkul, Alon and Zhang2011) and Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016) suggest that managerial perks (or slack in our term) may substitute for insufficient cash compensation offered to Chinese managers. We thus explicitly include ‘Executive Pay’ as a control variable, which is measured as the logarithm value of the average compensation of the top three highest paid executives.[Footnote 5] We next control for other board and ownership characteristics. We measure ‘Board Size’ as the number of directors on the board. We create an indicator variable ‘Combine’ to measure whether the post of the CEO and the chairperson is combined. ‘Largest SH%’ represents the percentage ownership of the controlling shareholder. To control for the quality of external governance mechanism, we use a dummy variable ‘Auditor’ to indicate whether the firm hires a major auditor, i.e., one of the largest ten auditors in China ranked by assets (DeFond, Wong, & Li, Reference DeFond, Wong and Li2000). We also control for the following firm characteristics. ‘Log Assets’ is a measure of company size and complexity calculated as the logarithm value of total assets. Firm performance is measured using the return on assets ratio, denoted as ‘Return on assets’. We control for the influence of declining performance using a dummy variable denoted as ‘Performance decline’, which is equal to one if the current year ROA is smaller than the previous year's and zero otherwise. We measure ‘Sales growth’ using annual sales growth ratio, ‘Leverage’ using long-term liability divided by total assets, and ‘Free cash flow’ using net operating cash flow divided by total assets.

Statistical Methods

We estimate a standard panel data model containing firm-level fixed effects to test our hypotheses. The fixed-effects model is inherently a change model that investigates how changes in CEO final-year status may affect changes in managerial slack for a given firm. By testing within-sample instead of between-sample variations, the fixed-effect method enables us to mitigate endogeneity problems created by unobserved firm specific variables that might affect the linkage between CEO final years and managerial slack. Our model is specified below:

(2) $$\begin{equation} \begin{array}{@{}l@{}} Managerial{\rm{ }}Slac{k_{i,t}} = {\alpha _i} + {\beta _1}FinalYear{s_{i,t}} + {\beta _2}SO{E_{i,t}} + {\beta _3}CEOShar{e_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\beta _4}IndepBoar{d_{i,t}} + {\gamma _1}ExecPa{y_{i,t}} + {\gamma _2}BoardSiz{e_{i,t}} + {\gamma _3}Combin{e_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\gamma _4}LargestSH{\% _{i,t}} + {\gamma _5}Audito{r_{i,t}} + {\gamma _6}LogAsset{s_{i,t}} + + {\gamma _7}RO{A_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\gamma _8}PerfDeclin{e_{i,t}} + {\gamma _9}S alesGrowt{h_{i,t}} + {\gamma _{10}}Leverag{e_{i,t}}\\ \qquad +\, {\gamma _{11}}FreeCashFlo{w_{i,t}} + {\lambda _t} + {\varepsilon _{it}} \end{array} \end{equation}$$

Here ‘Managerial Slackit is the abnormal G&A expenses for firm ‘i’ at time ‘t’ calculated using residuals from Equation 1. The term ‘Final Years’ is an indicator variable coded as 1 if the CEO is in the final two years of office and zero otherwise. The coefficient β1 is expected to be positive, implying that managerial slack increases in the CEO's final years in office. The model also contains a set of firm level control variables as specified above. The term αi is a set of firm fixed effects controlling for unobserved non-time varying firm-specific factors that might influence managerial slack (Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2010). λt is a set of time dummy variables and εit is the error term.

RESULTS

Descriptive Statistics

Table 1 provides some basic descriptive statistics along with a correlation matrix for main variables used in our analysis. We find that an average firm has 9 board members and 83% of firms have at least one-third of independent directors on their boards. Approximately 11% of firms have a combined leadership position. An average CEO holds no shares in his/her firm. The largest shareholder on average owns 39% of the firm. The percentage of SOEs in our sample is 71%. We also find that 29% of sample firms hire a top-ten auditor. The average return on assets ratio is approximately 0.03, average sales growth rate is 0.16, and the average leverage ratio is 0.06. These patterns are broadly consistent with other corporate governance studies using Chinese data (e.g., Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2011, Reference Conyon and He2012; Firth et al., Reference Firth, Fung and Rui2006, Reference Firth, Fung and Rui2007; He & Fang, Reference He and Fang2016; Shen & Lin, Reference Shen and Lin2009). Importantly, we find that managerial slack is significantly higher during CEO final years in office. The unconditional data are thus consistent with our prediction in H1.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix

Note: *p < 0.05

Table 2a contrasts managerial slack in CEO final years with those in non-final years using all four slack measures specified above. We also report average executive compensation for comparison. Both mean and median values are reported along with t-statistics for equal means and z scores for the Wilcoxon rank sum test for equal medians. Table 2a indicates that managerial slack is significantly higher in CEO final years compared to non-final years across all four measures of managerial slack in terms of both mean and median values, with p value ranging from 0.00 to 0.02. This result is consistent with our prediction that the horizon problem prompts an increase in managerial slack right before CEO turnover compared to earlier years. Importantly, we notice that average executive compensation is also significantly higher in the CEO's final years in office. Therefore, there is no evidence that increased managerial slack before CEO turnover is used to offset insufficient cash compensation in this period.

Table 2a. Managerial slack in final years vs. non-final years

Notes: Both mean and median values are reported. t statistics from two tailed t-test for equal mean and Z values for Wilcoxon rank sum test for equal median are presented with respective significance level. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

To illustrate the role of corporate governance mechanisms in constraining the influence of the horizon problem on managerial slack, we split our samples based on three sets of corporate governance variables: SOEs vs. non-SOEs, firms with CEO equity ownership vs. those without, and firms with independent boards vs. those without. For each set of firms, we calculate mean values of their managerial slack during and before CEO final years in office. We present differences in managerial slack between these two periods as well as t-statistics for equal mean tests for each set of subsamples in Table 2b. We also report F values from two-factor ANOVA tests on our difference-in-difference results to test whether changes in managerial slack are significantly different within each set of governance variables. Table 2b suggests that SOEs experience a significant increase in managerial slack during CEO final years, with the slack level rising from 0.00 to 0.06 (p = 0.00). In contrast, no statistically significant increase in slack is identified for non-SOEs (p = 0.32). In addition, our difference-in-difference test suggests that the positive increase in managerial slack right before CEO turnover is significantly larger for SOEs than for non-SOEs (F = 27.77, p = 0.00), which confirms our prediction of H2 that the horizon problem is severer in SOEs than in non-SOEs. We also find that firms whose CEOs have no equity stakes experience significant increase of managerial slack during their final years in office (p = 0.00), while a statistically significant difference is not identified for the subgroup of firms with CEO equity ownership. The difference in the change of managerial slack between these two groups is statistically significant (F = 7.00, p = 0.00), thus supports H3 that CEO equity ownership lessens the impact of the horizon problem on managerial slack. Finally, Table 2b suggests that firms without independent boards undergo a significant surge of managerial slack right before CEO turnover, with slack increasing from −0.08 to 0.13 (p = 0.00), while such an increase is only marginally significant for firms with independent boards (p = 0.09). The difference-in-difference test between these two subgroups is also statistically significant (F = 6.50, p = 0.00), which is consistent with the prediction of H4 that board independence mitigates the influence of horizon problem on managerial slack. Overall, these analyses provide preliminary and important empirical support to all four hypotheses. That is, the horizon problem results in increased managerial slack in a CEO's final years in office, and such an increase is more salient in SOEs, firms without CEO equity ownership and firms without an independent board.

Table 2b. Managerial slack in final years vs. non-final years for different corporate governance mechanisms

Notes: Mean values are reported with standard errors in parenthesis. t statistics from two tailed t-test for equal mean and F statistics from ANOVA test are present. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01

Multivariate Analysis

Table 3 contains our main regression results to test H1, with column 1 reporting standard ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates and column 2 reporting firm-level fixed effects estimates, both based on the full turnover sample. Column 3 presents results from the confined voluntary turnover sample using the fixed-effect model. The VIF test for multi-collinearity indicates that the mean VIF for all variables is 2.49 when time dummy variables are included, and 1.22 when time dummy variables are excluded. VIF values range from 1.04 to 1.61 for all non-time dummy variables. Therefore, there is no severe multi-collinearity problem in our multivariate analyses.

Table 3. Managerial slack in CEOs’ final years in office

Notes: Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors in parenthesis. p value is calculated based on two-tailed t statistics. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

Table 3 indicates a statistically significant positive correlation between managerial slack and CEO final years, with p values in all models smaller than 0.01. This relationship is economically significant. Specifically, Table 3 suggests that managerial slack is approximately 3% (Column 3) to 4% (Columns 1 & 2) higher during the CEO's final two years in office compared to earlier years. This translates into about 2.3 million to 3.1 million RMB excessive expenditure calculated using the mean level of G&A expenses. The multivariate regression results therefore provide strong support to our H1 that the horizon problem leads to increased managerial slack during the CEO's final years in office.

Table 4 tests hypotheses 2 through 4 using the split-sample method to evaluate the moderating role of firm governance structures. We split the sample based on ownership structure (SOEs vs. non-SOEs) in columns 1 and 2 to test H2, on CEO equity ownership in columns 3 and 4 to investigate H3, and on board structure in columns 5 and 6 to test H4. We apply the firm-level fixed-effects panel data method in all models. Our goal is to see whether the association between managerial slack and CEO final years is significantly different within each pair of subsample splits.

Table 4. Managerial slack and corporate governance mechanisms: Split-sample tests

Notes: Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors in parenthesis. p value is calculated based on two-tailed t statistics.*p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

Table 4 indicates that the coefficient of ‘Final Years’ is 0.04 (p = 0.00) in the SOE subsample, which suggests that managerial slack will rise 4% in CEO final years in SOEs. In contrast, we observe no significant increase in slack in the non-SOE subsample. These results are consistent with the prediction of H2 that private ownership reduces the horizon problem. In addition, we find a positive and significant coefficient of 0.04 (p = 0.00) in the subsample of firms without CEO equity ownership, while we do not isolate a statistically significant coefficient in firms with CEO equity ownership. H3 is thus confirmed that the increase in managerial slack during CEOs’ final years is more salient in the absence of managerial equity ownership. Table 4 also suggests that firms with less independent boards are associated with significantly higher managerial slack in CEOs’ final years (β = 0.15, p = 0.00), which suggests that managerial slack in these firms will increase 15% right before CEO turnover. In sharp contrast, firms with more independent boards are associated with only a modest 2% increase in slack during the CEO's final years (p = 0.06). These results support H4 that board independence mitigates the CEO horizon effect. Overall, evidence present in Table 4 suggests that better quality corporate governance mechanisms help alleviate the impact of the horizon problem on managerial slack.

To further illustrate the moderating role of corporate governance structures, we next create interaction variables between ‘Final Years’ and all three corporate governance variables. Given there are very few within-sample variations in SOE status, CEO equity ownership and board independence, we apply the pooled OLS method instead of the firm-level fixed effects method to conduct our test. We report our results in Table 5. Column 1 tests the moderating role of SOE status, column 2 tests the role of CEO equity ownership, column 3 evaluates the role of board independence, and column 4 includes all three interaction variables simultaneously. First, we notice that the coefficients of ‘Final Years’ are significantly positive in all models, which again confirms H1 that managerial slack increases in CEO final years. In addition, we notice that the increase in managerial slack is even larger for SOEs as indicated by the significantly positive coefficient of the interaction variable of SOE and ‘Final Years’. Column 1 of Table 5 indicates that managerial slack increases 14% (0.08+0.06) when SOE CEOs approach turnover, compared to 8% for CEOs in non-SOEs. This difference is statistically significant at p = 0.05 level, thus supports the prediction of H2. Table 5 also suggests that firms with CEO equity ownership are associated with a lower level of managerial slack in CEO final years compared to firms without CEO equity ownership, although the difference is not statistically significant. Finally, table 5 indicates that firms with an independent board are associated with significantly smaller managerial slack in CEO final years. Column 3 indicates that although managerial slack increases 14% in final years of CEOs in firms without independent boards, firms with board independence are only associated with a milder 2% (0.14-0.12) increase in managerial slack. Generally speaking, our interaction models provide additional empirical supports for H1 on the presence of horizon problem and for H2 and H4 on the moderating roles of SOE and board independence.

Table 5. Managerial slack and corporate governance mechanisms: Interaction models

Notes: Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors in parenthesis. p value is calculated based on two-tailed t statistics. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS

Alternative Measures of Managerial Slack

We have shown in our main analyses that managerial slack increases during the CEO's final years in office and this relationship is further moderated by corporate governance designs. To evaluate whether our results are sensitive to alternative slack metrics, we re-estimate our main models using three alternative slack measures discussed earlier, namely (i) an asset scaled measure of abnormal G&A expenditure, (ii) abnormal SG&A expenses, and (iii) abnormal cash expense. For brevity we do not tabulate detailed results. Generally speaking, we find a clear and consistent picture that reinforces our main finding that there is a significant increase in managerial slack in CEO final years in office. For example, we find that managerial slack measured using the asset scaled method is significantly higher in CEO final years (β = 0.002, se. = 0.000, and p = 0.00). Similarly, slack measured as abnormal SG&A costs is also significantly higher in CEO final years (β = 0.03, se. = 0.01, and p = 0.00). Finally, a marginally significant coefficient is identified for slack measured using abnormal cash expense (β = 0.02, se. = 0.01, and p = 0.09). Our non-tabulated split-sample test results are also qualitatively consistent with empirical findings reported in Table 4, although significance levels of these results vary by measures. Taken as a whole, these additional tests confirm our main argument that managerial slack increases in Chinese CEOs’ final years in office as a result of the horizon problem, and higher quality corporate governance mechanisms help mitigate the horizon effect manifested in managerial slack.

Apart from the residual method, the extant literature has also used voluntarily disclosed itemized expenditure to capture executive perks, a construct closely related to managerial slack captured in this study. We argue above that our residual measure is superior to this alternative measure. To further validate the appropriateness of our estimate, we also collect these voluntarily disclosed expenditure items reported in the appendix of firm financial reports following procedures described in Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016) and Gul et al. (Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011). We define Perk_Chen as the logarithm of the summation of the eight itemized expenditures listed in Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016) and define Perk_Gul as the logarithm of the summation of the six itemized expenditures used by Gul et al. (Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011). Given only a small proportion of our sample firms have disclosed these itemized expenses, we apply our residual method explained in Equation (1) to calculate managerial slack for all listed firms during our sample period of 2001 to 2011 regardless of their managerial turnover status. There is a total of 13,818 firm year observations that we have non-missing information to calculate managerial slack using the residual method. Within these firm years, we only obtain 4,475 firm-year observations for Perk_Chen and 4,204 observations for Perk_Gul. That is, only 30.42% to 32.38% of firms have chosen to disclose detailed administrative expenditure, which validates our earlier claim that using voluntarily disclose information to measure managerial slack is subject to severe selection bias. We find that our measure of managerial slack is positively correlated with both Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016)’s and Gul et al. (Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011)’s measures. The Pearson correlation between our measure and the Chen measure is 0.34 and for the Gul measure is 0.32; both significant at the 0.01 level. Thus, although different, our measure of managerial slack is in agreement with these alternatives proposed in prior literature. We thus conclude that our measure does possess external validity.

Managerial Slack and Firm Performance

If an increase in managerial slack is a result of an optimal compensation design or valuable resources for innovation and change, we should expect a positive relationship between managerial slack and firm performance. That is, if managerial slack is beneficial to the firm, an increase in managerial slack should be associated with higher firm performance and an increase in shareholder wealth. Is this claim true? To evaluate this counter argument, we test the performance impact of managerial slack and report our results in Table 6. We estimate firm performance equations using both an accounting performance measure of the return on assets ratio denoted as ‘ROA’ and a stock performance measure of annualized stock returns denoted as ‘RET’. To prevent the problem of reverse causality and the possible mechanical relationship between our slack measure (abnormal G&A expenditure) and the current-term accounting performance measure, we lag all our independent variables by one year to test the influence of managerial slack on the next period firm performance. Columns 1 and 3 are based on the whole sample of all listed firms between 2001 and 2011; columns 2 and 4 report results from our CEO turnover sample applied in the main analysis. All estimates are conducted using the firm-level fixed effects regression method.

Table 6. Managerial slack and firm performance

Notes: Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors in parenthesis. p value is calculated based on two-tailed t statistics. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

Table 6 indicates a consistently significant negative relationship between managerial slack and firm performance measured using both ROA and stock market returns in both the whole sample and our CEO turnover sample. That is, larger managerial slack is associated with worse firm accounting performance and worse stock market returns as predicted by agency theory. These results testify our construct validity, i.e. managerial slack captured in our article reflects managerial excess that reduces value of Chinese listed firms.[Footnote 6]

DISCUSSION

Our research is motivated by Williamson (Reference Williamson1964)’s managerial discretion model that defines managerial slack as excess costs, compensation, and perks consumed by management at their own discretion to divert firm resources from other productive activities. We add a temporal dimension to the concept of managerial slack to investigate the impact of the horizon problem on managerial slack. We test whether there is a disproportional increase in managerial slack prior to CEO turnover. Using data on Chinese listed firms experiencing CEO turnovers between 2003 and 2011, we find consistent evidence that managerial slack is significantly higher during the CEO's final years in office. This empirical evidence is consistent with the predicted horizon effect, i.e., CEOs modify their behavior later in their careers to gain private benefits at the cost of shareholder interests. In addition, we find that the increase in managerial slack at the time of CEO departure is larger in SOEs, but smaller in firms with CEO equity ownership and independent boards. These results suggest that corporate governance mechanisms help alleviate the horizon problem manifested in managerial slack and improve operational efficiency. Our results are also robust to alternative measures of managerial slack and a refined measure of CEO turnover. Finally, our additional analysis documents a consistently negative relationship between managerial slack and firm performance and confirms that slack captured in our paper is indeed a reflection of managerial diversion and organizational inefficiency since it reduces instead of enhances firm value.

From a theoretical standpoint, our findings provide new insights to the CEO horizon problem. The extant literature on the horizon effect is rooted in the work of agency theory and behavioral models on myopic decision-making and risk aversion (Fama, Reference Fama1980; Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979). It also falls in the broadly defined economic short-termism (Laverty, Reference Laverty1996) and managerial temporal myopia (Miller, 2002). The short-term temporal horizon compels executives to operate with a short-run perspective, since they are unable to benefit much from long-term firm profitability. As a result, the horizon effect would nudge CEOs to reduce investment with long-term payoffs in an attempt to boost short-term earnings and to maximize their post-turnover or post-retirement incomes (Krause & Semadeni, Reference Krause and Semadeni2014; Matta & Beamish, 2010; McClelland, Liang, & Barker III, Reference McClelland, Liang and Barker2010; McClelland et al., Reference McClelland, Barker and Oh2012). We significantly augment this stream of studies to test a new process variable, namely operational efficiency manifested in the level of managerial slack. We argue that when the managerial labor market is less efficient in assessing and rewarding CEO performance, the horizon problem may result in increased operational inefficiency and accentuated managerial slack in the years near CEO exits instead of prompting CEOs to increase short-term performance at the cost of long-term benefits. More specifically, at presence of an embryonic corporate governance system and a relatively primitive executive labor market, the myopic focus induced by anticipated job separation may motivate departing CEOs to shirk their duties or to directly divert firm resource so as to maximize their short-term gains. This is because long-term penalties associated with such value-diminishing activities are limited and negligible. By testing the horizon effect in a major emerging market, we determine and highlight an alternative consequence of the CEO horizon effect, mainly its impact on operational efficiency and managerial slack.

We also provide an important methodological contribution to the study of organizational slack. While it has long been realized that slack can have both positive and negative effects on firm performance, management studies to date have mainly focused on examining the performance impact of slack and identifying contingency factors that may affect the relationship between slack and firm performance (e.g., Ju & Zhao, Reference Ju and Zhao2009; McClelland et al., Reference McClelland, Barker and Oh2012; Peng, Li, Xie, & Su, Reference Peng, Li, Xie and Su2010; Singh, Reference Singh1986; Su, Xie, & Li, Reference Su, Xie and Li2009; Tan & Peng, Reference Tan and Peng2003). It has consequently been suggested that there is an optimal level of slack and the relationship between slack and firm performance is curvilinear with the negative effect starting to dominate when slack exceeds certain amounts or when organizational characteristics are not favorable for efficient deployment of slack resource. We tackle the double-edged role of slack by measuring managerial slack as excess general administrative expenses expressed as a deviation from the predicted optimal level of slack. Effectively, we introduce to the managerial slack literature a new technique (i.e., residual analysis) to isolate managerial private benefits from the aggregate slack measure adopted in prior studies. The promulgation of this residual method thus enables us to explicitly separate the positive component of slack owing to legitimate investment and diligent deployment of firm resources from the negative element that likely reflects organizational inefficiency and managerial diversion of productive assets.

The findings of our study also have practical implications. First, our study points to the significance of situational and structural factors in affecting the magnitude of horizon problem and managerial slack. For example, our study highlights the importance of executive equity incentives as a potential alignment tool to alleviate the horizon problem at the later stage of managerial careers. Our study also indicates that enhanced board independence is effective in mitigating the negative impact of CEO horizon problem on managerial slack. This is reassuring for advocates of ‘best-practice’ corporate governance methods, since regulatory changes that improve corporate governance quality appear to have a positive impact on shareholder value. We argued earlier that the problem of managerial slack is particularly severe in China given its relatively weak financial disclosure system that creates substantial information asymmetry between management and shareholders. Recent studies in the US have indicated that enhanced disclosure rules imposed by Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) in 2006 lead to disclosures of significantly larger amounts of perquisites and a substantial reduction in these discretionary expenses afterwards (Grinstein, Weinbaum, & Yehuda, Reference Grinstein, Weinbaum and Yehuda2017). We thereby suggest that imposing more extensive financial disclosure rules might be a reasonable policy direction to better constrain managerial value diversion and improve operational efficiency.

Our article also suggests several future directions for research. First, Meyer (Reference Meyer2015) suggests that it is essential to incorporate national contexts in management research to set boundary conditions for a theoretical model. A natural extension to our study is to investigate similar research topics in other countries, cultures, and contexts to probe whether managerial slack is also affected by the impending departure of key executives, or to conduct a cross-country comparative study to examine contingency factors affecting the magnitude of such impacts. Second, we have probed the importance of internal corporate governance mechanisms as a means to ameliorate the influence of horizon problem on managerial slack. Future research might focus on the efficacy of external governance mechanisms and the overall governance environment in controlling managerial opportunism and temporal myopia. Finally, our article has suggested that managerial time horizon has a significant impact on their decision-making outcomes in terms of the level of managerial slack. Future studies may benefit from extending this stream of literature to further explore the role of time horizon and temporal orientation in affecting resource allocation, strategic choices, and other organizational outcomes (Reilly, Souder, & Ranucci, Reference Reilly, Souder and Ranucci2016).

CONCLUSION

Overall, our paper provides the first evidence on the existence of a horizon effect for Chinese CEOs during their final years in office as reflected in higher operational inefficiency and larger managerial slack. We also identify the moderating role of internal corporate governance mechanisms in curtailing the severity of the horizon problem. Although our study is conducted in the Chinese context, it will also have implications for other emerging economies with institutional voids. We hope that our findings could enhance understanding on managerial myopia and stimulate further research on the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms in mitigating executive short-termism and promoting shareholder value in China and beyond.

APPENDIX I

The Residual Model to Calculate Managerial Slack

Footnotes

We thank Alex Bryson, Jerry Cao, Peter Cappelli, Richard Freeman, Donald Hambrick, Jianqiao Hong, William Judge, Kenneth Kim, Clive Lennox, Yunguo Liu, Changjiang Lv, Gary Tian, Lixin Colin Xu, Hongqi Yuan, Zhifang Zhang, and seminar participants at the 2012 International Workshop on CEO Compensation, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, the 2012 Financial Young Scholar Round Table Seminar, the 2014 Academy of Management Annual Meeting, and the 2015 Inaugural International Corporate Governance Society Annual Conference for comments on earlier versions of this paper. We would also like to thank Senior Editor Dr. Xiaowei Luo and two anonymous reviewers for their insights. This research was supported by three grants from National Natural Science Foundation of China: ‘Government Control, Marketization and the Efficiency of Top Management Compensation Contract in China’ (71072003), ‘Institutional Environment, Corporate Governance and CEO Governance’ (71372119), and ‘Information Disclosure and Market Competition under Informaton Asymmetry: Theory, Evidence and Policy’ (71673048). Financial support from the 4th Fujian 100 Innovation & Entrepreneurship Grant (He) and Center for Human Resources at the Wharton School (Conyon) are also gratefully acknowledged.

[1] The use of the job title, Chief Executive Officer, or CEO to identify the most senior firm executive is a relatively new phenomenon in China. Only recently are Chinese companies beginning to use this term. Historically, General Manager has been used to represent presidents of a company. In addition, the Chairman of the board of directors in China is the legal representative of the firm who works full time for the company, thus it is also a top executive position that ranks even above the general manager (Firth et al., Reference Firth, Fung and Rui2006). Previous Chinese corporate governance literature either used the general manager or the chairperson of the board, or a combination of these two positions to represent CEOs. In our study, we code CEO turnover as one whenever the general manager or the chairperson leaves the position and the firm, but not when the person relinquishes one post and remains another.

[2] This measure is constructed based on Fan, Wang, and Zhu (Reference Fan, Wang and Zhu2011)’s NERI index, which is an annual index created for each of the 31 Chinese provinces as well as four municipalities directly under control of the central administration. We code ‘Developed’ as one if the firm's headquarter is located in a region with above median NERI market development score.

[3] Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Li and Liang2016) identify eight items related to executive perks using voluntarily disclosed expenditure, including 1) office expenses, 2) business travel expenses, 3) business entertainment expenses, 4) communication expenses, 5) training expenses, 6) board meeting expenses, 7) company car expense, and 8) meeting expenses. Gul et al. (Reference Gul, Cheng and Leung2011) excluded office expenses and communication expenses from the above list and used the remaining six items to measure executive perk.

[4] We follow He and Fang (Reference He and Fang2016) to classify a turnover as a forced one if the turnover reason is dismissal, litigation, retirement before 60, personal reasons, or no reason given. It is classified as voluntary in all other cases. Data on such classifications are provided by CSMAR.

[5] Due to a more primitive compensation disclosure system, Chinese listed firms were not required to report individual executive compensation information before 2005, but only had to report the aggregate compensation of the top three highest paid executives. As a result, we use this average compensation number to conduct our analysis following some prior Chinese executive compensation studies (e.g., Firth et al., Reference Firth, Fung and Rui2006, Conyon & He, Reference Conyon and He2011). In our unreported tables, we also substitute this measure with abnormal executive compensation measured using the residual method by subtracting the predicted normal level of executive compensation from total executive compensation following He and Fang (Reference He and Fang2016)’s study. Our results from this alternative compensation measure are qualitatively consistent with those reported using the main measure.

[6] We also perform other additional analyses. To rule out reverse causality that excessive consumption of managerial slack may induce disciplinary actions from the firm and subsequently cause CEO turnover, we test the relationship between managerial slack and the likelihood of forced turnover by running a Probit regression of CEO forced turnover on all four measures of managerial slack specified above. Consistent with the extant CEO turnover literature, we do document a significant negative relationship between firm performance and the likelihood of forced executive turnover (e.g., Kato & Long, Reference Kato and Long2006; Shen & Lin, Reference Shen and Lin2009). We, however, do not find a significant positive linkage between our measures of managerial slack and the likelihood of forced CEO turnover. These findings again support our earlier claim that managerial slack in CEO final years could be attributed to the horizon problem. Detailed results are available on request.

Notes: Detailed Models are specified in Equation 1. Coefficients are reported along with robust standard errors and t statistics in parenthesis. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < .0.01.

Accepted by: Senior Editor Xiaowei Rose Luo

References

REFERENCES

Adithipyangkul, P., Alon, I., & Zhang, T. 2011. Executive perks: Compensation and corporate performance in China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 28 (2): 401425.Google Scholar
Anderson, M., Banker, R., Huang, R., & Janakiraman, S. 2007. Cost behavior and fundamental analysis of SG&A costs. Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance, 22 (1): 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antia, M., Pantzalis, C., & Park, J. C. 2010. CEO decision horizon and firm performance: An empirical investigation. Journal of Corporate Finance, 16 (3): 288301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banker, R., Huang, R., & Natarajan, R. 2011. Equity incentives and long-term value created by SG&A expenditure. Contemporary Accounting Research, 28 (3): 794830.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barker, V. L. III., & Mueller, G. 2002. CEO characteristics and firm R&D spending. Management Science, 48 (6): 782801.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bebchuk, L., & Jolls, C. 1999. Managerial value diversion and shareholder wealth. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15 (2): 487502.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L., & Stole, L. 1993. Do short-term objectives lead to under- or over-investment in long term projects. Journal of Finance, 48 (2): 719729.Google Scholar
Boyd, B. 1994. Board control and CEO compensation. Strategic Management Journal, 15 (5): 335344.Google Scholar
Brickley, J., Linck, J., & Coles, J. 1999. What happens to CEOs after they retire? New evidence on career concerns, horizon problems, and CEO incentives. Journal of Financial Economics, 52 (3): 341377.Google Scholar
Cai, D., Luo, J., & Wan, D. 2012. Family CEOs: Do they benefit firm performance in China? Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29 (4): 923947.Google Scholar
Cai, H., Fang, H., & Xu, L. 2011. Eat, drink, firms, government: An investigation of corruption from the entertainment and travel costs of Chinese firms. Journal of Law and Economics, 54 (1): 5578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casamatta, C., & Guembel, A. 2010. Managerial legacies, entrenchment, and strategic inertia. Journal of Finance, 65 (6): 24032436.Google Scholar
Chang, E., & Wong, S. 2009. Governance with multiple objectives: Evidence from top executive turnover in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 15 (2): 230244.Google Scholar
Chen, D., Li, O., & Liang, S. 2016. Perk consumption as a suboptimal outcome under pay regulations. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting and Economics, 23 (4): 373399.Google Scholar
Chen, J., Cumming, D., Hou, W., & Lee, E. 2016. CEO accountability for corporate fraud: Evidence from the split share structure reform in China. Journal of Business Ethics, 138 (4): 787806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, X., Lu, H., & Sougiannis, T. 2012.The agency problem, corporate governance, and the asymmetrical behavior of selling, general, and administrative costs. Contemporary Accounting Research, 29 (1): 252282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheng, J., & Kesner, I. 1997. Organizational slack and response to environmental shifts: The impact of resource allocation patterns. Journal of Management, 23 (1): 118.Google Scholar
Conyon, M., & Florou, A. 2006. The pattern of investment surrounding CEO retirements: UK evidence. British Accounting Review, 38 (3): 299319.Google Scholar
Conyon, M., & He, L. 2011. Executive compensation and corporate governance in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17 (4): 11581175.Google Scholar
Conyon, M., & He, L. 2012. CEO pay and corporate governance in China. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 20 (6): 575592.Google Scholar
Conyon, M., & He, L. 2016. Executive compensation and corporate fraud in China. Journal of Business Ethics, 134 (4): 669691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R., & March, J. 1963. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Dalton, D., Daily, C., Ellstrand, A., & Johnson, J. 1998. Meta-analytic reviews of board composition, leadership structure, and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 19 (3): 269290.Google Scholar
Davis, G. 2005. New directions in corporate governance. Annual Review of Sociology, 31 (1): 143162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechow, P., & Sloan, R. 1991. Executive incentives and the horizon problem: An empirical investigation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 14 (1): 5189.Google Scholar
DeFond, M. L., Wong, T. J., & Li, S. 2000. The impact of improved auditor independence on audit market concentration in China. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 28 (3): 269305.Google Scholar
Delios, A., Wu, Z. J., & Zhou, N. 2006. A new perspective on ownership identities in China's listed companies. Management and Organization Review, 2 (3): 319343.Google Scholar
Ding, Y., Zhang, H., & Zhang, J. 2007. Private vs. state ownership and earnings management: Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15 (2): 223238.Google Scholar
Fama, E. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88 (2): 288307.Google Scholar
Fan, G., Wang, X., & Zhu, H. 2011. NERI index of marketization of China's provinces: 2011 report. Beijing, Economic Science Press.Google Scholar
Feng, M., Li, C., & McVay, S. 2009. Internal control and management guidance. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48 (2–3): 190209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferris, S., Kim, K., & Noronha, G. 2009. The effect of crosslisting on corporate governance: A review of the international evidence. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17 (3): 338352.Google Scholar
Finkelstein, S., Hambrick, D. C., & Cannella, A. 2009. Strategic leadership: Theory and research on executives, top management teams, and boards. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Firth, M., Fung, P., & Rui, O. 2006. Firm performance, governance structure, and top management turnover in a transitional economy. Journal of Management Studies, 43 (6): 12891330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Firth, M., Fung, P., & Rui, O. 2007. How ownership and corporate governance influence chief executive pay in China's listed firms. Journal of Business Research, 60 (7): 776785.Google Scholar
Firth, M., Wong, S., & Xin, Q. 2016. Regulatory sanctions on independent directors and their consequences to the director labor market: Evidence from China. Journal of Business Ethics, 134 (4): 693708.Google Scholar
Gibbons, R., & Murphy, K. 1992. Optimal incentive contracts in the presence of career concerns: Theories and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 100 (3): 468506.Google Scholar
Grinstein, Y., Weinbaum, D., & Yehuda, N. 2017. The economic consequences of perk disclosure. Contemporary Accounting Research, DOI: 10.1111/1911-3846.12343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gul, F., Cheng, L., & Leung, T. 2011. Perks and the informativeness of stock prices in the Chinese market. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17 (5): 14101429.Google Scholar
Hambrick, D. C., & Mason, P. 1984. Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection of its top managers. Academy of Management Review, 9 (2): 193206.Google Scholar
Hart, O. 1983. The market mechanism as an incentive scheme. Bell Journal of Economics, 14 (2): 366382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, H. A., & Wang, Y. 2013. Going (more) public: Institutional isomorphism and ownership reform among Chinese firms. Management and Organization Review, 9 (1): 1751.Google Scholar
He, L., & Fang, J. 2016. CEO overpayment and dismissal: The role of attribution and attention. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 24 (1): 2441.Google Scholar
He, L., Shaw, T., & Fang, J. 2017. Managerial labor market during institutional transition: A study of CEO underpayment and voluntary turnover. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 25 (3): 167185.Google Scholar
Hermalin, B. E., 1992. The effects of competition on executive behavior. Rand Journal of Economics, 23 (3): 350365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hermalin, B. E., & Weisbach, M. S. 1988. The determinants of board composition. Rand Journal of Economics, 19 (4): 589606.Google Scholar
Huson, M. R., Tian, Y., Wiedman, C., & Wier, H. 2012. Compensation committees’ treatment of earnings components in CEOs’ terminal years. The Accounting Review, 87 (1): 231259.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review, 76 (2): 323329.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. 1993. The modern industrial revolution, exit and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of Finance, 48 (3): 831880.Google Scholar
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (4): 305360.Google Scholar
Jensen, M., & Murphy, K. J. 1990. Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98 (2): 225264.Google Scholar
Jensen, M., & Warner, J. B. 1988. The distribution of power among corporate managers, shareholders, and directors. Journal of Financial Economics, 20 (1–2): 324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ju, M., & Zhao, H. 2009. Behind organizational slack and firm performance in China: The moderating roles of ownership and competitive intensity. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26 (4): 701717.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. 1979. Prospect theory: Analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47 (2): 263291.Google Scholar
Kato, T., & Long, C. 2006. Executive turnover and firm performance in China. American Economic Review, 96 (2): 363367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. 2003. Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41 (4): 10951136.Google Scholar
Krause, R., & Semadeni, M. 2014. Last dance or second chance? Firm performance, CEO career horizon, and the separation of board leadership roles. Strategic Management Journal, 35 (6): 808825.Google Scholar
Laverty, K. 1996. Economic ‘short-termism’: The debate, the unresolved issues, and the implications for management practice and research. Academy of Management Review, 21 (3): 825860.Google Scholar
Li, S., Xia, J., Long, C., & Tan, J. 2012. Control modes and outcomes of transformed state owned enterprises in China: An empirical test. Management and Organization Review, 8 (2): 283309.Google Scholar
Lott, J. R. Jr. 1990. Attendance rates, political shirking, and the effect of post-elective office employment. Economic Inquiry, 28 (1): 133150.Google Scholar
Luo, W., Zhang, Y., & Zhu, N. 2011. Bank ownership and executive perquisites: New evidence from an emerging market. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17: 352–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J., & Simon, H. 1958. Organizations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Martin, G., Wiseman, R., & Gomez-Mejia, L. 2016. Going short-term or long-term? CEO stock options and temporal orientation in the presence of slack. Strategic Management Journal, 37 (12): 24632480.Google Scholar
Matejka, M., Merchant, K., & Stede, W. 2009. Employment horizon and the choice of performance measures: Empirical evidence from annual bonus plans of loss-making entities. Management Science, 55 (6): 890905.Google Scholar
Matta, E., & Beamish, P. 2008. The accentuated CEO career horizon problem: Evidence from international acquisitions. Strategic Management Journal, 29 (7): 683700.Google Scholar
McClelland, P. L., Barker, V. III, & Oh, W. 2012. CEO career horizon and tenure: Future performance implications under different contingencies. Journal of Business Research, 65: 13871393.Google Scholar
McClelland, P. L., Liang, X., Barker, V. III. 2010. CEO commitment to the status quo: replication and extension using content analysis. Journal of Management, 36 (5): 12511277.Google Scholar
Miller, 2002. Knowledge inventories and managerial myopia. Strategic Management Journal, 29 (3): 273292.Google Scholar
Meyer, K. 2015. Context in management research in emerging economies. Management and Organization Review, 11 (3): 369377.Google Scholar
Murphy, K. J., & Zimmerman, J. L. 1993. Financial performance surrounding CEO turnover. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 16 (1–3): 273315.Google Scholar
Narayanan, M. P. 1987. Managerial incentives for short-term results: A reply. Journal of Finance, 42 (4): 11031104.Google Scholar
Peng, M. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choices. Academy of Management Review, 28 (2): 275296.Google Scholar
Peng, M., Li, Y., Xie, E., & Su, Z. 2010. CEO duality, organizational slack, and firm performance in China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 27 (4): 611624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reilly, G., Souder, D., & Ranucci, R. 2016. Time horizon of investments in the resource allocation process: Review and framework for next steps. Journal of Management, 42 (5): 11691194.Google Scholar
Scharfstein, D. 1988. Product–market competition and organizational slack. Rand Journal of Economics, 19 (1): 147155.Google Scholar
Shen, W., & Lin, C. 2009. Firm profitability, state ownership, and top management turnover at the listed firms in China: A behavioral perspective. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17 (4): 443456.Google Scholar
Shen, W., Zhou, Q., & Lau, C. 2016. Empirical research on corporate governance in China: A review and new directions for the future. Management and Organization Review, 12 (1): 4173.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52 (2): 737–77.Google Scholar
Singh, J. 1986. Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making. Academy of Management Journal, 29 (3): 562585.Google Scholar
Souder, D., & Shaver, M. 2010. Constraints and incentives for making long horizon corporate investments. Strategic Management Journal, 31 (12): 13161336.Google Scholar
Stan, C., Peng, M., & Bruton, G. 2014. Slack and the performance of state-owned enterprises. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 31 (2): 473495.Google Scholar
Su, Y. Y., Xu, D., & Phan, P. H. 2008. Principal-principal conflict in the governance of the Chinese public corporation. Management and Organization Review, 4 (1): 1738.Google Scholar
Su, Z., Xie, E., & Li, Y. 2009. Organizational slack and firm performance during institutional transition. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26 (1): 7591.Google Scholar
Tan, J., & Peng, M. 2003. Organizational slack and firm performance during economic transitions: Two studies from an emerging economy. Strategic Management Journal, 24 (13): 12491263.Google Scholar
Weisbach, M. S. 1988. Outside directors and CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 431460.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1964. The economics of discretionary behavior: Managerial objectives in a theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1991. Economic institutions: Spontaneous and intentional governance. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7: 159187.Google Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. 2010. Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E., & Peng, M. W. 2005. Strategy research in emerging economies: Challenging the conventional wisdom. Journal of Management Studies, 42 (1):133.Google Scholar
Xu, C., & Yan, M. 2014. Radical or incremental innovations: R&D investment around CEO retirement. Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance, 29 (4): 547576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix

Figure 1

Table 2a. Managerial slack in final years vs. non-final years

Figure 2

Table 2b. Managerial slack in final years vs. non-final years for different corporate governance mechanisms

Figure 3

Table 3. Managerial slack in CEOs’ final years in office

Figure 4

Table 4. Managerial slack and corporate governance mechanisms: Split-sample tests

Figure 5

Table 5. Managerial slack and corporate governance mechanisms: Interaction models

Figure 6

Table 6. Managerial slack and firm performance