Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T14:56:38.196Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Immigration, skill acquisition, and fiscal redistribution in a search equilibrium model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 February 2023

Bright Isaac Ikhenaode*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Law, Sapienza University of Rome, Rome, Italy
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

As recent immigration flows are reshaping the host countries workforce composition, this paper aims to assess whether age composition and skill adjustment dynamics play a relevant role in the welfare impact of immigration. To this end, we build and simulate a search and matching model that allows for endogenous natives’ skill acquisition and intergenerational transfers to analyze the welfare effects of immigration on a selected group of 19 OECD countries. The obtained results are then compared with those obtained under different assumptions on age composition and skill adjustment dynamics. Our comparative statics analysis shows that stronger job creation effects take place when natives adjust their skill in response to immigration. Moreover, taking into account age composition plays a key role in assessing the fiscal impact of immigration, which turns out to be positive when we include intergenerational transfers to retirees and immigration is high-skilled. Finally, we find that our model yields more optimistic welfare effects than standard search models that abstract from skill decision and intergenerational redistribution.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Over the past decades, several developed countries have begun to rise concerns over the continuous growth of international migration flows. Despite the academic literature has so far found limited effects of immigration on native citizens welfare, international migration is now at the heart of public debates and selective migration policies are proliferating worldwide in order to protect national employment and welfare.

Between 2000 and 2017, the increase in the foreign-born population accounted for almost three-quarters of the total population increase in EU/EFTA countries, and for more than one-third of the increase in the USA.Footnote 1 Such demographic changes are reshaping the host countries workforce composition and underline the importance of taking into account intergenerational aspects concerning young and older individuals when assessing for the effects of migration on the host countries. Indeed, as migration flows keep changing the host country labor force composition, younger natives may respond to immigration by upgrading their skills and specializing in different production tasks in the long run. Further, another interesting aspect which is often debated, but rarely taken into account when evaluating the immigration surplus, is that most developed countries are aging, while migration flows are usually characterized by young workers looking for new job opportunities. Given that intergenerational transfers in high-income countries are large, immigrant workers could play a considerable role in alleviating the fiscal burden that aging populations will face in the next decades.

As the stylized facts, described in Section 2, show that immigrants face higher unemployment rate, are on average younger, and are often characterized by different skill levels than natives, this paper aims to contribute to the limited but growing literature regarding the impact of immigration through search and matching models by introducing two major features that characterize the long-run equilibrium. First, we allow young natives that enter the labor market to endogenously adjust their skill in face of migration so that the skill composition of the migration flows affects natives education decisions in the long run. Second, we distinguish between young and retired workers, who receive different public transfers according to their age, skill, and origin. This feature allows us to better assess the fiscal impact of migration, as natives and immigrants are characterized by different shares of retirees and social welfare usage. It is also worth to point out that the choice of a search and matching model is instrumental for addressing these two key aspects. Indeed, natives’ skill adjustment may play a relevant role in mitigating the unemployment risks deriving from a fiercer competition in the labor market. Moreover, the government spending on unemployment benefits is a relevant component of a country’s fiscal balance, implying that differences in workers’ unemployment risks affect the redistributive effect of immigration. To the best of our knowledge, no previous paper has developed a theoretical model able to analyze long-run effects of migration on native welfare by taking into account unemployment issues, endogenous skill acquirement, and fiscal redistribution among different generations.Footnote 2

Focusing on a selected group of 19 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries, we calibrate and simulate the search model under 3 different scenarios: (a) an increase in low-skilled migration equal to 1% of the total labor force; (b) an increase of the same size of high-skilled migration; and (c) an increase of the same size of immigrants, keeping their skill composition constant. The obtained results are then compared to the cases in which the natives skill is exogenous and/or the retired population is not taken into account. Our quantitative analysis generates the following main results. First, we find that when skill acquisition is endogenous, skill-biased immigration generates stronger job creation effects in the sector that is not directly affected by the arrival of new immigrants. Second, taking into account the age composition of the population plays a key role in determining the fiscal impact of immigration. In particular, our simulations show that the fiscal impact of high-skilled immigration is positive for the aggregate group of the selected countries when we distinguish between active and retired workers in the economy. Conversely, when abstracting from retired individuals, the fiscal impact of immigration is found to be more pessimistic as well as negative for all of the three analyzed scenarios. Third, in almost all of the considered countries, incorporating endogenous natives skill acquisition and age composition yields more optimistic welfare results than a standard search model that neglects both of these features. In particular, under our model, we find that skill-balanced and high-skilled migration shocks increase the average native welfare on most countries, while low-skilled immigration is found to be beneficial to native welfare on 7 out of the 19 considered OECD countries.

This study is related to at least three strands of literature. First, it is related to the stream of literature that focuses on the effect of migration on the natives skill composition and specialization. While most of this literature is empirical and finds mixed results on the effects on natives high school completion rate [see, e.g., Betts (Reference Betts and Betts1998) and Hunt (Reference Hunt2012)], a number of papers have recently focused on the immigration effects on natives task specialization. These latter studies include Peri and Sparber (Reference Peri and Sparber2009, Reference Peri and Sparber2011) and D’Amuri and Peri (Reference D’Amuri and Peri2014) who, by analyzing whether native workers move to more complex jobs as a consequence of immigration, find that natives may respond to immigration by changing their specialization. Cattaneo et al. (Reference Cattaneo, Fiorio and Peri2013) find that native Europeans are more likely to upgrade to more skilled and better paid occupations when a larger number of immigrants enter their labor market. McHenry (Reference McHenry2015) finds that low-skilled immigration induces natives to improve their performance in school, attain more years of schooling, and take jobs that involve communication-intensive tasks, potentially mitigating the negative effects of immigration on the labor market. Llull (Reference Llull2018) builds and estimates a labor market equilibrium dynamic model on USA and finds heterogeneous reactions to immigration, as some natives decide to switch to white-collar careers and increase education, whereas others reduce labor market attachment as well as their education. Similarly, Brunello et al. (Reference Brunello, Lodigiani and Rocco2020) show that immigration in Italy has increased both the probability that young native high school graduates attain higher education and the probability that young natives with less than high school education stay out of further education or training.

Second, this paper is related to the recent stream of the migration literature that analyzes the impacts of immigration through a framework that allows for labor market search frictions. This literature includes Ortega (Reference Ortega2000), Liu (Reference Liu2010), Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2013, Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014), Chassamboulli and Peri (Reference Chassamboulli and Peri2015), Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Palivos and Zhang2017), Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), and Ikhenaode and Parello (Reference Ikhenaode and Parello2020). In particular, our paper is closely related to Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), who employ a setup with search and matching frictions in order to assess the welfare effects of immigration on 20 OECD countries. Their quantitative analysis suggests that immigration attenuates the effects of search frictions by boosting firms’ profits and generating a job creation effect which, in turn, offsets the welfare costs of fiscal redistribution. However, as pointed out by these authors, their analysis abstracts from intergenerational transfers and population aging so that the fiscal effect of migration could differently impact the government balance and welfare. Moreover, they assume that all workers’ skill level is exogenous so that their analysis does not allow natives to update their skill in response of skill-biased migration shocks.

Last, our paper also relates to that strand of the migration literature that focuses on the fiscal effects of immigration. Storesletten (Reference Storesletten2000, Reference Storesletten2003) finds that new immigrants represent, on average, a positive gain for the fiscal balances of USA and Sweden. Dustmann and Frattini (Reference Dustmann and Frattini2014) find a noticeable positive fiscal contribution from recent immigrants, especially those originating from European Economic Area countries. However, aside from Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), this literature mainly focuses on accounting approaches that involve in computing the net fiscal contribution of different population groups in greater detail, while usually abstracting from labor market interactions between migrant and native workers and the equilibrium responses of the economy.Footnote 3

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides stylized facts on labor market characteristics and population composition of the 19 analyzed OECD countries. Section 3 introduces the benchmark version of the model and characterizes the search equilibrium. Section 4 describes the calibration procedure used to simulate the model and discusses the results. Finally, Section 5 offers some concluding remarks.

2. Stylized facts

In OECD countries, 127 million people were foreign-born in 2017, which represents an average of 13% of the total population compared with 9.5% in 2000.Footnote 4 To provide some key stylized facts, as well as to perform our simulation exercises later in the paper, we use the Database on Immigrants in OECD countries (DIOC) for the census round 2010 described by Arslan et al. (Reference Arslan, Dumont, Kone, Moullan, Ozden, Parsons and Xenogiani2014), which allows us to account for differences in demographic characteristics, level of education, and labor market status of the population of the 19 selected OECD countries. This database is a compilation of original data on migrant stocks from a large number of destination countries which provides detailed information on the country of origin, demographic characteristics, level of education, and labor market outcomes of the population of OECD member states. For the purpose of the analysis undertaken in the paper, we extract information about the country of origin (native- or foreign-born), age (25–64 or 65 years and over), educational attainment (college graduates or less educated), and labor market status (employed, unemployed, or inactive) of the individuals residing in each of the considered OECD countries (the 15 members of the European Union, Australia, Canada, Switzerland, and USA).

Figure 1 below shows age composition, labor market status, education level, and labor income of immigrant and native residents in the analyzed countries. Each of the presented stylized facts serves the purpose of underlining relevant differences between immigrants and natives in the demographics and labor market characteristics of the considered OECD countries. In turn, these differences rise questions related to the fiscal, labor market, and welfare effects of immigration and provide motivations for our model to take into account a number of key aspects.

Figure 1. Labor market and population characteristics across countries.

Note: Figure 1 shows population characteristics for the 19 selected countries—reference year 2010.

Figure 1(a) compares the share of elderly natives (aged 65 years and over) in total native population with the share of elderly immigrants over the total immigrant population in each country. Coherently with the empirical evidence that immigrant flows are characterized by younger individuals [OECD (2014)], the average share of older natives in the considered 19 countries is almost twice as large as the share of older immigrants (19.1% for natives vs. 10.9% for immigrants). Countries with a long history of immigration flows, such as Canada and Australia, tend to have a narrower (and/or even negative) gap between the elderly shares of natives and immigrants. Conversely, in countries where immigration is a relatively new phenomenon, such as Italy and Spain, the difference in the two shares is quite large (e.g., in Italy the share of older natives is almost five times as large as the share of older immigrants). This represents a relevant aspect to underline, because the dependency ratio plays a key role in the fiscal effect of immigration which, in turn, affects natives’ welfare.

Figure 1(b) shows that, on average, immigrants suffer from a higher unemployment rate (12.9% for immigrants vs. 9.7% for natives). In particular, 16 out of 19 countries (all but Ireland, USA, and Canada) are characterized by a higher unemployment rate for immigrant workers, though the correlation between immigrant and native unemployment is extremely high (91.3%). It is noteworthy that in some countries, the difference in unemployment rates is quite substantial. In Spain, immigrant workers face an unemployment rate almost 10% points higher than natives, while in Austria, Netherlands, and Sweden the migrant unemployment rate is more than twice as high as the native one. These figures are in line with the hypothesis that native workers may be able to avoid fiercer competition and face lower unemployment risks by upgrading their skill as a response to new immigrant workers in the labor market.

As far as skill composition is concerned, Figure 1(c) illustrates the share of immigrant and native workers with at least 1 year of college education or a bachelor’s degree (ISCED 5). Despite the correlation between native- and foreign-born is high (65.7%) and, on average, immigrants and natives have a similar share of college-educated workers (33% for immigrants and 35.4% for natives), some countries still present a sharp difference in skill composition between the immigrant and native workers—particularly in Belgium, where the share of college-educated natives is almost twice as high as that of college-educated immigrants. These figures place further emphasis on the skill composition aspect and it shows that, even though the aggregate group of countries is characterized by a similar share of college-educated workers for immigrants and natives, the share of college-educated natives is much higher than that of college-educated immigrants in most European countries. This implies that immigration flows are far from skill-balanced for most countries and that, for this reason, new immigrants may indeed induce natives to upgrade their skill to mitigate the competition in the labor market.

Finally, statistics on native/immigrant wage ratios are obtained from Docquier et al. (Reference Docquier, Ozden and Peri2014) and shown in Figure 1(d).Footnote 5 The average native/immigrant wage ratio in the 19 considered countries is 1.04, implying the presence of a slight native wage premium. Multiple determinants may influence the native wage premium, such as imperfect transferability of human capital [Poutvaara (Reference Poutvaara2008)], discrimination [Bartolucci (Reference Bartolucci2014)], different outside options [Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014) and Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018)], or imperfect substituability in production [Manacorda et al. (Reference Manacorda, Manning and Wadsworth2012) and Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012)]. In Section 3, we follow Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012) and use a standard nested Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function, thus interpreting this stylized fact as a result of imperfect substituability in production between immigrant and native workers.Footnote 6

Before moving to the next section, it is interesting to point out that some puzzling aspects emerge by computing the correlations between some of the key indicators described in the stylized facts. First, the correlation between the unemployment rate of natives and the share of college-educated immigrants is negative, but rather close to zero (i.e., equal to −9.4%). This is at odds with the empirical findings that high-skilled migration raises native employment and reduces job destruction [see, e.g., Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018) and Orrenius et al. (Reference Orrenius, Zavodny and Abraham2020)]. Second, the correlation between the unemployment rate of natives and the share of immigrants aged 65 years and over turns out to be negative (−36.5%), which contradicts the economic intuition that the labor market outcomes of native workers improve when immigrants are younger, rather than older. Third, there is a negative correlation (−34.1%) between immigrant workers, as a share of total active population, and the native/immigrant wage ratio. This is also at odds with the literature, as migration is found to primarily reduce the wage of immigrant workers, with little to no effect on the wages of native workers [see, e.g., Manacorda et al. (Reference Manacorda, Manning and Wadsworth2012), Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012), D’Amuri and Peri (Reference D’Amuri and Peri2014), and Dustmann and Frattini (Reference Dustmann and Frattini2014)]. Nonetheless, these correlations can hardly be used as a meaningful inference tool in this instance. Indeed, unemployment rates and wage rates across the different considered countries are influenced by a multitude of factors, including differences in the labor market structures and redistributive institutions. Because it is crucial to take into account the interplay between the different economic channels that take place in the economy, in the next section, we develop a theoretical model able to analyze the complex interaction among unemployment issues, wage setting dynamics, skill upgrade decision, and intergenerational fiscal redistribution. The model described in the next section will then be calibrated to match all of the described stylized facts as closely as possible and to shed some light on the different mechanisms at play in the considered economies.

3. The model

Consider a small open economy populated by a continuum of risk-neutral agents, who discount the future at a constant rate $r\gt 0$ and are heterogeneous under three respects. First, agents differ in their origin country so that they can either be native- or foeign-born individuals who immigrated in the domestic economy. Second, agents are characterized by different education attainments. Following the bulk of the literature that identifies education-based skills [e.g., Card (Reference Card2009), Docquier et al. (Reference Docquier, Ozden and Peri2014), and Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018)], throughout the paper we will refer to college graduates as high-skilled individuals, and to less educated as low-skilled individuals. Third, individuals of all origins are assumed to be either in their working age or retired. Young active individuals supply labor in order to be employed and earn a wage, while retirees are unable (or unwilling) to enter the labor market so that their only income derives from government transfers and capital market. For simplicity, all agents in the economy are assumed to be born and to die at the same rate $\nu$ , whereas the rate at which workers retire in the host country differs between native and immigrant individuals, so to reflect the stylized fact that immigrants and natives are characterized by different shares of retirees.Footnote 7

As far as production is concerned, intermediate firms open vacancies in a frictional labor market in order to hire workers and produce intermediate goods. At the same time, retail firms buy these intermediate goods in order to produce and sell a homogeneous final good in a perfectly competitive market. Finally, the government taxes labor income to finance redistributive transfers, public consumption, and unemployment benefits. For easy of exposition, the time variable $t$ is omitted where no confusion arises.

In Sections 3.1 and 3.2, we describe the production technology and the frictional labor market that characterizes the economy. We then illustrate the skill acquisition process and the government fiscal redistribution in Sections 3.3 and 3.4. Finally, the search equilibrium is characterized in Section 3.5.

3.1. Production

In the small open economy, retail firms employ physical capital $K$ and a composite input good $Z$ in order to produce a homogeneous final output $Y$ , whose price is normalized to unity, according to the following Cobb–Douglas production function:

(1) \begin{equation} Y=A K^{\alpha } Z^{1-\alpha }, \end{equation}

where $A\gt 0$ is a given parameter capturing the level of Total Factor Productivity (TFP) and $\alpha \in (0,1)$ is the share of capital income in total output.

At the same time, the composite input $Z$ is produced by intermediate firms who employ young individuals of heterogeneous skill and origin country. Let $E_{os}$ denote employed workers in the labor market, where the subscript $o=(n,m)$ refers to natives and immigrants, and the subscript $s=(h,l)$ refers to high- and low-skilled individuals. As standard in this strand of literature [see, e.g., Acemoglu (Reference Acemoglu2002)], we assume that each intermediate firm employs at most one worker so that the number of intermediate goods, $Y_{os}$ , and employed workers, $E_{os}$ , coincide in each point in time $t$ . Hence, following recent studies [such as Manacorda et al. (Reference Manacorda, Manning and Wadsworth2012) and Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012)] that find imperfect substituability between native and migrant workers, the production technology used to assemble the composite input $Z$ can be described by the following nested CES function:

(2) \begin{align} Z & =\left [ xY_{h}^{(\sigma _{1}-1)/\sigma _{1}}+(1-x) Y_{l}^{(\sigma _{1}-1)/\sigma _{1}}\right ] ^{\sigma _{1}/\left(\sigma _{1}-1\right)}\nonumber\\Y_{s} & =\left [ \lambda Y_{ns}^{(\sigma _{2}-1)/\sigma _{2}}+(1-\lambda ) Y_{ms}^{(\sigma _{2}-1)/\sigma _{2}}\right ] ^{\sigma _{2}/(\sigma _{2}-1)}, \ s=(h,l), \end{align}

where $\sigma _{1}$ and $\sigma _{2}$ are, respectively, the elasticity of substitution between skill groups and between origin groups, $x \in (0,1)$ denotes the relative productivity of high-skilled compared to low-skilled, and $\lambda \in (0,1)$ denotes the relative productivity of native workers compared to immigrants.

Because intermediate goods are produced under perfect competition, their price $p_{os}$ equals their marginal productivity:

(3a) \begin{align} p_{mh}=A(1-\alpha )x(1-\lambda )K^{\alpha } Z^{\frac{1-\alpha \sigma _1}{\sigma _1}} Y_h^{-\frac{1}{\sigma _1}} \left(\frac{Y_h}{Y_{mh}} \right)^{\frac{1}{\sigma _2}} \end{align}
(3b) \begin{align} p_{ml}=A(1-\alpha )(1-x)(1-\lambda ) K^{\alpha } Z^{\frac{1-\alpha \sigma _1}{\sigma _1}} Y_l^{-\frac{1}{\sigma _1}} \left(\frac{Y_l}{Y_{ml}} \right)^{\frac{1}{\sigma _2}} \end{align}
(3c) \begin{align} p_{nh}=A(1-\alpha )x \lambda K^{\alpha } Z^{\frac{1-\alpha \sigma _1}{\sigma _1}} Y_h^{-\frac{1}{\sigma _1}} \left(\frac{Y_h}{Y_{nh}} \right)^{\frac{1}{\sigma _2}} \end{align}
(3d) \begin{align} p_{nl}=A(1-\alpha )(1-x)\lambda K^{\alpha } Z^{\frac{1-\alpha \sigma _1}{\sigma _1}} Y_l^{-\frac{1}{\sigma _1}} \left(\frac{Y_l}{Y_{nl}} \right)^{\frac{1}{\sigma _2}}. \end{align}

Finally, capital in the economy is free to be perfectly mobile and, because the domestic economy is assumed to be small compared to the outside world, the return on capital $r$ is fixed by international markets. Hence, the total amount of physical capital in the economy will adjust so to satisfy the usual first-order condition:

(4) \begin{equation} r=A \alpha K^{\alpha -1} Z^{1-\alpha }. \end{equation}

3.2. Labor market

Each intermediate firm opens a vacancy for either high-skilled or low-skilled workers. Following Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014) and Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), the labor market is assumed perfectly segmented by skill level for simplicityFootnote 8 and firms are not able to discriminate between immigrant and native workers at the vacancy posting stage so that job vacancies $V_s$ and unemployed individuals $U_s \equiv \sum \limits _o U_{os}$ are randomly matched with each other according to the following Cobb–Douglas matching function:

(5) \begin{equation} M(U_s,V_s)=\xi U_s^{\epsilon } V_s^{1-\epsilon }, s=(h,l), \end{equation}

where $M$ is the number of job matches, $\xi$ is a constant matching efficiency parameter,Footnote 9 and $\epsilon \in (0,1)$ is the elasticity parameter of the matching function.

Let $\theta _s \equiv V_s/U_s$ denote the labor market tightness in the skill sector $s$ . The job-finding rate is given by $M_s/U_s = \xi \theta _s^{1-\epsilon } \equiv m(\theta _s)$ , and the vacancy-filling rate is given by $M_s/V_s = \xi \theta _s^{-\epsilon } \equiv q(\theta _s)$ . As easy to verify, $m(\theta _s)$ and $q(\theta _s)$ are, respectively, increasing and decreasing in $\theta _s$ , implying that a higher market tightness makes it more difficult for firms to fill a vacancy, but easier for unemployed workers to find a job.

3.2.1. Asset value functions

Let $\mathcal{J}_{os}^{F}$ and $\mathcal{J}_s^V$ denote the value associated with a filled and unfilled vacancy, respectively.Footnote 10 Then, their flow value in steady state is given by:

(6) \begin{align} r \mathcal{J}_{os}^{F} &= p_{os} - w_{os} - \left(\delta _{os}+g_o \right) \left [ \mathcal{J}_{os}^{F}-\mathcal{J}_s^V \right ] \end{align}
(7) \begin{align} r \mathcal{J}_s^V &= -c_s+q(\theta _s) \left [ \left(1-\phi _s \right) \mathcal{J}_{ns}^{F} +\phi _s \mathcal{J}_{ms}^{F}-\mathcal{J}_s^V \right ], \end{align}

where $c_s$ is the fixed cost of an open vacancy for a worker of skill level $s$ , $\phi _s \equiv U_{ms}/U_s$ is the share of unemployed immigrants among all searching individuals of skill type $s$ , $g_o$ is the retirement rate for individuals of origin $o$ , and $\delta _{os}$ is the exogenous separation rate, which is allowed to differ for workers’ skills and country origin. Equation (6) states that the asset value of a filled vacancy is given by the price at which the intermediate input is sold, minus the wage rate paid to employed workers, and the expected value of breaking up with an employed worker, multiplied by the probability that such an event occurs, $\delta _{os}+g_o$ .Footnote 11 Equation (7) has a similar interpretation, as it states that the asset value of having an unfilled vacancy is given by the vacancy cost, $-c_s$ , plus the expected value of filling a vacancy, which occurs at a probability $q(\theta _s)$ .

For working-age individuals who supply labor, the steady-state discounted present value of employment, $\mathcal{J}_{os}^{E}$ , and unemployment, $\mathcal{J}_{os}^{U}$ , are given by:

(8) \begin{align} r\mathcal{J}_{os}^{E}&= (1-\tau )w_{os}+\delta _{os}\!\left [ \mathcal{J}_{os}^{U}-\mathcal{J}_{os}^{E}\right ]+g_o \!\left [ \mathcal{J}_{os}^R-\mathcal{J}_{os}^E \right ] +T^y_{os}+r k^y_{os} \end{align}
(9) \begin{align} r\mathcal{J}_{os}^{U}&= b_{os}+m\!\left( \theta _{s}\right) \left [ \mathcal{J}_{os}^{E}-\mathcal{J}_{os}^{U}\right ]+g_o \!\left [ \mathcal{J}_{os}^R-\mathcal{J}_{os}^U \right ]+T^y_{os}+r k^y_{os}, \end{align}

where $\tau$ is the labor income tax rate, $T^y_{os}$ and $r k^y_{os}$ are, respectively, redistributive transfers and capital income of young workers of origin $o$ and skill $s$ ,Footnote 12 and $\mathcal{J}_{os}^R$ is the steady-state value of retirement which is defined later on in the paper. According to equation (8), the flow value of being employed equals the difference between the after-tax wage income and the expected loss from breaking up from the firm, plus transfers, $T^y_{os}$ , capital income, $r k^y_{os}$ , and the expected gain from becoming a retiree, $g_o [ \mathcal{J}_{os}^R-\mathcal{J}_{os}^E ]$ . Likewise, equation (9) states that the flow value of unemployment equals its return, that is, the unemployment benefit $b_{os}$ , plus the probability of finding a job, multiplied by the expected gain from such event, transfers, capital income, and the expected gain from retirement.

Finally, denoting with $R_{os}$ the number of retired workers and $Q_{os}$ the total amount of active workers of type $(o,s)$ , the flow value of being a retired worker in steady state, $\mathcal{J}_{os}^R$ , can be written as:

(10) \begin{equation} r\mathcal{J}_{os}^R= T^R_{os}+r k^R_{os}-\nu \mathcal{J}_{os}^R, \end{equation}

where $T^R_{os}$ are redistributive transfers paid to retired workers and $k^R_{os}$ is the share of capital held by retired workers.

3.2.2. Job creation condition

As intermediate firms are in perfect competition and bare no costs of entry, they will find it profitable to enter the market as long as the value of posting a new vacancy is greater than zero. In steady state, the free entry condition is thus given by:

(11) \begin{equation} \mathcal{J}_{s}^{V}=0. \end{equation}

Combining equations (6), (7), and (11), in steady state, the job creation condition reads:

(12) \begin{equation} \frac{c _{s}}{q\!\left( \theta _{s}\right) }=\left( 1-\phi _{s}\right) \left [ \frac{p_{ns}-w_{ns}}{r+g_n+\delta _{ns}}\right ] +\phi _{s}\!\left [ \frac{p_{ms}-w_{ms}}{r+g_m+\delta _{ms}}\right ]. \end{equation}

Equation (12) states that the expected cost of creating a vacancy, $c_{s}/q ( \theta _{s} )$ , is equal to the expected benefit of filling a vacancy with either a native or immigrant worker, $p_{os}-w_{os}$ , adjusted by the worker-type specific discount rate, $r+g_o+\delta _{os}$ . Note that a higher market tightness $\theta _s$ translates to higher vacancy opening costs, since the waiting time for filling a vacancy is increasing in $\theta _s$ .

3.2.3. Wage determination

Following mainstream search and matching literature, wages are determined through a Nash-bargaining process. The surplus created when a job seeker $U_{os}$ and a vacancy $V_s$ meet leads to a negotiation over the wage rate $w_{os}$ . For the worker accepting a job offer would generate a surplus of $\mathcal{J}_{os}^F - \mathcal{J}_s^V$ , whereas for the firm hiring an additional worker would generate a gain of $\mathcal{J}_{os}^E-\mathcal{J}_{os}^U$ . The outcome of the bargaining process is the wage rate $w_{os}$ that solves the following maximization problem:

\begin{equation*} w_{os}= \mathrm{argmax} \!\left(\mathcal {J}_{os}^E-\mathcal {J}_{os}^U\right)^{\beta }\left( \mathcal {J}_{os}^F - \mathcal {J}_s^V \right)^{1-\beta }, \end{equation*}

where $\beta \in (0,1)$ denotes the worker bargaining power. The first-order maximization condition derived from the above equation satisfies:

(13) \begin{equation} \left( 1-\beta \right) \left( \mathcal{J}_{os}^{E}-\mathcal{J}_{os}^{U}\right) =\beta \!\left( \mathcal{J}_{os}^{F}-\mathcal{J}_{s}^{V}\right). \end{equation}

Combining equation (13) with the asset value equations (6)–(9) and considering the free entry condition (11), the bargained wage rate paid to workers of type $(o,s)$ is given by:

(14) \begin{equation} w_{os}=\frac{\beta \!\left [ r+g_o+\delta _{os}+m\!\left( \theta _{s}\right) \right ] p_{os}}{\left( r+g_o+\delta _{os}\right) \left [ 1-\left( 1-\beta \right) \left( \tau +\mu \right) \right ] +\beta m\!\left( \theta _{s}\right) }, \end{equation}

where the unemployment benefit $b_{os}$ has been endogenized and proportionally set to the wage rate, that is, $b_{os} \equiv \mu w_{os}$ , with $\mu \in (0,1)$ denoting the replacement rate. According to equation (14), higher worker bargaining power $\beta$ translates to higher wage rates. It is also easy to check that the bargained wage rate $w_{os}$ is increasing in the replacement rate $\mu$ . This is coherent with the intuition that higher values of replacement rate would increase the worker’s outside option and, thus, the worker’s surplus from hiring.

3.2.4. Employment and retirement

The dynamic law of employed workers of skill $s$ and origin $o$ is given by the difference between the amount of matches formed and the breakups that take place in a given instant of time $t$ , that is:

(15) \begin{equation} \dot{E}_{os}=m\!\left( \theta _s \right) U_{os}-\left(\delta _{os}+g_o\right) E_{os}. \end{equation}

Similarly, the dynamic law of retired workers of skill $s$ and origin $o$ is given by the difference between the workers who retire and the retirees that die in a given instant of time $t$ , that is:

(16) \begin{equation} \dot{R}_{os}=g_o Q_{os}-\nu R_{os}. \end{equation}

Recalling that $Q_{os} \equiv E_{os}+U_{os}$ is the total amount of active individuals of type $(o,s)$ , the number of employed, unemployed, and retired people in steady state can be written as:

(17) \begin{align} E_{os}& =\frac{m\!\left( \theta _{s}\right) Q_{os}}{\delta _{os}+g_o+m\!\left(\theta _{s}\right) } \end{align}
(18) \begin{align} U_{os}& =\frac{\left(\delta _{os}+g_o\right)Q_{os}}{\delta _{os}+g_o+m\!\left( \theta _{s}\right) } \end{align}
(19) \begin{align} R_{os}& =\frac{g_o}{\nu }Q_{os}. \end{align}

Based on equations (17) and (18), for any given size of the active population $Q_{os}$ , employment is increasing in the job-finding probability, $m(\theta _s)$ , and decreasing in the separation rate, $\delta _{os}$ . Also note that, according to equation (19), an in increase in active population translates to more retirees in the steady state. It is worth pointing out that, because immigrants and natives have different retirement rates, a variation in the quantity of active workers type $o$ is able to affect the host country dependency ratio $\sum \limits _{o} \sum \limits _{s} (R_{os}/Q_{os})$ .

3.3. Skill acquisition

Before entering the labor market, each young native individual decides whether to invest in education and become high-skilled or remain low-skilled.Footnote 13 Following Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014), agents differ in their cost of acquiring education and, in particular, older agents are assumed to face prohibitive costs that prevent them from investing in training. Let $z$ denote the cost of acquiring training and assume for simplicity that it is distributed uniformly over the closed interval $[0,\bar{z}]$ . A native young agent will invest in education if the benefit of looking for a job as high-skilled, rather than as low-skilled, exceeds the cost of acquiring training, that is,

(20) \begin{equation} \mathcal{J}_{nh}^U-\mathcal{J}_{nl}^U \geq z. \end{equation}

Setting (20) as an equality, there exists a threshold value for the training cost:

(21) \begin{equation} z^*=\mathcal{J}_{nh}^U-\mathcal{J}_{nl}^U, \end{equation}

such that agents will find it profitable to invest in education and become high-skilled. From equation (20), it follows that the fraction of native high-skilled workers, $\gamma \equiv Q_{nh}/(Q_{nh}+Q_{nl})$ , is thus endogenously determined by the model and equals:

(22) \begin{equation} \gamma = \frac{z^*}{\bar{z}}. \end{equation}

Plugging equation (9) into (20), and then using equation (8), the steady-state share of native high-skilled workers $\gamma$ reads:

(23) \begin{equation} \gamma =\frac{\mu \!\left( w_{nh}-w_{nl} \right)+T^y_{nh}-T^y_{nl}+ m\!\left( \theta _h \right)\left [ \dfrac{w_{nh}(1-\tau -\mu )}{r+g_n+\delta _{nh}+ m\!\left( \theta _h \right)} \right ]- m\!\left( \theta _l \right)\left [ \dfrac{w_{nl}(1-\tau -\mu )}{r+g_n+\delta _{nl}+ m\!\left( \theta _l \right)} \right ]}{\bar{z} \!\left( r+g_n\right)}. \end{equation}

According to equation (23), the higher is the benefit of being a high-skilled worker, rather than low-skilled worker, the larger will be the share of young natives that decide to invest in education. It is worth noting that, since young individuals eventually age and become retired, a change in young natives skill composition implies a change in retired skill composition as well so that the ratio $R_{nh}/R_{nl}$ always matches the ratio $Q_{nh}/Q_{nl}$ in the steady state.

3.4. Government

The government imposes a fixed tax rate $\tau \in (0,1)$ on labor income in order to finance unemployment benefits $\mu w_{os}$ , and group-specific transfers $T^a_{os}$ , where the superscript $a=(y,R)$ denotes young and retired individuals. Assuming that the government conducts a zero-profit policy, the government budget constraint writes

(24) \begin{equation} \tau \sum \limits _{o}\sum \limits _{s}E_{os} w_{os} =\mu \sum \limits _{o}\sum \limits _{s}U_{os}w_{os}+\sum \limits _{o}\sum \limits _{s}Q_{os}T^y_{os}+\sum \limits _{o}\sum \limits _{s}R_{os}T^R_{os}. \end{equation}

The left-hand side of equation (24) corresponds to the government revenues, whereas the right-hand side corresponds to the government expenditures. The income tax $\tau$ is assumed to endogenously adjust to balance the government budget so that when a temporary deficit (surplus) takes place, the government responses by raising (decreasing) $\tau$ . It is also worth pointing out that, since labor income is the only source of tax revenues for the government, both native and immigrant employed workers contribute to the fiscal balance as a percentage of their labor income, whereas retirees and unemployed workers do not contribute to the government revenues.

3.5. Search equilibrium

Definition 1. A steady-state equilibrium is a set of equilibrium values $\{p_{os}, K, \theta _s, w_{os}, E_{os}, U_{os}, \gamma, \tau \}$ , where $o=(n,m)$ and $s=(h,l)$ , such that: (i) the intermediate inputs markets clear so that equations (3a)–(3d) are satisfied; (ii) capital markets clear so that equation (4) is satisfied; (iii) the job creation condition (12) for each skill type $s$ is satisfied; (iv) the Nash-bargaining optimality condition (14) holds for each origin $o$ and skill type $s$ ; (v) the numbers of employed, unemployed, and retired workers are given by equations (17), (18), and (19) for each origin $o$ and skill type $s$ ; (vi) the skill acquisition condition (23) is satisfied; and (vii) the government sustains a no-deficit policy and its budget (24) is balanced.

Unfortunately, it is impossible to obtain closed-form equilibrium solutions and the complexity of the model makes it too burdensome to provide analytical results on the welfare effect of immigration. For this reason, in the next section we will perform a comparative statics analysis by first assigning specific values to the model parameters and then solving the model numerically.

4. Quantitative analysis

In this section, we assess the impact of immigration on welfare, labor market outcomes, and fiscal redistribution in 19 selected OECD countries through a comparative statics analysis. More specifically, we analyze both the cases of skill-biased and -unbiased migration shocks taking place in the described economy. Throughout the analysis, we will refer to the welfare level of natives by taking into account the following welfare index:Footnote 14

(25) \begin{equation} \mathcal{W}_{n}\equiv \frac{(1-\tau )\sum \limits _s E_{ns}w_{ns}+\mu \sum \limits _s U_{ns} w_{ns}-\frac{z^* (r+g_n)}{2}Q_{nh}+\sum \limits _s Q_{ns} T_{ns}^y+\sum \limits _s R_{ns} T_{ns}^R+r K_n}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}, \end{equation}

where $K_n \equiv \sum \limits _s \sum \limits _a k^a_{ns}$ is the total amount of capital held by natives and $\frac{z^*}{2}$ is the discounted (endogenous) average cost of acquiring skill.Footnote 15 The welfare index $\mathcal{W}_{n}$ includes the flow values of native labor income, capital income, unemployment benefits, transfers, and cost for training.Footnote 16

The remainder of this section is presented as follows. Section 4.1 explains the calibration strategy for the benchmark model. Section 4.2 shows the results obtained and compares them with different variations of the model. Finally, Section 4.3 provides a robustness check on the results to the parameters choice.

4.1. Parametrization

We parametrize the described model in order to match the economic and sociodemographic characteristics of 19 OECD countries (EU15 member states, Australia, Canada, Switzerland, and USA). The model includes a total of 33 exogenous parameters which need to be calibrated in order to perform a quantitative analysis. Most of these parameters vary across countries and are set to match moments taken from data, while some are assumed to be country-invariant and taken from the empirical literature.

4.1.1. Calibration of common parameters

Table 1 reports exogenous parameters without country variation. We set the capital share parameter $\alpha =0.33$ to match the empirical evidence of Gollin (Reference Gollin2002). Following Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012), we choose the elasticity of substitution between skill groups and origin groups of, respectively, $\sigma _1 =2$ and $\sigma _2 =20$ . In line with Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014) and Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), the monthly interest rate $r$ is set to $0.4\%$ . Further, we choose the matching elasticity parameter $\epsilon =0.5$ , which is within the range of estimates reported in Petrongolo and Pissarides (Reference Petrongolo and Pissarides2001) and Mortensen and Nagypal (Reference Mortensen and Nagypal2007), and the bargaining power $\beta =0.5$ , so that the Hosios condition is met [see Hosios (Reference Hosios1990)]. Finally, we normalize the low-skilled vacancy cost $c_l$ to the same value adopted in Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018).Footnote 17

Table 1. Parameters without country variation

4.1.2. Calibration of country-specific parameters

Exogenous parameters varying across countries are listed in Table 2. The TFP parameter $A$ is set to match the TFP levels at current PPPs from the Penn World Table 10 database for each of the considred OECD countries. The matching efficiency parameter $\xi$ is instead set to match the monthly job-finding rates reported by Hobijn and Şahin (Reference Hobijn and Şahin2009) for each country.Footnote 18 Further, the parameter $x$ is calibrated to match the average return to skill $w_h/w_l$ according to the Education at Glance 2012 report of the OECD (2012), whereas $\lambda$ is calibrated to match the average native wage premium $w_n/w_m$ obtained from Docquier et al. (Reference Docquier, Ozden and Peri2014). The separation rates $\delta _{os}$ are set to match the unemployment rates observed in the DIOC data. Specifically, separation rates are calibrated to be, on average, larger for migrants than for natives, since migrant workers are generally characterized by a higher unemployment rate. The vacancy costs ratio $c_h/ c_l$ is set equal to the wage ratio $w_h/w_l$ , implying that it is more costly to have a high-skilled unfilled vacancy, rather than a low-skilled one, proportionately to the education wage premium.Footnote 19 The upper bound parameter related to the cost of acquiring education, $\bar{z}$ , is set in order to match the share of high-skilled natives provided by DIOC data.

Table 2. Parameters varying across countries

As far as fiscal parameters are concerned, the replacement rate $\mu$ matches the share of unemployment benefits in GDP obtained from the Annual National Accounts harmonized by the OECD. In line with Burzynski et al. (Reference Burzynski, Docquier and Rapoport2018) and Aubry et al. (Reference Aubry, Burzynski and Docquier2016), we calibrate the level of public transfers to each cohort so to match the government expenditure to GDP, taken from the OECD Annual National Accounts, as well as the data on social protection expenditures included in the Social Expenditure Database (SOCX) of the OECD. More precisely, the SOCX database includes internationally comparable statistics on public social expenditures at the program level as well as net social spending indicators. We extract the data on expenditures linked to pension benefits, sickness and disability, family and children transfers as well as other transfers, as percentage of total social protection expenditures. Next, we disaggregate education expenditures and all social protection expenditures by education, age, and origin using the European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC) provided by Eurostat for European countries, and the fiscal profiles used in Chojnicki et al. (Reference Chojnicki, Docquier and Ragot2011) for the USA, Canada, and Australia. We then extract personal characteristics, data on social benefits, and the sampling weight of each individual. The amount of benefits received by each individual type $({a,o,s})$ is then computed and rescaled to match the aggregate level obtained from the SOCX database.

Finally, we normalize the total young native workers population to one and parametrize the number of young immigrants by skill ( $Q_{mh}$ and $Q_{ml}$ ) according to the DIOC data on active individuals of age 25–64 years by origin. The retirement rates $g_n$ and $g_m$ are set in order to match the shares of total individuals of age 65 years and over by origin $\Big(R_n \equiv \sum \limits _s R_{ns} \text { and } R_m \equiv \sum \limits _s R_{ms}\Big)$ , while the birth rate $\nu$ is calibrated to match the monthly growth rate of the labor force during the period 2002–2010 in the analyzed OECD countries.

Using this calibration, in the following section, we simulate marginal increases in different types of migration flows taking as reference the described moments as the status quo.Footnote 20

4.2. Sensitivity to different specifications

In this section, we simulate a 1% increase in the labor force due to an increase in the stock of immigrant workers.Footnote 21 As many developed countries are moving towards more selective migration policies in order to attract highly educated workers, and the skill composition of the migration flows plays a key role for determining welfare effects [Borjas (Reference Borjas2003) and Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012)], in the analysis we consider three different types of one-off migration shocks: (a) a shock of low-skilled immigrant workers ( $Q_{ml}$ ); (b) a shock of high-skilled immigrant workers ( $Q_{mh}$ ); and (c) a shock of low- and high-skilled immigrant workers such that the immigrants’ skill composition does not change in the post-shock scenario (henceforth, we will refer to this scenario as the “skill-balanced” migration shock). Table 3 summarizes the description of the three different immigration shocks taken into account in this subsection.

Table 3. Immigration shock scenarios

Our main goal is to analyze the effects of immigration on native welfare and to assess to what extent taking into account natives’ endogenous skill and age composition matters in such analysis. For this reason, we also compare the results obtained by the benchmark version of the model described in Section 3 with those obtained in three other models that differ for the following elements: (i) the economy is composed of only working-age individuals, that is $R_{os}\equiv 0$ for each agent type $(o,s)$ (henceforth referred as Model 2); (ii) young natives never adjust their skill in response to migration, that is $\gamma$ is exogenous (henceforth referred as Model 3); and (iii) there are no retirees in the economy and young natives never adjust their skill, that is $R_{os}\equiv 0$ and $\gamma$ is exogenous (henceforth referred as Model 4).

In what follows, we will first present the simulation results over the selected OECD countries and provide welfare comparisons across different model variations. Then, we will shed some light on the mechanisms in action by decomposing the observed welfare effects into different transmission channels.

4.2.1. The welfare effects of immigration

Figure 2 describes the effects of immigration on native welfare in the selected 19 OECD countries. In particular, Figure 2(a) shows the average welfare effects of low-skilled, high-skilled, and skill-balanced immigration on the aggregate group of the selected OECD countries, weighted for their native population size (which includes retirees for the benchmark model and Model 3, but only working-age active natives for Models 2 and 4) in order to account for the differences in countries size. The welfare effect on immigration is on average quite modest under the benchmark model, as it ranges from −0.08% (low-skilled immigration scenario) to 0.18% (high-skilled immigration scenario). The model versions abstracting from the presence of retirees (i.e., Model 2 and Model 4) are the most pessimistic ones under all of the three analyzed scenarios (especially Model 2, which ranges from −0.21% in the low-skilled immigration scenario to 0.06% in the high-skilled scenario). These are also the model versions that differ the most from the benchmark model, implying that taking into account the age structure of immigrants and natives plays an important role in the evaluation of the welfare effects of immigration. As far as the introduction of endogenous skill adjustment is concerned, the model version that differs from the benchmark for the only absence of native skill adjustment (i.e., Model 3) yields slightly more pessimistic results in the low-skilled scenario (average native welfare decreases by 0.12%), but more optimistic results in the high-skilled scenario (average native welfare increases by 0.25%) when compared with the benchmark model. In the skill-balanced scenario, both the benchmark model and Model 3 yield negligible effects on the average native welfare of the aggregate group of the considered OECD countries (average native welfare increases by less than 0.01% in both model versions).

Figure 2. Effects of immigration (1% of the total labor force) on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 2(b)–(d) show the effects of the three immigration shocks—low-skilled, high-skilled, and skill-balanced immigration—by country. According to our benchmark model, the countries that benefit the most from migration in all of the three scenarios are those characterized by a share of elderly immigrants that is much lower than the share of elderly natives (cfr. Figure 1(a) in Section 2). Unsurprisingly, the high-skilled immigration scenario is the more optimistic one for most countries (under the benchmark model, native welfare increases in all countries but Sweden, Denmark, and France). The skill-balanced immigration scenario also improves native welfare on most countries (14 out of 19 under the benchmark model). On the contrary, the low-skilled immigration scenario is the most pessimistic one for most countries (natives benefit from low-skilled immigration only in 7 out of 19 countries under the benchmark model).

4.2.2. Welfare effect decomposition

To shed light on the mechanisms at work behind the simulations results we presented, we decompose the average welfare effect into different transmission channels: employment, gross wage, fiscal, capital, education cost, and residual effect channels. Indeed, using equation (25), variations in native welfare can be decomposed as:

\begin{equation*} \Delta \mathcal {W}_n= \sum \limits _s \left. \Delta \mathcal {W}_n\right |_{\text{empl}_s}+\sum \limits _s \left. \Delta \mathcal {W}_n\right |_{\text{wage}_s}+\left. \Delta \mathcal {W}_n\right |_{\text{fiscal}}+\left. \Delta \mathcal {W}_n\right |_{\text{capital}}+\left. \Delta \mathcal {W}_n\right |_{\text{educ}}+\left. \Delta \mathcal {W}_n\right |_{\text{resid}}, \end{equation*}

where

\begin{align*} &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}_n\right |_{\text{empl}_s} \equiv \frac{\left( 1-\tau \right) \left(\Delta E_{ns} \right) w_{ns}+\mu \!\left(\Delta U_{ns} \right) w_{ns}}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}\\ &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}_n\right |_{\text{wage}_s} \equiv \frac{ \left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \Delta w_{ns} \right) E_{ns} +\mu \!\left( \Delta w_{ns} \right) U_{ns}}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}\\ &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}_n\right |_{\text{fiscal}} \equiv -\frac{\Delta \tau \sum \limits _s E_{ns} w_{ns}}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}\\ &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}_n\right |_{\text{capital}} \equiv \frac{r \sum \limits _s \sum \limits _a \Delta k^a_{ns}}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}\\ &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}_n\right |_{\text{educ}} \equiv -\frac{\left( r+g_n\right) \left [ \left( \Delta z^* \right) Q_{nh} + \left( \Delta Q_{nh} \right) z^* \right ] }{2 \sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)} \\ &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}_n\right |_{\text{resid}} \equiv \frac{ \sum \limits _s \!\left( \Delta Q_{ns} \right) T^y_{ns} + \sum \limits _s \!\left( \Delta R_{ns} \right) T^R_{ns} }{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}. \end{align*}

Figure 3 gives the weighted mean averages of the labor market-related welfare components (employment and wage transmission channels by skill), whereas Figure 4 gives the weighted mean averages of the other transmission channels (fiscal, capital, education, and residual).Footnote 22 For the sake of comparability, in all of these figures, we use the same vertical scale.

Figure 3. Decomposition of the average welfare effect of immigration (1% of the total labor force) — employment and wage channels.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Figure 4. Decomposition of the average welfare effect of immigration (1% of the total labor force) — fiscal, capital, education, and residual channels.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Figure 3(a) and (b) show that when natives endogenously decide whether to invest in education (i.e., in Benchmark and Model 2), the employment transmission channel contributes to welfare variations in a meaningful way only in case of skill-biased immigration. In particular, endogenous skill adjustment asymmetrically amplify the job creation effects for low- and high-skilled jobs so that there is a positive job creation effect for natives employed in the skill sector that is not directly affected by the immigration shock, but a negative job creation effect for those natives working in the same skill sector of the new immigrants. This is because, in case of low-skilled (high-skilled) immigration, more natives will find it profitable to (to not) invest in education and apply for high-skilled (low-skilled) positions, so to avoid a fiercer competition from the new immigrants in the low-skilled (high-skilled) sector. As a result, the welfare effect contribution due to the presence of high-skilled (low-skilled) workers increases, whereas that of low-skilled (high-skilled) workers decreases. This same mechanism does not operate in those model versions where natives are not allowed to upgrade their skill in face of migration. Indeed, in Models 3 and 4, the employment effect only depends on the market tightness, which results to not be particularly sensible to immigration shocks. As a consequence, the employment transmission channel does not significantly contribute to variations in native welfare under Models 3 and 4.

Figure 3(c) and (d) illustrate the contribution of the wage transmission channel on the obtained welfare results. Interestingly, this channel is not particularly sensitive to differences in the model versions. Indeed, wage variations are mainly driven by complementarity effects in production between low- and high-skilled workers: an increase of low-skilled (high-skilled) migrant employment makes marginal productivity of high-skilled (low-skilled) workers increase, leading to a higher high-skilled (low-skilled) labor income. This holds true regardless of the considered model version, as they all share the same production function structure.

As far as the direct fiscal contribution of the immigration shocks is concerned, Figure 4(a) gives noticeably less pessimistic results when retired workers are included in the model (i.e., in Benchmark and Model 3). In particular, the fiscal contribution in the high-skilled immigration scenario turns positive, while the negative fiscal effect of low-skilled and skill-balanced immigration shrinks with the introduction of retirees in the model. This is because retirees tend to be a weighty fiscal burden (retired workers have access to pension benefits and stop contributing to the fiscal revenues as they leave the labor market) and, at the same time, immigrants in the host countries are, on average, characterized by a lower share of retirees. Furthermore, the result that high-skilled and low-skilled immigration have different fiscal impacts is given by the differences in their unemployment rates (high-skilled workers are characterized by a lower unemployment rate, which translates to a lower government expenditure on unemployment benefits) and welfare usage.

Figure 4(b) displays the welfare effect of immigration that takes place through the capital accumulation channel. High-skilled immigration stimulates native capital accumulation, whereas low-skilled immigration hampers native capital accumulation in per capita terms (i.e., the capital dilution effect takes place) across all model variants. Indeed, recalling that the capital accumulation transmission channel takes into account native capital in per capita terms, $\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _a k_{ns}^a \equiv \left(\sum \limits _s Q_{ns} + \sum \limits _s R_{ns}\right)K/\left(\sum \limits _o \sum \limits _s Q_{os} + \sum \limits _o \sum \limits _s R_{os}\right)$ , the resulting effect depends on whether the increase in aggregate capital $K$ is able to offset the increase in the total population $\left(\sum \limits _o \sum \limits _s Q_{os} + \sum \limits _o \sum \limits _s R_{os}\right)$ due to the inflow of new immigrants. As in almost all of the considered countries, the share of low-skilled workers is much higher than that of high-skilled workers, increasing the number of the scarcer and more productive input, that is, the high-skilled workers, leads to a positive complementary effect that is stronger than any capital dilution effect that may take place in the host economy. On the contrary, the complementary effect taking place in response to low-skilled immigration turns out to be unable to counteract the capital dilution effect.

Finally, Figure 4(c) and (d) show the education cost and residual transmission channels, respectively. Both channels are necessarily equal to 0 in the models where natives skill distribution cannot change in response to immigration shocks (Models 3 and 4), as education cost is exogenous and the residual channel depends on the changes on natives skill distribution. Focusing our attention on the benchmark model and Model 2, the results on the education cost channel are quite intuitive: when new low-skilled immigrants enter the labor market, more natives find it profitable to invest in education, making both total and average cost in education increase. In the case of high-skilled immigration, a specularly symmetric scenario takes place, that is, a lower number of natives invest in education, making the education cost decrease. The residual effect is still negligible under both the benchmark model and Model 2, as natives skill adjustment does not noticeably affect the weight of the redistributive transfers on the average native welfare.

4.3. Sensitivity to parameters

As there is empirical disagreement on the degree of substitutability between workers of different skill and origin [see Borjas et al. (Reference Borjas, Grogger and Hanson2012)] and these parameters play a key role for correctly assessing the impact of migration on the host country labor market, here we perform a ceteris paribus sensitivity analysis on the elasticities of substitution between high- and low-skilled workers, $\sigma _1$ , and between native and immigrant workers, $\sigma _2$ . In the benchmark parametrization, following Ottaviano and Peri (Reference Ottaviano and Peri2012), we chose $\sigma _1=2$ and $\sigma _2=20$ . In what follows, we set $\sigma _1=1.5$ and $ \sigma _2=10,000$ to check how robust our benchmark model is when high- and low-skilled workers are more complementary, and when native and immigrant workers can be considered as perfect substitutes (i.e., $\sigma _2\rightarrow \infty$ ). We vary each parameter each time and perform the same skill-biased and skill-balanced immigration shocks we have discussed in the previous sections.

Figure 5 illustrates the sensitivity of the immigration effects on native welfare under different calibrations of the benchmark model. Qualitatively, our results countries are robust to the choice of elasticity parameters when we consider the aggregate group of the selected OECD countries [see Figure 5(a)]. Quantitatively, however, we find that our results are highly robust to $\sigma _1$ , but rather sensitive to $\sigma _2$ . In particular, smaller welfare gains are obtained when immigrants are closer substitutes for native workers. Nonetheless, the countries ranking is barely affected by these parameters choice the all of the three different immigration shock scenarios [see Figure 5(b)–(d)].

Figure 5. Effects of immigration (1% of the total labor force) on 19 selected OECD countries — sensitivity to parameters.

Note: Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

5. Concluding remarks

This paper investigates the effects of immigration on the native welfare by introducing two key features that have been so far mostly neglected in the growing literature of search models. The first feature is related to the recent empirical findings that natives tend to adjust their task specialization in response to immigration. The second feature regards individuals age composition and allows us to assess whether immigrant workers are able to alleviate the fiscal burden of aging populations. Both of these features are taken into account in our search model by endogenizing natives education decisions and by including different generations of workers. We focus our analysis on a selected group of 19 OECD countries (EU15 member states, Australia, Canada, Switzerland, and USA) and perform a comparative statics analysis under different variations of immigration shocks and model versions in order to assess to what extent the introduced features affect welfare results.

Despite the heterogeneity in population and labor market characteristics across countries, our analysis finds the following results for the aggregate group of considered OECD countries. First, the introduction of young natives’ endogenous skill acquisition asymmetrically amplifies any job creation effect generated by skill-biased immigration shocks. This is because young natives decide to specialize and apply in the sector which is less affected by the immigration shock so to avoid a fiercer competition from new immigrants. Second, high-skilled immigration has positive fiscal effects when age composition is taken into account. On the contrary, model variants that abstract from retired workers find negative fiscal effects under all immigration shock scenarios. Third, the features introduced in our benchmark model allow for an overall more optimistic prediction of the impact of immigration on natives’ welfare. In particular, according to our benchmark model simulation, average native welfare increases in 14 out of the selected 19 OECD countries in response to a immigration shock that does not affect the observed immigrants education composition. However, these results change when the influx of migration is composed of only low-skilled workers, as only 7 of the analyzed 19 countries experience an increase in average welfare after the shock. Qualitatively, our results are mostly robust to different choices on the degrees of substitution between workers of different skill and origin.

Our paper departs from a search model inspired by Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), in which we introduced intergenerational features. However, our analysis can still be extended to address several issues for future research. For example, one significant issue to be pursued in future work may be to allow for immigrants assimilation. Indeed, our model accounts for population dynamics regarding skill and age composition but totally abstracts from immigrants assimilation. Long-term immigrants, and especially their offspring, may successfully integrate in the host country and eventually be considered the same as native workers under all respects. Another interesting avenue would be to take into account a more detailed fiscal block of the model that abstracts from the simplifying assumption of a fixed-benefit scheme and includes different types of income taxes. This is particularly relevant, as immigrants also contribute to the host country government revenues through consumption and capital taxes and, thus, the fiscal effects of immigration might be even greater than those obtained in the presented analysis.

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Michele Battisti, Alfonso Carfora, Paolo Giordani, Antonio Minniti, Carmelo Pierpaolo Parello, Alessandro Piergallini, and Luca Spinesi for very helpful comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank seminar participants at the Workshop on Migration and Mobility at the University of Glasgow. Any remaining errors are mine.

Appendix A. Alternative welfare index: native consumption

In the main text of the paper, we follow Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018) and consider $\mathcal{W}_n$ as the benchmark index for the presented welfare analysis. However, this index cannot be directly interpreted as a consumption-equivalent measure. For this reason, in what follows we provide an alternative welfare index that represents the steady-state value of average native consumption.

Let us assume, for ease of exposition, that all native agents can be considered as a single household and that capital does not depreciate over time.Footnote 23 Under such assumptions, the flow budget constraint of the native household is

\begin{equation*} \dot {k}_{n} =\frac {(1-\tau )\sum \limits _s E_{ns}w_{ns}+\mu \sum \limits _s U_{ns} w_{ns}-\frac {z^* (r+g_n)}{2}Q_{nh}+\sum \limits _s Q_{ns} T_{ns}^y+\sum \limits _s R_{ns} T_{ns}^R+r K_n + \pi _n}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)} - \tilde{c}_n, \end{equation*}

where $k_n \equiv K_n/ \sum \limits _s (Q_{ns}+R_{ns} )$ is the capital held by each native, $ \tilde{c}_n \equiv \tilde{C}_n/ \sum \limits _s (Q_{ns}+R_{ns} )$ is the per capita amount of native consumption $ \tilde{C}_n$ , and

\begin{equation*} \pi _n \equiv \frac {\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}{\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _o \left(Q_{os}+R_{os}\right)} \left [ Y - \sum \limits _s \sum \limits _o E_{os} w_{os} - rK - \sum \limits _s c_s V_s \right ], \end{equation*}

denotes the native firms’ profits under the assumption that all individuals can hold intermediate and final goods firms regardless of their age, skill, or origin. Note that, in the presented model, we have that final goods firms’ profits are given by:

\begin{equation*} \pi ^f \equiv Y - \sum \limits _s \sum \limits _o Y_{os}p_{os} - rK, \end{equation*}

whereas intermediate goods firms’ profits amount to

\begin{equation*} \pi ^i \equiv \sum \limits _s \sum \limits _o Y_{os}p_{os} -\sum \limits _s \sum \limits _o E_{os} w_{os}- \sum \limits _s c_s V_s, \end{equation*}

thus the aggregate amount of profits in the economy is

\begin{equation*} \pi \equiv \pi ^f + \pi ^i = Y - \sum \limits _s \sum \limits _o E_{os} w_{os} - rK - \sum \limits _s c_s V_s. \end{equation*}

In the steady state, we have that $\dot{k}_{n}=0$ and thus that the steady-state native consumption can be written as:

\begin{equation*} \tilde {c}_n =\frac {(1-\tau )\sum \limits _s E_{ns}w_{ns}+\mu \sum \limits _s U_{ns} w_{ns}-\frac {z^* (r+g_n)}{2}Q_{nh}+\sum \limits _s Q_{ns} T_{ns}^y+\sum \limits _s R_{ns} T_{ns}^R+r K_n + \pi _n}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}. \end{equation*}

Making use of equation (25), it is straightforward to check that $ \tilde{c}_n = \mathcal{W}_n +\pi _n/ \sum \limits _s (Q_{ns}+R_{ns} )$ . This implies that, to obtain a welfare index which represents a measure of native consumption, profits’ income need to be added on the right-hand side of equation (25) so that the alternative welfare index can be defined as:

\begin{equation*} \mathcal {W}^*_n = \mathcal {W}_n +\pi _n/ \sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right). \end{equation*}

Figure 6. Effects of immigration (1% of the total labor force) on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries using $\mathcal{W}_n^*$ as welfare index.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Replicating the same comparative statics analysis that we performed in Section 4.2.1, using $\mathcal{W}_n^*$ in place of $\mathcal{W}_n$ , we find that the obtained welfare effects under the alternative index (see Figure 6) are overall slightly more optimistic than those obtained in the main text of the paper (cf. Figure 2), though the main conclusions of the analysis hold mostly unaffected. In particular, Figure 6(a) shows that the welfare effect on immigration is still, on average, quite modest under the benchmark model, as it ranges from 0.01% (low-skilled immigration scenario) to 0.44% (high-skilled immigration scenario). Moreover, the model versions abstracting from the presence of retirees (i.e., Model 2 and Model 4) are still the most pessimistic ones under all of the three analyzed scenarios, while the model version that differs from the benchmark for the only absence of native skill adjustment (i.e., Model 3) yields very slightly more pessimistic results when compared with the benchmark model. Interestingly, the welfare effects in the skill-balanced scenario turn slightly positive for both Model 2 and Model 4, though such effects are still very small (average native welfare increases by roughly 0.03% and 0.02% for Model 2 and Model 4, respectively). Finally, Figure 6(b)–(d) show that a slightly higher number of countries benefit from the different immigration shocks under the alternative welfare index $\mathcal{W}_n^*$ (the native welfare effect is indeed positive for 11 countries under the low-skilled migration scenario, for 16 countries under the skill-balanced scenario, and for 18 under the high-skilled scenario), though the ranking of the welfare effect by country is mostly unaffected when compared with Figure 2(b)–(d).

The reason for such results lies in the addition of the profitability effect, which is included in the alternative welfare index $\mathcal{W}^*_n$ , but not in the benchmark welfare measure $\mathcal{W}_n$ . This additional transmission channel can be defined as:Footnote 24

\begin{align*} &\left. \Delta \mathcal{W}^*_n\right |_{\text{profit}} \equiv \frac{\Delta \pi _n}{\sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right)}. \end{align*}

Figure 7 gives the weighted mean averages of the profitability effect. According to this figure, such effect appears to be extremely robust under all of the four model variations, though sensible to the different immigration shock scenario. We can thus conclude that the differences in the welfare effects obtained across the four different model variants are robust to the choice of the welfare index.

Figure 7. Decomposition of the average welfare effect of immigration (1% of the total labor force)—profitability channel.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Appendix B. Actual immigration scenario

In the main text of the paper, we have focused our attention on analyzing the effects of a 1% increase in the labor force due to three different types of migration shocks: an increase of only low-skilled immigrant workers; an increase of only high-skilled immigrant workers; and an increase of both low- and high-skilled immigrant workers such that the immigrants’ skill composition does not change in the post-shock scenario. In this Appendix, we instead consider the actual changes in immigration stocks that took place during the period 2010–2015. To do so, we simulate all of the presented model variants under an “actual immigration shock” scenario, where we use the DIOC census round 2015 to extract information in the stock of immigrant workers by skill, age, and market status for the year 2015.Footnote 25

Figure 8. The actual changes in the stock of immigrants between the two census rounds in terms of total labor force and skill composition.

Note: Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

According to Figure 8(a), where the changes in the stock of immigrants are computed as percentage of the total labor force in the year 2010, the actual immigration shock during the period 2010–2015 appears to be much higher than 1% of the total labor force for the most of the considered countries. In particular, Switzerland is the country who faces the largest shock of immigrants in the considered period, as the increase in immigration amounts to 13.4% of the total labor force population of the year 2010. Sweden and Luxembourg also face large inflows of immigrants (their increase in immigration amounts to about 9% and 8.8% of the total labor force, respectively), while the other countries are characterized by relatively lower, or even negative, variations in the stock of immigrant stocks (in particular, the stock of immigrant workers in Greece and Portugal reduce by 0.9% and 2.5%, respectively, of the total labor force). As far as the skill composition of the immigrant workers is concerned, Figure 8(b) shows that the actual immigration variation appears to be roughly skill-balanced for most countries, though some countries experienced a relevant increase in the share of high-skilled immigrants in 2015 (in particular, the share of high-skilled immigrants in Luxembourg rises from 34.1% in 2010 to 51.1% in 2015; similarly, the share of high-skilled immigrants in Denmark rises from 30.5% in 2010 to 45.2% in 2015).

In what follows, we will first present the simulation results under the actual immigration scenario by taking into account all of the considered model variants. Then, we will test the endogenous skill acquisition mechanism described in Section 3 by comparing the share of high-skilled natives implied by the benchmark model with the actual changes in natives’ skill composition observed in DIOC 2015 census round data.

B.1. The effects of the actual immigration during the period 2010–2015

To determine the actual impact of immigration on native welfare over the period 2010–2015, we use the same welfare index $\mathcal{W}_n$ described by equation (25) that we considered in the previous simulation exercises. The model is then calibrated according to the parametrization strategy described in Tables 1 and 2. Figure 9 shows the effects of the actual immigration shock on the average native welfare in the selected group of OECD countries according to the four considered model versions.

Figure 9. Effects of immigration for the period 2010–2015 on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

According to Figure 9(a), the average welfare effect of the actual change in the stock of migrant workers is quantitatively negligible for the benchmark model and Model 3, and slightly negative under Model 2 and 4. Such welfare impacts are similar to those obtained in Section 4.2 under the skill-balanced scenario, coherently with the empirical fact that the actual immigration shock is roughly a skill-balanced shock for most countries [cf. Figure 8(b)]. Nonetheless, the benchmark model and Model 3 produce welfare effects that are less pessimistic than those obtained under Models 2 and 4, implying that taking into account age composition still affects the quantitative evaluation of the welfare effects under the actual immigration shock. As for the welfare effect by country depicted in Figure 9(b), the country ranking is also mostly in line with the ranking obtained under the skill-balanced shock depicted in Section 4.2 [cf. Figure 2(d)]. The greatest variations in the country ranking are mainly due to differences in the skill composition of the immigration shock (see, e.g., Luxembourg, which faced a very large inflow of high-skilled workers in the 2010–2015 period) or in the magnitude of the shock (see, e.g., Greece and Portugal, that faced a decrease in the stock of immigrants, rather than an increase).

Interestingly, the results are slightly sensible to the choice of the welfare index that we take into account in the simulation exercise. Indeed, if we consider the alternative welfare index:Footnote 26

\begin{equation*} \mathcal {W}^*_n = \mathcal {W}_n +\pi _n/ \sum \limits _s \!\left(Q_{ns}+R_{ns}\right), \end{equation*}

where $\pi _n$ denotes the native firms’ profits, the average welfare effects of the actual immigration shock turns positive under the benchmark model and Model 3 (cf. Figure 10), so that the inclusion of retirees in the model does not only quantitatively impact the results, but it is also able to affect the sign of the average welfare effect. Nonetheless, the average welfare effects depicted in Figure 10(a) are still in line with those obtained when the welfare index $\mathcal{W}^*_n$ is taken into account under the skill-balanced scenario shown in Appendix A [cf. Figure 6(a)], implying that the skill-balanced scenario gives a good approximation of the actual immigration scenario regardless of the considered welfare index.

Figure 10. Effects of immigration for the period 2010–2015 on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries using $\mathcal{W}_n^*$ as welfare index.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

B.2. Testing the endogenous skill acquisition mechanism

One of the main features of the benchmark model presented in Section 3 is the inclusion of an endogenous decision for natives to acquire education. This feature allows young natives to adjust their skill in face of migration, as the skill composition of the migration flows affects natives education decisions in the long run. Because the DIOC census rounds provide information on the level of education, age, and labor market status for both natives and immigrants, it is possible to check to what extent the skill acquisition mechanism described in Section 3 is able to reflect the actual native skill composition changes observed in the data.

Figure 11 shows the comparison between the change in the share of high-skilled natives implied by the benchmark model, under the actual immigration shock, with the actual changes observed in DIOC 2015 census round data. On the average, the actual share of high-skilled natives rises by 1.9% in the 2010–2015 period. The average predicted variation in the share of high-skilled natives is 2%, which is extremely close to the actual variation of 1.9%. Nonetheless, the predicted variation by country is close to the actual variation only for very few countries (namely Austria, Ireland, Portugal, Belgium, and France) and the correlation between the two variations is close to zero (−1.3%).

Figure 11. QNH

Different reasons might explain such a poor result of this test. First, the changes in the native skill composition implied by the model are related to the long-run equilibrium, as the adjustment process only ceases when the economy reaches its steady state. On the contrary, the actual changes are related to what we observed after only a 5-year period. Second, for the sake of simplicity, the model completely abstracts from other sources that might affect the education decision, such as the government investments in education or the presence of a technological innovation process able to spur investments in human capital.

Appendix C. Decomposed average welfare effects—component bar charts

Figure 12. Average welfare effects of immigration ( $1\%$ of the total labor force) decomposed for each transmission mechanism.

Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Footnotes

1 Source: OECD (2018).

2 Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014), in one of their extensions, analyze the case in which natives endogenously adjust their skill, but they completely abstract from the presence of a public sector.

3 See Preston (Reference Preston2014) for an extensive survey on the advantages and disadvantages of accounting approaches.

4 Source: OECD (2018).

5 Note that, because of the lack in immigrants wages data availability, the wage ratios presented in Docquier et al. (Reference Docquier, Ozden and Peri2014) derive from different sources and refer to different years.

6 In a technical appendix, available upon request, we show that assuming native and immigrant as workers perfect substitutes in production different outside options, as in Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014) and Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), does not affect the main results of the paper.

7 Indeed, many immigrants who remain in their host country during their working life still prefer to return to their home country at retirement [Coulon (Reference Coulon2016)]. For instance, Klinthall (Reference Klinthall2006) finds that the probability of return migration increases when reaching the age of 65 years in Sweden. Similarly, Jensen and Pedersen (Reference Jensen and Pedersen2007) estimate that the probability of leaving the country declines in the first 15 years of residence in Denmark but significantly increases upon retirement. Cobb-Clark and Stillman (Reference Cobb-Clark and Stillman2013) also find similar results in Australia.

8 See Liu et al. (Reference Liu, Palivos and Zhang2017) for a search and matching framework with international immigration that allows for cross-skill matching.

9 Note that, following Chassamboulli and Palivos (Reference Chassamboulli and Palivos2014) and Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), we postulate that the matching processes of low- and high-skilled workers are characterized by a common efficiency parameter so that cross-skill differences in the job-finding rates only depend on the sector-specific market tightness.

10 Note that the value of an open vacancy, $\mathcal{J}_s^V$ , has no origin index $o$ because firms are unable to direct their search towards different types of workers who hold the same skill level.

11 Remind that a worker will separate from a firm at a rate $\delta _{os}+g_o$ , rather than $\delta _{os}$ , because he will not supply labor after retirement.

12 Followig Aubry et al. (Reference Aubry, Burzynski and Docquier2016) and Burzynski et al. (Reference Burzynski, Docquier and Rapoport2018), redistributive transfers include public consumption as well as public health expenditures, family allowances, pension benefits, and other welfare payments. As it is debated that immigrants may use welfare more intensively than natives (see, e.g., Barrett and McCarthy (Reference Barrett and McCarthy2008) for a review on the literature of immigrants and their welfare usage), these transfers are allowed to vary across age, origin, and skill types.

13 We abstract from endogenizing education decisions of immigrants individuals, as analyzing the effects of immigration on the welfare of previous immigrant workers is beyond the scope of this paper. In Section 4, we will assess the effects of immigration under different skill composition scenarios.

14 Using this welfare index is equivalent of using the welfare index proposed by Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018) when the skill decision is exogenous and no retirement takes place. In Appendix A, we consider an alternative welfare index that can be interpreted as a consumption-equivalent measure.

15 Recall that native workers are heterogeneous with respect to their cost of training and that $z$ in uniformly distributed. This implies that the average cost paid by natives to acquire skill is $\frac{z^*}{2}$ , and the total flow value of training cost is $\frac{z^*(r+g_n)}{2}Q_{nh}$ .

16 For the sake of exposition, in this section, we will only refer to the immigration effects on the average native welfare. The online Appendix shows the effects of immigration on specific workers groups.

17 As pointed out by Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018), this is a normalization that does not affect the obtained results.

18 In a technical appendix, available upon request, we perform a sensitivity analysis on $\xi$ and show that the proposed results are robust to the choice of a matching efficiency parameter which is twice as large as that considered in the benchmark calibration.

19 This is in line with the empirical evidence that hiring costs generally increase with skill requirements for job applicants [see Blatter et al. (Reference Blatter, Muehlemann and Schenker2012)] as well as with the common practice of measuring vacancy costs as a percentage of labor costs [see Manning (Reference Manning2011), for a recent survey on hiring costs].

20 Although we cannot obtain a closed-form solution for our model, we find that, under the described parametrization, a unique economically meaningful equilibrium exists in all of the considered countries for the benchmark model.

21 Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Felbermayr, Peri and Poutvaara2018) simulate a shock of the same magnitude. In a technical appendix, available upon request, we show that considering a larger percentage change of immigration only proportionally affects the scale of the welfare effects. Moreover, in Appendix B, we also take into account the actual changes in immigration stocks that took place between the two most recent DIOC census rounds and show that the models results of this exercise are very close to those obtained under the skill-balanced scenario.

22 In Figure 12 of the Appendix C, we also show component bar charts for the decomposed average welfare effects under each of the three different immigration scenarios.

23 Note that considering each agent group as a different household and then computing the weighted average steady-state native consumption yields exactly the same level of average steady-state native consumption. Moreover, the introduction of a fixed positive rate of depreciation for capital is straightforward, but it does not change the results of the comparative statics analysis.

24 Note that all of the other transmission channels described in Section 4.2.2 are still in place, as including native firms’ profits $\pi _n$ to the welfare index does not affect the other welfare components studied in the welfare decomposition analysis.

25 Note that, at the time of this writing, the DIOC census round 2015 is the most recent database undertaken by the OECD that accounts for differences in demographic characteristics, level of education, and labor market status of the population of OECD member states.

26 See Appendix A for an extensive description of this alternative welfare index.

References

Acemoglu, D. (2002) Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies 69(4), 781809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arslan, C., Dumont, J.-C., Kone, Z., Moullan, Y., Ozden, C., Parsons, C. and Xenogiani, T.. (2014) A new profile of migrants in the aftermath of the recent economic crisis. OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers 160, 71.Google Scholar
Aubry, A., Burzynski, M. and Docquier, F. (2016) The welfare impact of global migration in OECD countries. Journal of International Economics 101(C), 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrett, A. and McCarthy, Y. (2008) Immigrants and welfare programmes: Exploring the interactions between immigrant characteristics, immigrant welfare dependence, and welfare policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 24(3), 542559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartolucci, C. (2014) Understanding the native – Immigrant wage gap using matched employer-employee data. ILR Review 67(4), 11661202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battisti, M., Felbermayr, G., Peri, G. and Poutvaara, P.. (2018) Immigration, search and redistribution: A quantitative assessment of native welfare. Journal of the European Economic Association 16(4), 11371188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betts, J. (1998) Educational crowding out: Do immigrants affect the educational attainment of american minorities? In: Betts, J. (eds.), Help or Hindrance? The Economic Implications of Immigration for African-Americans. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google ScholarPubMed
Blatter, M., Muehlemann, S. and Schenker, S. (2012) The costs of hiring skilled workers. European Economic Review 56(1), 2035.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borjas, G. J. (2003) The labor demand curve is downward sloping: Reexamining the impact of immigration on the labor market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(565), 11771205.Google Scholar
Borjas, G. J., Grogger, J. and Hanson, G. H. (2012) Comment: On estimating elasticities of substition. Journal of the European Economic Association 10(1), 198210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunello, G., Lodigiani, E. and Rocco, L. (2020) Does low skilled immigration increase the education of natives? Evidence from italian provinces. Labour Economics 63, 101794.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burzynski, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2018) The changing structure of immigration to the OECD: What welfare effects on member countries? IMF Economic Review 66(3), 564601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, D. (2009) Immigration and inequality. American Economic Review 99(2), 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cattaneo, C., Fiorio, C. and Peri, G. (2013) Immigration and careers of European workers: Effects and the role of policies. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies 2(1), 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chassamboulli, A. and Palivos, T. (2013) The impact of immigration on the employment and wages of native workers. Journal of Macroeconomics 38(PA), 1934.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chassamboulli, A. and Palivos, T. (2014) A search-equilibrium approach to the effects of immigration on labor market outcomes. International Economic Review 55(1), 111129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chassamboulli, A. and Peri, G. (2015) The labor market effects of reducing the number of illegal immigrants. Review of Economic Dynamics 18(4), 792821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chojnicki, X., Docquier, F. and Ragot, L. (2011) Should the US have locked heaven’s door? Journal of Population Economics 24(1), 317359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cobb-Clark, D. and Stillman, S. (2013) Return migration and the age profile of retirement among immigrants. IZA Journal of Migration and Development 2(1), 120.Google Scholar
Coulon, A. D. (2016) Where Do Immigrants Retire To? IZA World of Labor, p. 297.Google Scholar
D’Amuri, F. and Peri, G. (2014) Immigration, jobs, and employment protection: Evidence from Europe before and during the great recession. Journal of the European Economic Association 12(2), 432464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Docquier, F., Ozden, C. and Peri, G. (2014) The labour market effects of immigration and emigration in OECD countries. Economic Journal 124(579), 11061145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dustmann, C. and Frattini, T. (2014) The fiscal effects of immigration to the UK. Economic Journal 124(580), 593643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollin, D. (2002) Getting income shares right. Journal of Political Economy 110(2), 458474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobijn, B. and Şahin, A. (2009) Job-finding and separation rates in the oecd. Economics Letters 104(3), 107111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosios, A. J. (1990) On the efficiency of matching and related models of search and unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 57(2), 279298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunt, J. (2012). The Impact of Immigration on the Educational Attainment of Natives. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., NBER Working Papers 18047.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ikhenaode, B. I. and Parello, C. P. (2020) Immigration and remittances in a two-country model of growth with labor market frictions. Economic Modelling 93(C), 675692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, P. and Pedersen, P. J. (2007) To stay or not to stay? Out-migration of immigrants from denmark. International Migration 45(5), 87113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klinthall, M. (2006) Retirement return migration from sweden. International Migration 44(2), 153180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, X. (2010) On the macroeconomic and welfare effects of illegal immigration. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34(12), 25472567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, X., Palivos, T. and Zhang, X. (2017) Immigration, skill heterogeneity, and qualification mismatch. Economic Inquiry 55(3), 12311264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llull, J. (2018) Immigration, wages, and education: A labour market equilibrium structural model. Review of Economic Studies 85(3), 18521896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manacorda, M., Manning, A. and Wadsworth, J. (2012) The impact of immigration on the structure of wages: Theory and evidence from britain. Journal of the European Economic Association 10(1), 120151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manning, A. (2011) Imperfect competition in the labor market, Chapter 11. In: O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 4, pp. 9731041. London: Elsevier.Google Scholar
McHenry, P. (2015) Immigration and the human capital of natives. Journal of Human Resources 50(1), 3471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mortensen, D. and Nagypal, E. (2007) More on unemployment and vacancy fluctuations. Review of Economic Dynamics 10(3), 327347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD. (2012) Education at a Glance 2012: OECD Indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
OECD. (2014) Matching Economic Migration with Labour Market Needs. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
OECD. (2018) International Migration Outlook 2018. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Orrenius, P. M., Zavodny, M. and Abraham, A. (2020). The Effect of Immigration on Business Dynamics and Employment. Institute of Labor Economics (IZA), IZA Discussion Papers 13014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortega, J. (2000) Pareto-improving immigration in an economy with equilibrium unemployment. The Economic Journal 110(460), 92112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ottaviano, G. I. and Peri, G. (2012) Rethinking the effect of immigration on wages. Journal of the European economic association 10(1), 152197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peri, G. and Sparber, C. (2009) Task specialization, immigration, and wages. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1(3), 135169.Google Scholar
Peri, G. and Sparber, C. (2011) Highly educated immigrants and native occupational choice. Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 50(3), 385411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petrongolo, B. and Pissarides, C. A. (2001) Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function. Journal of Economic literature 39(2), 390431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poutvaara, P. (2008) Public and private education in an integrated Europe: Studying to migrate and teaching to stay? Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110(3), 591608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preston, I. (2014) The effect of immigration on public finances. The Economic Journal 124(580), F569F592.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storesletten, K. (2000) Sustaining fiscal policy through immigration. Journal of Political Economy 108(2), 300323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storesletten, K. (2003) Fiscal implications of immigration-A net present value calculation. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 105(3), 487506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Labor market and population characteristics across countries.Note: Figure 1 shows population characteristics for the 19 selected countries—reference year 2010.

Figure 1

Table 1. Parameters without country variation

Figure 2

Table 2. Parameters varying across countries

Figure 3

Table 3. Immigration shock scenarios

Figure 4

Figure 2. Effects of immigration (1% of the total labor force) on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 5

Figure 3. Decomposition of the average welfare effect of immigration (1% of the total labor force) — employment and wage channels.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Figure 6

Figure 4. Decomposition of the average welfare effect of immigration (1% of the total labor force) — fiscal, capital, education, and residual channels.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Figure 7

Figure 5. Effects of immigration (1% of the total labor force) on 19 selected OECD countries — sensitivity to parameters.Note: Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 8

Figure 6. Effects of immigration (1% of the total labor force) on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries using $\mathcal{W}_n^*$ as welfare index.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 9

Figure 7. Decomposition of the average welfare effect of immigration (1% of the total labor force)—profitability channel.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.

Figure 10

Figure 8. The actual changes in the stock of immigrants between the two census rounds in terms of total labor force and skill composition.Note: Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 11

Figure 9. Effects of immigration for the period 2010–2015 on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 12

Figure 10. Effects of immigration for the period 2010–2015 on native welfare in the 19 selected OECD countries using $\mathcal{W}_n^*$ as welfare index.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition. Countries are ranked in descending order according to the native welfare effect in the benchmark model. Variations are expressed in percentage points.

Figure 13

Figure 11. QNH

Figure 14

Figure 12. Average welfare effects of immigration ($1\%$ of the total labor force) decomposed for each transmission mechanism.Note: Benchmark = Retirees & Endogenous Skill Acquisition; Model 2 = No Retirees; Model 3 = Exogenous Skill Acquisition; and Model 4 = No retirees & Exogenous Skill Acquisition.