Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T17:51:21.911Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The political economy of foreign fighter death in the Russo-Ukrainian War: the role of institutions, politics, and international trade

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 April 2024

Franklin G. Mixon Jr.
Affiliation:
Center for Economic Education, Columbus State University, Columbus, GA, USA
Richard J. Cebula*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN, USA
*
Corresponding author: Richard J. Cebula; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This empirical study extends the public choice literature on the allocation of death during war by examining the political economy of foreign fighter deaths in the Russo-Ukrainian War since the 24 February 2022 invasion. The study explores the roles played by various demographic factors, military institutions, and international trade relations in determining the number of foreign fighters from a variety of countries who have died in support of either Ukraine or Russia during the Russo-Ukrainian War. Unlike other related studies, this study also investigates the importance of, and finds evidence in support of, both economic freedom and a robust democracy in shaping the choices made by individuals around the globe to venture to, and die fighting on, the battlefields of Ukraine.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Millennium Economics Ltd

Introduction

On 24 February 2022, Russia escalated its conflict with Ukraine, one that actually began in 2014, by invading Ukraine along three separate fronts in what was the largest attack on a European state since World War II. The Russo-Ukrainian War began with a pre-dawn declaration of war by Russian President Vladimir Putin, while the first day closed with Ukrainian President Volodymyr Zelensky's general mobilization order to ensure the defence of the country (Zinets and Vasovic, Reference Zinets and Vasovic2022). By the end of the first day, an estimated 100,000 Ukrainians had fled their homes, with many crossing into Romania, Moldova, Poland, and Hungary. Zelensky called on Ukraine's male population to remain and defend their country, adding that arms would be provided to anyone prepared to fight (Zinets and Vasovic, Reference Zinets and Vasovic2022). Since Zelensky's 24 February 2022 plea for Ukrainians to defend against the invasion, thousands of foreign fighters have poured into the theatre of war, with some supporting Ukraine while others have sided with Russia. Hundreds of these foreign fighters have since perished in the war, with most of these deaths occurring in support of Ukraine's defence against Russia.

An intriguing stream of public choice research that has developed over the past few decades that examines whether the disposition of military casualties during conflicts is, at times, impacted by the political desires of the government officials who are in a position to influence that disposition (Anderson and Tollison, Reference Anderson and Tollison1991; Cebula and Toma, Reference Cebula and Toma2006; Crisp and Mixon, Reference Crisp and Mixon2011; Goff and Tollison, Reference Goff and Tollison1987; Mixon, Reference Mixon2013; Mixon and Treviño, Reference Mixon and Treviño2002; Zerkle, Reference Zerkle2009). The present study seeks to extend that stream of research in a novel way, namely, by examining the political economy of foreign fighter deaths in the Russo-Ukrainian War since the 24 February 2022 invasion.Footnote 1 In doing so, this study most closely follows Mixon's (Reference Mixon2013) international public choice approach to the allocation of deaths in the recent Afghanistan War.Footnote 2 As in Mixon's (Reference Mixon2013) analysis of the allocation of deaths across minor allied countries in Afghanistan, this study explores the role played by demographic factors, military institutions, and international trade relations in determining the number of foreign fighters from various countries who have died in support of either Ukraine or Russia during the Russo-Ukrainian War. Unlike Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), however, we also examine the importance of economic freedom and democracy in shaping the choices made my individuals around the globe to venture to, and die fighting in, Ukraine.

Prior related literature: a brief review

The stream of public choice literature that is most relevant to the current study has developed along two separate but related branches. One of these branches involves the use of political institutions and power to manipulate the votes of members of the military in a way that favours incumbents. During times of military conflict, this process may even involve soldiers' access to the ballot box in a democratic election. The second of these branches involves the use of political influence in either the executive and/or the legislative arena in order to impact the disposition, and ultimately the deaths, of soldiers in the field. Each of these branches in the public choice literature is discussed in turn below.

Public choice and soldiers' access to the ballot box

Anderson and Tollison (Reference Anderson and Tollison1991) point out that incumbent President Abraham Lincoln won re-election in the U.S. presidential election of 1864 over challenger George McClellan by a comfortable popular vote margin – 55–45%. They also argue that from an Electoral College vote perspective, the Union soldier vote played a pivotal role in Lincoln's victory, as he carried this group by a margin of 77.6–22.4% over McClellan (Anderson and Tollison, Reference Anderson and Tollison1991; Crisp and Mixon, Reference Crisp and Mixon2011). Anderson and Tollison provide primary source evidence that Lincoln facilitated furloughs for Union soldiers to return home to vote if they lived in states that did not allow absentee ballots. Where absentee ballots were allowed, Lincoln took actions to smooth the way for Republican election agents to visit soldiers in the field, while at the same time Lincoln ordered obstacles be placed before Democratic election agents who sought to deliver absentee ballots to Union soldiers at the front (Anderson and Tollison, Reference Anderson and Tollison1991). As Anderson and Tollison (Reference Anderson and Tollison1991) indicate, this type of manipulation of the soldier vote is credited for providing Lincoln with winning popular vote margins in Connecticut, Illinois, Indiana, Maryland, New York, and Pennsylvania. The Electoral College votes from these states alone gave Lincoln more than 86% of the necessary Electoral College votes for a majority in the 1864 presidential election. Had the soldier vote not been facilitated by Lincoln and others, these states may well have gone to McClellan instead of Lincoln, thus giving George McClellan, Lincoln's Democratic opponent, a slim Electoral College vote margin in 1864 (Anderson and Tollison, Reference Anderson and Tollison1991).Footnote 3

Mixon and Treviño (Reference Mixon and Treviño2002) examine, through a public choice lens quite similar to that used by Anderson and Tollison (Reference Anderson and Tollison1991), historical accounts indicating that British Prime Minister Winston Churchill and his party allies had considerable influence over the date/timing of the British National Election, and, to some extent, the ability of the British military to cast votes in any election that was held before the official end of World War II. It was generally accepted that the British military favoured Churchill's Labour Party opponents given that they believed that a Labour Party victory would lead to a more rapid demobilization (Mixon and Treviño, Reference Mixon and Treviño2002). As a result, historical accounts of what were arguably Churchill's efforts to manage the military vote in the 1945 national election in a way favourable to him and his political allies are viewed by Mixon and Treviño (Reference Mixon and Treviño2002) as a rational response to the political environment at the time.Footnote 4

Zerkle (Reference Zerkle2009) also follows the Anderson and Tollison (Reference Anderson and Tollison1991) approach in asserting that what was expected to be a close wartime U.S. presidential election in 2004 gave incumbent U.S. President George Bush great incentive to treat wartime policy with an eye towards re-election. That is, the Bush Administration may have brought home reserve troops in key states in order to garner votes of reservists and reservists' families and communities. As Zerkle (Reference Zerkle2009) explains, the mechanism operates through voters gaining more support for the war in Iraq by witnessing troops returning largely unharmed. To determine a state's expected importance in the 2004 election, Zerkle (Reference Zerkle2009) uses political polling data, with expected electoral closeness being measured by counting the number of times a political poll flipped for one candidate versus the other.Footnote 5 Econometric tests indicate that each flip in a state poll correlates to 138 troops returned to that state over and above the average experienced by the non-flip states, ceteris paribus (Zerkle, Reference Zerkle2009).

Public choice and the allocation of soldier deaths

As Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) points out, an intriguing stream of public choice research has developed over the past few decades that examines whether the disposition of military casualties during conflicts is, at times, influenced by the political desires of the government officials who are in a position to influence that disposition (Anderson and Tollison, Reference Anderson and Tollison1991; Cebula and Toma, Reference Cebula and Toma2006; Crisp and Mixon, Reference Crisp and Mixon2011; Goff and Tollison, Reference Goff and Tollison1987; Mixon, Reference Mixon2013; Mixon and Treviño, Reference Mixon and Treviño2002; Zerkle, Reference Zerkle2009).Footnote 6 The seminal study by Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987) investigates the probability of death facing U.S. troops during the Vietnam War (1965–1971) against the hypothesis that the political influence of various U.S. Representatives and Senators was wielded to favour the safety of their own constituents-soldiers, such as placement in roles farther from the front lines of the conflict. Econometric evidence presented in that study suggests that casualty rates were lower, ceteris paribus, in states where U.S. Representatives and Senators held the highest seniority in the U.S. Congress and were perhaps able to secure for favoured constituents a deployment assignment that was safer than those faced by other infantry (Goff and Tollison, Reference Goff and Tollison1987). Other results presented by Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987) suggest that casualty rates were also lower among soldiers from states where the link between elected representatives and the defence industry was strong, thus highlighting the role of rent seeking theory (Krueger, Reference Krueger1974; Posner, Reference Posner1975; Tullock, Reference Tullock1967) in this political process.

Following the Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987) approach, Cebula and Toma's (Reference Cebula and Toma2006) analysis of Operation Iraqi Freedom follows the template established in Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987) by positing that presidential campaign strategies are influenced by the anticipated closeness of the election outcome across states in the Electoral College. Econometric results presented in the study indicate that the greater the competition for the electoral votes in a state during the 2004 U.S. Presidential election, the relatively fewer fatalities that state suffered. Additionally, Cebula and Toma report that fatalities were lower in states with U.S. Senate representation on that chamber's Armed Services Committee (Cebula and Toma, Reference Cebula and Toma2006). Next, the study by Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), which follows the approach of Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987) and the subsequent study by Cebula and Toma (Reference Cebula and Toma2006) and is most closely linked to the current one, investigates the allocation of deaths among the minor countries (i.e. countries other than the United States and England) involved in the Afghanistan War, also known as Operation Enduring Freedom, against the backdrop of political influence exerted from various quarters. Econometric results presented in Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) suggest that longer tenure in high-ranking posts within the United Nations, such as U.N. Secretary General, U.N. Deputy Secretary General, and U.N. General Assembly President, provided the political influence necessary to reduce military deaths among the minor participating countries that occupy them. The results also suggest that maintaining a free trade relationship with the U.S. or being the recipient of U.S. economic and military aid puts political pressure on countries to place more combatants in harm's way in a war being led by the U.S. (Mixon, Reference Mixon2013).

Political economy of foreign fighter flows

Only a few academic studies have examined the determinants of foreign fighter flows into military conflicts, and these typically focus on conflicts in the Middle East. For example, Krueger (Reference Krueger2006) examines the determinants of foreign fighters' support of Iraq in its post-9/11 war against the U.S. and its allies. To do so, Krueger (Reference Krueger2006) analyses data on the country of origin of 311 foreign fighters who were captured from April to October of 2005. In each specification tested, the results suggest on the one hand a significantly positive relationship between the size of the origin country's population and the number of its citizens who joined Iraq's war effort and on the other hand a significantly negative relationship between the distance from the origin country's capital city to Iraq's capital city (Baghdad) and the number of its citizens who joined Iraq's war effort. As expected, the percentage of the host country's population that is Muslim is positively and significantly related to foreign fighter flows from that country, while the degree of civil liberties present in the host country is negatively and significantly related to foreign fighter flows from the country (Krueger, Reference Krueger2006). Lastly, from a different perspective, Krueger (Reference Krueger2006) also reports that a higher infant mortality rate in a given country of origin is associated with significantly fewer of that country's citizens being captured in Iraq, whereas in one specification a higher literacy rate has a negative and significant effect on the number of captured insurgents from a given country.

Related studies by Pokalova (Reference Pokalova2019) and Benmelech and Klor (Reference Benmelech and Klor2020) examine the number of foreign fighters who joined the Islamic State of Iraq and Syria (ISIS) in its effort to establish a caliphate in the Middle East. Pokalova (Reference Pokalova2019) employs a dataset of 33,815 foreign fighters originating from 103 countries and finds that more foreign fighters originate in countries with larger populations, higher percentages of Muslims, and greater human development and religious diversity. The study also reports that countries with higher unemployment and greater internet penetration rates, along with those where youths account for greater shares of the overall population, produce more foreign fighters (Pokalova, Reference Pokalova2019). Next, Benmelech and Klor (Reference Benmelech and Klor2020) report that about 30,000 fighters from at least 85 countries joined the Islamic State of Iraq and Syria (ISIS) through December 2015 in its effort to establish a caliphate. Although a vast majority travelled from the Middle East, many came from Europe, the United States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. The main finding in Benmelech and Klor (Reference Benmelech and Klor2020) is that the size of a country's Muslim population positively and significantly impacted the number of ISIS foreign fighters originating from the country. They also find that a host country's GDP per capita and its unemployment rate are positively and significantly associated with the number of ISIS fighters supplied by that country (Benmelech and Klor, Reference Benmelech and Klor2020). Benmelech and Klor (Reference Benmelech and Klor2020) also report that income inequality in a given country is associated with fewer ISIS foreign fighters from that country. Finally, a recent study by Koch (Reference Koch2021) examines the various ideological motivations, both left and right, of foreign fighters who joined the fight against ISIS. This study, however, does not include statistical examination of the tendency of foreigners to journey to Syria and Iraq in order to assist other anti-ISIS warriors.

Public choice and the Russo-Ukrainian War: framing the hypotheses

As stated above, this study endeavours to explain the variations in the number of foreign fighters who have died in support of either Ukraine's defence or Russia's invasion since early 2022. The former number is specified from an econometric perspective as UDeathsi, or as the number of individuals from country i who have died in support of Ukraine during the Russo-Ukrainian War. The latter is specified as RDeathsi, or as the number of individuals from country i who have died in support of Russia during the Russo-Ukrainian War. Each of these is hypothesized to be a function of a number of demographic, military institutions, international trade, and economic/political institutions variables that are explained in the subsections that follow.

Demographic effects

Following Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), travelling from one's home to a battlefield in Ukraine is at best a difficult logistics process. Thus, one would expect that the distance between Kyiv and the capital of country i (in miles) would negatively impact the number of citizens who are able to journey from country i to the battlefields in Ukraine (Krueger, Reference Krueger2006; Mixon, Reference Mixon2013). Thus, one would expect that the number of foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of either Ukraine or Russia would be negatively related to Distancei, ceteris paribus. This expectation would hold whether or not citizens who choose to become foreign fighters travel to Ukraine as private citizens or do so with government, and possibly military, assistance (Mixon, Reference Mixon2013). The latter possibility is discussed in greater detail in the next subsection of this study.

Next, MedInci, or real median income (2021, PPP) in country i is included in both econometric specifications (Benmelech and Klor, Reference Benmelech and Klor2020; Cebula and Toma, Reference Cebula and Toma2006; Goff and Tollison, Reference Goff and Tollison1987; Krueger, Reference Krueger2006; Mixon, Reference Mixon2013; Pokalova, Reference Pokalova2019). Given the expense of travelling from country i to Ukraine, a relatively greater number of private citizens who choose to do so in an effort to support either Ukraine or Russia may be expected from relatively high-income countries than from relatively low-income countries, ceteris paribus. On the other hand, given that the opportunity cost of foreign fighter participation is greater for high-income individuals than for lower-income individuals, it may be the case that relatively fewer private citizens who choose to do so in an effort to support either Ukraine or Russia may be expected from relatively high-income countries than from relatively low-income countries, ceteris paribus. Both of these expectations are, however, muddled by the fact that Putin offers various forms of compensation for foreign fighters who support Russia.Footnote 7 As such, no a priori is offered regarding the relationship between MedInci and either UDeathsi or RDeathsi. Lastly, following Krueger (Reference Krueger2006), Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), and Pokalova (Reference Pokalova2019), the population of each country in the sample is accounted for by the variable Popi, which is expected to retain a positively signed coefficient in any model given the straightforward statistical expectation that more foreign fighters will originate, and ultimately die on the battlefields of Ukraine, from countries with larger populations, ceteris paribus.

Military institution effects

As explained in Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), there are a number of military-related institutional variables that may explain how many of a country's citizens participate, and ultimately die, in the Russo-Ukrainian War. The dummy variable NATOi is equal to 1 for countries that were members of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) at the beginning of the Russo-Ukrainian War, and 0 otherwise. Whether or not that country maintains military conscription and the size of a country's military are two additional examples of military-related institutional variables that may help to explain the number of battlefield deaths from country i. Thus, the econometric specifications include both Conscriptioni and MilitarySizei, with the former being a dummy variable equal to 1 if country i maintains a system of military conscription, and 0 otherwise, while the latter is the number of active soldiers in country i's standing army. A fourth institutional variable in this category is MilitarySupporti, which is equal to the amount of military support (in €billions) provided by country i to Ukraine.

As Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) observes, the variable NATOi accounts for countries with close geopolitical and national security ties to the United States, the country that is, along with Poland, arguably one of the strongest proponents of Ukraine's defence against the Russian invasion. NATO members such as France, Germany, and Italy have historically benefitted from close connections to the United States, particularly in terms of national defence (Mixon, Reference Mixon2013). As such, citizens from NATO countries may be more likely than others to venture to Ukraine in order to support its defence effort against Russia. At the same time, one would not expect citizens from NATO countries to travel to Russia, and ultimately die in support of, its February of 2022 invasion of Ukraine. Thus, we expect that the parameter estimate attached to the variable NATOi will be positively signed in the UDeathsi specification but negatively signed in the RDeathsi specification, ceteris paribus.

Next, Conscriptioni and MilitarySizei may relate to the likelihood that a country's citizens have prior military experience and adhere to a military ethos. If so, one would expect larger numbers of citizens from countries that maintain conscription and/or have larger standing armies to venture across the globe to support either country, Ukraine or Russia, in the Russo-Ukrainian War. These variables may also relate to the likelihood that a country's active-duty forces are voluntarily used, either overtly or covertly, to aid one side or the other in the conflict. Following Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), larger militaries afford countries with the capacity to support military engagements abroad. Countries with relatively large militaries, and/or that maintain conscription, also likely have national security concerns. Such countries stand to benefit, in a learning-curve sense, from occasional military engagements abroad. As such, countries with relatively large militaries, and those that maintain conscription of soldiers, are expected to support either country, Ukraine or Russia, in the Russo-Ukrainian War, ceteris paribus, than are countries with relatively small militaries and that do not employ conscription. Given these arguments, we expect that the parameter estimates attached to both Conscriptioni and MilitarySizei will be positively signed in both the UDeathsi and RDeathsi specifications, ceteris paribus.

Lastly, as in the case of NATO membership, any financial support for Ukraine's war effort by country i would likely be seen by the United States as an act of loyalty. Thus, citizens from countries loyal to the United States are expected to be more likely than citizens of other countries to travel to Ukraine in order to join Ukraine's military defence against Russia. Similarly, citizens from countries that are not so loyal to the United States, as indicated by the lack of financial support from their governments of Ukraine's defence, are expected to be more likely than citizens from countries that donate financially to Ukraine's defence to travel to Ukraine in order to join Russia's invasion of Ukraine. Given that the decisions made by citizens around the globe to fight in Ukraine will be linked to battlefield deaths there, one would expect the parameter estimate attached to the variable MilitarySupporti will be positively signed in the UDeathsi specification, but negatively signed in the RDeathsi specification, ceteris paribus.

International trade effects

Four international trade-related variables are also included in the econometric specifications. These are OECDi, TradeAgreementUi, TradeAgreementRi, and RussianEnergyi. The first of these, OECDi, is a dummy variable equal to 1 if country i was a member of the Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) at the outset of the 2022 Russian invasion of Ukraine, and 0 otherwise. The OECD is a 60-year-old organization of 38 countries whose stated goal is to shape policies that foster prosperity, equality, opportunity, and well-being of a country's citizens. Headquartered in Paris, France, the OECD's most prominent founding members are the United States, United Kingdom, France, and Germany, each of which has publicly supported Ukraine in its war with Russia. To the extent that this support is inculcated in the populations of these 38 countries, one would expect, ceteris paribus, OECDi to positively impact UDeathsi, but negatively impact RDeathsi.

The next two international trade-related variables – TradeAgreementUi and TradeAgreementRi – are dummy variables equal to 1 if country i maintains a separate trade agreement with Ukraine, in the case of TradeAgreementUi, and/or with Russia, in the case of TradeAgreementRi, and 0 otherwise. If these relationships translate into support for the trading partner's military endeavours, the TradeAgreementUi will be expected to positively impact UDeathsi, whereas TradeAgreementRi will be expected to positively impact RDeathsi, ceteris paribus. The final international trade-related variable, RussianEnergyi, is equal to the annual value (in $billions) of oil, gas, and/or coal imported by country i from Russia. Several countries are highly dependent on Russia for such forms of energy. One would expect, therefore, that the size of a country's energy bill from Russia will negatively (positively) impact UDeathsi (RDeathsi), ceteris paribus.

Economic and political institution effects

Unlike prior studies by Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987), Cebula and Toma (Reference Cebula and Toma2006), and Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), this paper considers the impact of certain important economic and political institutions. The first of these is economic freedom in country i, as measured by the Heritage Foundation's Index of Economic Freedom.Footnote 8 Citizens from countries positioned relatively high on this index likely possess an affinity for the economic freedom they enjoy. As such, they likely sympathize with the recent plight of Ukrainians and, in some cases at least, may feel a desire to venture to the battlefield in order to provide military support for Ukraine's defence. On the other hand, citizens from countries positioned lower along this index will likely constitute a relatively large portion of the foreign fighters who are currently participating in Russia's invasion of Ukraine. As such, and consistent with Krueger (Reference Krueger2006), EconFreedomIndexi is likely to positively impact UDeathsi, but negatively impact RDeathsi, ceteris paribus.

The second of these political institutions is the strength of democracy in country i, as measured by The Economist's Global Democracy Index.Footnote 9 As with economic freedom, citizens from countries scoring relatively high along this index likely enjoy the various democratic principles of government. Thus, they likely favour and support the political institutions that the Ukrainians have expressed an interest in developing. As before, in some cases they may feel a desire to venture to the battlefield in order to provide military support for Ukraine's defence. On the other hand, many citizens from countries scoring lower along this index will likely venture to Ukraine to support Russia's invasion of that country. As such, and again consistent with Krueger (Reference Krueger2006), DemocracyIndexi is expected to positively impact UDeathsi, but negatively impact RDeathsi, ceteris paribus.

Data, empirical approach, and econometric results

Both regression specifications (i.e. that corresponding to UDeathsi and that corresponding to RDeathsi) utilize data from 131 countries. The list of countries included in the study appears in Table A1 of the Appendix. A breakdown of foreign fighter deaths (as of December 2023) by country of origin is provided in Table A2 of the Appendix.Footnote 10 Data for the distance between Kyiv and the capital of country i, or Distancei, are measured in miles and come from the website DistanceFromTo.net. Data for MedInci, or real median income (2021, PPP) in country i, and the population of country i (Popi) are collected from World Population Review. Members of NATO are found on that organization's website. Following the United Nations, information on the maintenance of military conscription across the countries in the dataset is found at NationMaster.com. Members of the OECD are found on that organization's website. Data for the size of country i's standing army (in millions) are found in World Population Review, whereas those pertaining to financial support (in €billions) from country i for Ukraine's defence are collected from the Kiel Institute for the World Economy. Information on the various individual trade agreements between country i and either Ukraine or Russia is collected from the International Trade Administration of the U.S. Department of Commerce and the Congressional Research Service. Data for the value of Russian energy imported by country i are collected from Conte (Reference Conte2023). Information on economic freedom in country i, and the robustness of country i's democracy, comes from the Heritage Foundation and The Economist, respectively. Lastly, data on the number of foreign fighter deaths used to compile UDeathsi and RDeathsi are taken from numerous news reports.

Summary statistics

As indicated in Table 1, about 1.5 times as many foreign fighters have died in support of Ukraine as have died supporting Russia's invasion. Also, the average distance between the capitals of the countries in the sample and Kyiv is 3,276 miles, the average population across the countries in the sample is about 56.8 million, and the real median income of the typical country is $5,734. Next, about 21% of the countries in the sample are members of NATO, while nearly 14% of countries maintain military conscription. The mean size of the standing armies in the sample is about 131,000 soldiers, and the average financial contribution to Ukraine's defence during the recent conflict is €0.57 billion. In terms of the economic variables, just over 27% of the countries in the sample are members of the OECD, while 11.5 and 3.1% of the countries maintain a trade agreement with Ukraine and Russia, respectively. Lastly, the typical country in the sample purchases about $0.62 billion in Russian energy annually. Among the countries in the sample, the mean overall economic freedom score is almost 61, while the democracy rating of the typical country is just over 5.5.

Table 1. Variable descriptions and summary statistics

Correlation coefficients

Next, we examined a correlation matrix containing all of the variables included in this study. Of the 78 correlation coefficient estimates not involving either UDeaths or RDeaths, 63 fall between ±0.400. Even so, there are a number of correlations that fall outside of this range. For example, there are relatively large positive correlations among MedInc, NATO, OECD, EconFreedomIndex, and DemocracyIndex. The positive correlation between the last two variables in this list is not unexpected, given research by Leeson and Dean (Reference Leeson and Dean2009) and Leeson et al. (Reference Leeson, Sobel and Dean2012) indicating that a country's ability to reform its political institutions in a particular manner may depend on its ability to reform its economic institutions in a particular manner as well, and/or vice-versa. It is also consistent with the combination of earlier work by Barro (Reference Barro1996, Reference Barro1997), indicating that democracy is a normal good, and a plethora of studies that find a positive relationship between economic freedom and per capita income (see Berggren, Reference Berggren2003; Gwartney et al., Reference Gwartney, Holcombe and Lawson2004). Next, the correlations between MedInc and the other four variables range from +0.540 to +0.738. Similarly, the correlations between NATO and the other four variables range from +0.470 to +0.638, while those between OECD and the other four variables range from +0.638 to +0.738. Lastly, correlations between EconFreedomIndex and the other four variables range from +0.470 to +0.793, whereas the correlations between DemocracyIndex and the other four variables range from +0.477 to +0.793. In addition to these correlations, there are some other relatively large correlations (in absolute value) involving Pop, MilitarySize, MilitarySupport, and RussianEnergy. As a result, we offer results from various specifications of our econometric model in order to explore the impact of multicollinearity on the individual results.

Empirical approach

Modelling the distribution of deaths among foreign fighters in the Russo-Ukrainian War requires data on the number of fighters from country i who are killed during the Russo-Ukrainian War supporting either the Ukrainian defence (i.e. UDeathsi) or the Russian invasion (i.e. RDeathsi). Either dependent variable, UDeathsi or RDeathsi, is both observed and discrete, thus requiring a limited dependent variables approach. Following Cameron and Trivedi (Reference Cameron and Trivedi1998), a Poisson model, estimated by maximum likelihood, is employed. In order to measure the predictive power of the model, we report the $R_d^2$, which is based on residual deviances from a Poisson regression including all of the regressors and one including only a constant term (Cameron and Trivedi, Reference Cameron and Trivedi1998). The Poisson regression results for the allocation of foreign fighter deaths in the Russo-Ukrainian War are provided in Table 2, with estimates from the UDeathsi specifications occupying the left-hand side of the table and estimates from the RDeathsi specifications shown on the right-hand side of the table. Results for all seven econometric specifications in each case are jointly significant. As shown at the bottom of Table 2, the $R_d^2$ statistics range from 0.401 to 0.593 for the UDeathsi, and from 0.608 to 0.730 for the RDeathsi specifications. Although each of these ranges is noteworthy, care should be taken in comparing any one to the others given that the number of observations employed varies as regressors are added to or subtracted from the unrestricted specification.

Table 2. Poisson regression results

Notes: The numbers in parentheses above are t-values. *(‡)[†] denotes the 0.01(0.05)[0.10] level of significance.

Demographic effects

In terms of the demographic factors, distance from the theatre of war (i.e. Ukraine) matters, as in Krueger (Reference Krueger2006). The variable Distance is, ceteris paribus, negatively signed and statistically significant across all seven of the specifications on the left-hand side of Table 2. This suggests that distance from the battlefield significantly hampers the ability and/or willingness of foreign fighters to fight, and ultimately to die on the battlefield, in support of Ukraine's defence against Russia. The first two coefficient estimates attached to Distance on the right-hand side of Table 2 are also negatively signed. In the first of these two cases, it is statistically significant, suggesting that distance from the battlefield significantly hampers the ability of foreign fighters to fight, and ultimately die on the battlefield, in support of Russia's offensive against Ukraine.

Next, only one specification in each case includes MedInc, and, consistent with Goff and Tollison (Reference Goff and Tollison1987) and Cebula and Toma (Reference Cebula and Toma2006), the coefficient estimate attached to it is negatively signed in each case. This suggests that, regardless of which side is being supported, foreign fighters who die on the battlefields of Ukraine tend to arrive there from lower income countries. In the case of support for Russia, the income effect is significantly negative. Given that the correlation coefficient estimates indicate relatively high correlations between MedInc and NATO, OECD, and the two index variables, EconFreedomIndex and DemocracyIndex, a version of the base model without these four variables was estimated in each case in order to evaluate the impact that multicollinearity has on the prior results. Although the results in Table 2 reveal that Pop positively and significantly impacted RDeaths, as found in Krueger (Reference Krueger2006), Mixon (Reference Mixon2013), and Pokalova (Reference Pokalova2019). Results from this auxiliary specification suggest that Pop is not significantly related to foreign fighter deaths in support of either country, while MedInc is positively and significantly related to foreign fighter deaths in support of Ukraine and negatively and significantly associated with foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia.

Military institution effects

With regard to the military variables, there are fewer foreign fighter deaths from NATO countries than from other countries, ceteris paribus, regardless of which combatant country is being supported. This result is statistically significant in five of the seven specifications in the case of support for Ukraine, and in all seven specifications in the case of support for Russia. In the case of battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine's defence, NATO countries contribute only 38.5–54.0% of the battlefield deaths that non-NATO countries contribute, ceteris paribus. In the case of battlefield deaths in support of Russia's invasion, NATO countries contribute only 5.0–21.7% of the battlefield deaths that non-NATO countries contribute, ceteris paribus. Interestingly, an auxiliary specification, one that is not included in Table 2, that omits five variables that are highly correlated with NATODist, MedInc, OECD, EconFreedomIndex, and DemocracyIndex – was also estimated. In this case, the variable NATO is positively signed in the UDeaths specification, although it is not statistically significant at acceptable levels. This result suggests that NATO membership is effectively unrelated to the geographic origin of the foreign fighters who have died in support of Ukraine's defence.Footnote 11 On the other hand, the coefficient attached to NATO in the RDeaths specification remains negatively signed and statistically significant. This finding suggests that NATO countries contribute only 5.7% of the foreign fighter battlefield deaths, ceteris paribus, that non-NATO countries contribute in support of Russia's offensive. This figure is very near the low end of the range discussed above. Moreover, the latter results are consistent with the findings reported in Mixon (Reference Mixon2013).

The results for Conscription are generally mixed in terms of signs and for the most part are statistically insignificant. However, there is one specification involving RDeaths where Conscription is positively signed and statistically significant. This estimation suggests that there are 78.4% more foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia's invasion of Ukraine from countries that maintain military conscription than there are from countries that maintain volunteer armies, ceteris paribus. There are two other specifications involving RDeaths shown in Table 2, where Conscription is only marginally insignificant. In these cases, the parameter estimates suggest that there are 28.3 or 58.7% more foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia's invasion of Ukraine from countries that maintain military conscription than there are from countries that maintain volunteer armies, ceteris paribus. If taken together, the results suggest that the positive impact of Conscription on RDeaths ranges from 28.3 to 78.4%.

Next, the results in Table 2 indicate that foreign fighter deaths in support of Ukraine tend to emanate more from countries with relatively large standing armies, while those in support of Russia tend to emanate from countries with smaller standing armies. The results in Table 2 pertaining to financial support for Ukraine's defence against Russia are mixed, with the negatively signed and significant parameter estimates in the UDeaths specifications being the result of multicollinearity. In version six on the left-hand side of the table, the positively signed and statistically significant coefficient attached to MilitarySupport suggests that countries contributing more financially to Ukraine's defence are also home to more foreign fighter battlefield deaths in defence of Ukraine. According to the estimate, each additional €1 billion in military aid sent to Ukraine is associated with about 5.5% more battlefield deaths from that country, ceteris paribus. In the right-hand side specifications, MilitarySupport is negatively related to RDeaths, as expected, once the effect of multicollinearity is filtered out.

International trade effects

Maintenance of trade relations with Ukraine appears to be an important consideration in terms of foreign manpower support for Ukraine's military efforts. The results shown in Table 2 are consistent with Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) in suggesting that countries with separate international trade agreements with Ukraine tend to contribute more battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine than do countries lacking such ties to Ukraine. At the same time, countries with separate international trade agreements with Russia tend to contribute only 5.3–17.6% of the foreign deaths in support of Ukraine that countries lacking such trade relations with Russia contribute in support of Ukraine. On the other hand, there is some evidence that foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia from those countries maintaining separate international trade agreements with Russia are greater than foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia from countries lacking such trade arrangements. These results align with those in Mixon (Reference Mixon2013).

The results concerning the variable RussianEnergy are quite interesting. They indicate that the citizens of countries that are relatively large purchasers of Russian oil, gas, and/or coal tend to die in lower numbers supporting Ukraine's defence that do citizens of other countries. The estimates suggest that for every $1 billion that a country spends on Russian energy imports, that country experiences between 21.4 and 53.2% fewer foreign fighter deaths in support of Ukraine. As indicated on the right-hand side of Table 3, that same country experiences between 32.0 and 56.0% more foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia's invasion with every additional $1 billion of Russian energy imported.

Table 3. Negative binomial regression results

Notes: The numbers in parentheses above are t-values. *(‡)[†] denotes the 0.01(0.05)[0.10] level of significance.

Economic and political institution effects

Lastly, the results for institutions related to economic freedom suggest that economically freer countries are associated with more foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine, and fewer foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Russia, than are their less economically free counterparts, ceteris paribus. For example, a one-unit increase in a country's economic freedom index is associated with between 8 and 15.8% more foreign fighter deaths in support of Ukraine, and between 5.3 and 6.8% fewer foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Russia. After testing multiple specifications to examine the impact of multicollinearity, which is expected to be present given aforementioned research by Leeson and Dean (Reference Leeson and Dean2009) and Leeson et al. (Reference Leeson, Sobel and Dean2012) on the joint development of a country's economic and political institutions, it appears that the results pertaining to democratic government also provide evidence in support of our expectations. These results indicate more democratic countries are associated with more foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine, and fewer foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Russia, than are their more authoritarian counterparts, ceteris paribus. In this case, a one-unit increase in a country's democracy index is associated with between 16.9 and 18.6% more foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine, and between 21.7 and 24% fewer foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Russia.

Negative binomial estimates

To explore the impact of overdispersion in the data examined in this study, we also estimated the unrestricted version of each model presented in Table 2 using negative binominal regression estimation. These results, which are presented in Table 3, generally support their counterparts in Table 2. For example, OECD membership is positively associated with foreign fighter deaths, ceteris paribus, regardless of which combatant country is being supported. As with those in Table 2, the results shown in Table 3 are consistent with Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) in suggesting that countries with separate international trade agreements with Ukraine tend to contribute more battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine than do countries lacking such ties to Ukraine. Lastly, the economic freedom (or lack thereof) enjoyed by a country has an influence on whether it has contributed to the foreign fighter death toll in the Russo-Ukrainian War. Based on the results in Table 3, a one-unit increase in a country's economic freedom index is associated with 9.5% more foreign fighter deaths in support of Ukraine, and 13.7% fewer foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Russia. Moreover, when specification (6) on both the right-hand and left-hand sides of Table 2 is tested using negative binomial regression, DemocracyIndex retains a positively signed and statistically significant parameter estimate in explaining UDeaths and a negatively signed parameter estimate in explaining RDeaths. The results suggest that a one-unit increase in a country's democracy index is associated with 64.8% more foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Ukraine, and 15.9% fewer foreign fighter battlefield deaths in support of Russia.

Moreover, a few of the results presented in Table 3 differ from their Table 2 counterparts. For instance, distance from the battlefields is a significant determinant of only the number of foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia. The Poisson regression indicated a significantly negative relationship between distance and foreign fighter deaths regardless of which combatant country is being supported. Also, NATO membership is positively associated with UDeaths and negatively (and statistically significantly) associated with RDeaths. These results are more in line with expectations than are their counterparts from the Poisson regression. Next, the presence of conscription in a country is associated with 86.4% fewer foreign fighter deaths in support of Russia from that country than is expected from a country that does not maintain conscription. Lastly, the binomial regression results reported in Table 3 indicate that maintenance of separate international trade agreements with Russia does not appear to influence either UDeaths or RDeaths.

Conclusions

This research undertaking has sought, using the most recent available data, to investigate the allocation of deaths among foreign fighters in the Russo-Ukrainian War since the 24 February 2022 Russian invasion of Ukraine. In doing so, this study most closely follows parallels Mixon's (Reference Mixon2013) international public choice approach to the allocation of deaths among the minor allies of the United States in the recent Afghanistan War. As in Mixon's (Reference Mixon2013) analysis, this study explores the role played by demographic factors, military institutions, and international trade relations in determining the number of foreign fighters from various countries who have died in support of either Ukraine or Russia during the Russo-Ukrainian War. Unlike Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) and other related studies, however, this study also examines and finds empirical support for the importance of economic freedom and democracy in shaping the choices made by individuals around the globe to venture to, and risk dying, fighting on the battlefields of Ukraine.

There are multiple avenues for future research of this subject. First and foremost, as this war drags on, newer investigations of the sort provided here should provide important insights into the determinants of foreign fighter flows related to this particular conflict. Perhaps another fruitful avenue for future research pertains to an investigation of spatial autocorrelation relating to the institutional variables (e.g. economic freedom and democracy) along the lines of Leeson and Dean (Reference Leeson and Dean2009) and Leeson et al. (Reference Leeson, Sobel and Dean2012), particularly if a dataset can be constructed that provides foreign fighter deaths per year. Lastly, an understanding of the motivations of foreign fighters to participate in the war may be gained through analysis of the biographical information about the individual fighters who have participated and died in the conflict. Although there have been several hundred foreign fighter deaths thus far in the Russo-Ukranian War, a biographical analysis in this case may be more manageable than in other major military conflicts.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank four anonymous referees for helpful comments on a previous version. Any remaining errors are our own.

Financial support

The authors received no external financial support in the production of this study.

Appendix

Table A1. Countries included in the empirical analyses

Table A2. Foreign fighter deaths by country of origin

Footnotes

1 A recent issue of the Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice includes a symposium on public choice aspects of the Russo-Ukrainian War. However, none of these studies, including either Hebert and Krasnozhon (Reference Hebert and Krasnozhon2024) or Trantidis (Reference Trantidis2024), examines this particular public choice aspect of that conflict.

2 Mixon (Reference Mixon2013) focused on the determinants of battlefield casualties across the countries allied with the United States in its war against Al Qaida and the Taliban. These included, but were not limited to, receipt by that country of foreign aid and/or military aid from the United States, the maintenance of free trade agreements with the United States, and the seats of institutional power held by individuals from that country at the top of the United Nations bureaucratic hierarchy.

3 Crisp and Mixon (Reference Crisp and Mixon2011) extend research by Anderson and Tollison (Reference Anderson and Tollison1991) by examining how Lincoln rewarded those in his orbit who facilitated his 1864 election win. In doing so, Crisp and Mixon (Reference Crisp and Mixon2011) employ elements of the modern theory of bureaucracy (Breton and Wintrobe, Reference Breton and Wintrobe1982, Reference Breton and Wintrobe1986).

4 Election simulations presented by Mixon and Treviño (Reference Mixon and Treviño2002) suggest that Churchill would have had to work to prevent anywhere from 78.0 to 81.5% (approximately) of the total military vote, which represents 1.95 million to 2.04 million (approximately) military votes, in order to provide a Conservative alliance victory in 1945. Thus, it is unsurprising that any attempt by Churchill to manipulate the election outcome ultimately failed.

5 As Zerkle (Reference Zerkle2009) explains, changes in the leader in an election poll, referred to as ‘flips’, are counted based on the initial election poll within a state. For instance, if the first poll in a state projected that Candidate A is expected to win the election, the first subsequent poll favoring Candidate B counts as one ‘flip’ (i.e. the first ‘flip’). Going forward with the above example, if Candidate B leads in the next three election polls (i.e. elections polls two through four), then no additional ‘flips’ would have occurred (Zerkle, Reference Zerkle2009). However, if Candidate A were to lead again in the fifth election poll, then there would have been two ‘flips’ thus far in this state. Following this process going forward, the number of ‘flips’ in the state are summed for a total for that state (Zerkle, Reference Zerkle2009).

6 This genre of the literature includes studies of the allocation of death outside of the military context, such as the public choice examination by Mixon (Reference Mixon2015) of the allocation of death during the Salem witch trials. This literature stream is also at least tangentially related to studies that test public choice models of resource allocation in a legislative setting, such as Stroup's (Reference Stroup1998) empirical analysis of the distribution of Department of Defense personnel – both military and civilian – across states.

7 Between May of 2022 and May of 2023, Putin admittedly directed $1 billion to support the Wagner Group, a paramilitary group that has supported Russia's war efforts using foreign fighters (Seddon et al., Reference Seddon, Ivanova and Minder2023). This appropriation, and others like it, allow the Wagner Group to compensate its fighters generously. In January of 2024, Putin began issuing contracts allowing foreign fighters to gain Russian citizenship upon completion of one year of service (Trevelyan, Reference Trevelyan2024).

8 The Heritage Foundation's Index of Economic Freedom is based on 12 quantitative and qualitative factors of economic freedom, including the rule of law, government size, regulatory efficiency and open markets.

9 The Economist's Global Democracy Index is based on 60 indicators that capture a country's electoral process and pluralism, civil liberties, functioning of government, political participation and political culture.

10 These deaths are catalogued by Wikipedia, with sources noted in each case (see https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Casualties_of_the_Russo-Ukrainian_War#:~:text=by%2014%20December.-,Foreign%20fighters%20and%20volunteers,fighting%20on%20the%20Ukrainian%20side). Sources include, but are not limited to, ABC News, Anambay News, Army Times, BBC News, Business Insider, CNN, The Daily Beast, The Guardian, The Kyiv Independent, Memorial International Legion Ukraine, Odishi TV, The New York Times, Pulzo, Taiwan News, La Teja, The Telegraph, Ukrainska Pravda and The Washington Post. Even with these prominent sources, we accept the likelihood that much more is accurately known about the number of foreign fighters who have died in support of Ukraine than about the number of foreign fighters who have died in support of Russia.

11 Based on the regression coefficient from this auxiliary regression, NATO countries contribute 27% more foreign fighter battlefield deaths, ceteris paribus, than do other countries in support of Ukraine's defense.

References

Anderson, G.M. and Tollison, R.D. (1991). Political influence on civil war mortality rates: The electoral college as a battlefield. Defence Economics 2(3), 219233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1996). Getting it Right: Markets and Choices in a Free Society. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1997). Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Benmelech, E. and Klor, E.F. (2020). What explains the flow of foreign fighters to ISIS? Terrorism and Political Violence 32(7), 14581481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N. (2003). The benefits of economic freedom: A survey. The Independent Review 8(2), 193211.Google Scholar
Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. (1982). The Logic of Bureaucratic Conduct: An Economic Analysis of Competition, Exchange, and Efficiency in Private and Public Organizations. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. (1986). The bureaucracy of murder revisited. Journal of Political Economy 94(5), 905926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, A.C. and Trivedi, P.K. (1998). Regression Analysis of Count Data. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cebula, R.J. and Toma, M.J. (2006). Preliminary evidence on the allocation of U.S. Army deaths from operation Iraqi freedom. Atlantic Economic Journal 34(1), 314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conte, N. (2023). Who's still buying Russian fossil fuels in 2023? Visual Capitalist, July 6.Google Scholar
Crisp, A.M. and Mixon, F.G. Jr. (2011). Lincoln's wartime incumbency network: Vertical trust, informal payments and the presidential election of 1864. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice 29(1–3), 123139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goff, B.L. and Tollison, R.D. (1987). The allocation of death in the Vietnam War: A public choice perspective. Southern Economic Journal 54(2), 316321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J.D., Holcombe, R.G. and Lawson, R.A. (2004). Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth. The Cato Journal 24(3), 205233.Google Scholar
Hebert, D. and Krasnozhon, L. (2024). Public choice economics of the Ukraine crisis. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice 39(1), 5974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, A. (2021). The non-Jihadi foreign fighters: Western right-wing and left-wing extremists in Syria. Terrorism and Political Violence 33(4), 669696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A.O. (1974). The political economy of the rent seeking society. American Economic Review 64(3), 291303.Google Scholar
Krueger, A.B. (2006). The National Origins of Foreign Fighters in Iraq. National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Leeson, P.T. and Dean, A.M. (2009). The democratic domino theory: An empirical investigation. American Journal of Political Science 53(3), 533551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, P.T., Sobel, R.S. and Dean, A.M. (2012). Comparing the spread of capitalism and democracy. Economics Letters 114(1), 139141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mixon, F.G. Jr. (2013). The allocation of death in the Afghanistan War: An international public choice perspective. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice 31(1–3), 2141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mixon, F.G. Jr. (2015). Public Choice Economics and the Salem Witchcraft Hysteria, New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mixon, F.G. Jr. and Treviño, L.J. (2002). Politicians as utility maximizing agents: Public choice and the British National Election of 1945. International Journal of Social Economics 29(12), 956962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pokalova, E. (2019). Driving factors behind foreign fighters in Syria and Iraq. Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 42(9), 798818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, R.A. (1975). The social costs of monopoly and regulation. Journal of Political Economy 83(4), 807827.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seddon, M., Ivanova, P. and Minder, R. (2023). Vladimir Putin says Wagner paramilitaries paid billions by Russian State. Financial Times, June 27.Google Scholar
Stroup, M.D. (1998). Some evidence of congressional political markets in DoD personnel allocations across states. Public Choice 94(3/4), 241254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trantidis, A. (2024). Introducing public choice in international relations: The Russian invasion of Ukraine. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice 39(1), 7590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trevelyan, M. (2024). Putin offers citizenship to foreigners who fight for Russia. Reuters, January 4.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal 5(3), 224232.Google Scholar
Zerkle, A.M. (2009). Measuring and Detecting Political Forces. Doctoral dissertation, Clemson University.Google Scholar
Zinets, N. and Vasovic, A. (2022). Missiles rain down on Ukraine. Reuters.com.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Variable descriptions and summary statistics

Figure 1

Table 2. Poisson regression results

Figure 2

Table 3. Negative binomial regression results

Figure 3

Table A1. Countries included in the empirical analyses

Figure 4

Table A2. Foreign fighter deaths by country of origin