1. Introduction
Pension planning is one of the most important financial decisions, as it impacts a significant portion of a plan participant’s life. Contributions and investment decisions during the accumulation phase are key factors for determining the guarantee that individuals expect to maintain their standard of living after retirement. This is where portfolio insurance strategies come into play by protecting participants’ retirement savings from significant market downturns while allowing growth potential. Using techniques such as dynamic asset allocation or option-based approaches, one can ensure that a minimum portfolio value is maintained and the risk of substantial losses near retirement is reduced. This balance between risk mitigation and growth is essential for providing retirees with more predictable and secure financial benefits in the face of long-term market volatility.
In the present paper, we focus on a specific type of portfolio insurance, namely, the constant proportion portfolio insurance (CPPI) tailored for a DC plan within a discrete-time trading framework. In such settings, investors always face the risk that the portfolio value may reach the floor due to the inability to trade instantly in response to market changes when trading discretely. If the portfolio value drops below the floor value, the entire wealth is invested in the riskless asset creating a special case of a cash-locked position. As a result, the potential gains from the risky asset are missed during an upward market movement, and the portfolio value may fail to meet the guarantee at the termination date. On the other hand, an interruption of the CPPI strategy before the termination of the policy (such as withdrawal and retirement) also poses a gap risk. To reduce such a risk, the investor may consider a financial tool, such as a put option, to improve the course of the asset growth. To cope with such unwanted situations, this paper introduces an exotic option called the ‘cushion option’ which is designed to generate an additional gain in case of a gap that is a sudden drop in the portfolio value. Hence, the option is expected to benefit when the cushion becomes negative between discrete trading times. Since this is a theoretical derivative instrument, our primary assumption is that there are parties in the market who sell these options. Then, based on the position of the pension fund, the plan participant can buy it.
The option is priced as an expectation of the discounted claims with its boundary under the equivalent martingale measure in our complete market. In an incomplete market, on the other hand, there exists a class of equivalent martingale measures to price the exotic option. Applying Schweizer’s variance-optimal criterion (Schweizer, Reference Schweizer1995), one can then obtain the explicit price of the exotic option under the minimal martingale measure which is not in the scope of this paper. The market we consider exhibits perfect correlation between the labor income and the risky asset processes following the approach of Bodie et al. Reference Bodie, Merton and Samuelson(1992) and Benzoni et al. Reference Benzoni, Collin–Dufresne and Goldstein(2007). This assumption is needed to find a replicating portfolio of the labor income. Through sensitivity analyses, we examine the effectiveness of cushion option on CPPI strategy in a DC pension plan to deal with gap risk. We also analyze the optimal strike price interval of the cushion option under predetermined market parameters and question if this option can be proposed as a financial tool to reduce the impact of early withdrawals resulting in lapse risk.
In the related literature, Blake et al. Reference Blake, Cairns and Dowd(2000) examine the optimal dynamic asset allocation strategy for DC plan taking into account stochastic process for labor income including a non-hedgeable risk component. Considering stochastic behavior of labor income and stochastic inflation rate, a closed form solution is given by Battochio and Menoncin Reference Battochio and Menoncin(2004) for the optimal portfolio in a complete financial market. Similarly, Baltas et al. Reference Baltas, Szczepański, Dopierala, Kolodziejczyk, Weber and Yannacopoulos(2018) study the optimal management of defined-contribution pension schemes by considering both the portfolio’s exposure to various market risks and the model uncertainty regarding the evolution of several unknown market parameters that influence its behavior. The authors delve into the same problem, considering the effects of inflation, mortality, and model uncertainty in Baltas et al. Reference Baltas, Dopierala, Kolodziejczyk, Szczepański, Weber and Yannacopoulos(2022).
In the discrete-time trading framework, Haberman and Vigna (Reference Haberman and Vigna2001, Reference Haberman and Vigna2002) and Temocin et al. (Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2017) investigate an optimal investment strategy in DC plan by using dynamic programming techniques. Among many others, the main risk in a DC pension plan for participants is the investment risk during accumulation phase, in which their pension wealth has been built up so that an appropriately sized annuity (or other investment) can be purchased to provide income during retirement. To moderate investment risk, a minimum guarantee is introduced as a lower bound for pension wealth that will be paid out to the participants upon retirement. With respect to this, Boulier et al. Reference Boulier, Huang and Taillard(2001) study the optimal management of a defined contribution (DC) plan with deterministic contribution and the guarantee in retirement depending on the level of stochastic interest rate which follows the Vasicek Reference Vasiček(1977) model. In their setup, the guarantee has a form that is annuity paid out from retirement time until the date of death which is also taken as deterministic. Deelstra et al. Reference Deelstra, Grasselli and Koehl(2003) investigate the optimal investment problem for DC plan that allows for minimum guarantee with stochastic contribution and assumes that interest rate dynamics are given as in Duffie and Kahn Reference Duffie and Kahn(1996) in its one-dimensional version. Although authors make various assumptions, their aim is to provide the minimum guarantee, which are so-called ‘portfolio insurance strategies’.
The concept of CPPI strategy is firstly introduced by Perold Reference Perold(1986) for fixed-income securities and by Black and Jones Reference Black and Jones(1987) for equity instruments. The properties of CPPI strategies in continuous time are studied by Black and Perold Reference Black and Perold(1992). Assuming HARA utiliy function, they show that the CPPI strategy can maximize expected utility. This study is extended by Horsky Reference Horsky(2012) with the interest rate that follows the Vasiček model and stock modeled by the Heston process. Temocin et al. (Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2017) study the CPPI strategy in DC pension funds with different floor assumptions under continuous-time and discrete-time trading. The gap risk which is the probability of portfolio falling below the floor and the risk of portfolio being fully invested in the risk-free asset without a recovery, called the cash-lock risk, are analyzed for discrete time trading as well in Temocin et al. Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2018.
Bertrand and Prigent Reference Bertrand and Prigent(2003) compare the performances of CPPI and Option based portfolio insurance (OBPI) strategies when the volatility of the risky asset is stochastic. They also examine both strategies under first-order stochastic dominance criteria that are related to increasing utility functions (Bertrand and Prigent, Reference Bertrand and Prigent2005). Considering various stochastic dominance criteria up to third order, Zagst and Kraus Reference Zagst and Kraus(2011) compare the two portfolio insurance strategies. They conclude that CPPI is likely to dominate the OBPI strategy at third order. Pézier and Scheller Reference Pézier and Scheller(2013) show that CPPI is superior to the OBPI strategy under discrete trading and asset prices having jump.
In the Black and Scholes framework, which is the basis for most academic studies on CPPI, there is no gap risk, because the probability of the portfolio value being above the floor at any time equals to one. However, addressing the gap risk, Balder et al. (Reference Balder, Brandl and Mahayni2009), Cont and Tankov (Reference Cont and Tankov2009), and Lacroze and Paulot Reference Lacroze and Paulot(2011) show that portfolio value may crash through the floor in incomplete market in which asset price jumps may occur or when the portfolio may only be re-balanced on a finite number of trading days. Balder et al. Reference Balder, Brandl and Mahayni(2009) investigate the CPPI strategy under trading restrictions, where the multiplier, a certain proportion of excess value of current wealth over the floor, cannot be changed between instant trading dates. So that, investor will not have an opportunity to re-balance the portfolio, which then may crash through the floor between trading dates on a downward market move. Cont and Tankov Reference Cont and Tankov(2009) quantify the gap risk that results from instantaneous price jumps analytically for the CPPI strategy under continuous-time trading. Lacroze and Paulot Reference Lacroze and Paulot(2011) show that if the underlying has independent increments, the dynamics of the portfolio at trading dates is described by a discrete-time Markov process in a single variable. Extreme value approach is also used by Bertrand and Prigent Reference Bertrand and Prigent(2002) to estimate gap risk of the CPPI strategy. Moreover, Tankov introduces an exotic derivative called gap option in Tankov Reference Tankov(2010) and shows that to price and manage the option, jumps must necessarily be included into the model. The author then presents explicit pricing and hedging formulas in the single asset and multi-asset case.
The main difference of our CPPI setting from the literature listed above is that we focus on a CPPI with random floor that grows not only with interest rate but also with the portions of each contribution, unlike the deterministic floors in the classical CPPI strategies. Hence, in this setup, floor becomes a stochastic process due to the dynamics of the labor income as described in Temocin et al. (Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2017).
The plan of this paper is as follows: In Section 2, the classical CPPI strategy is presented. Section 3 gives the CPPI strategy for a DC pension plan, the cushion option is also proposed, and the CPPI strategy for DC pension scheme under the cushion option is derived. In Section 4, the evolution of a wealth in pension fund with and without the cushion option until certain withdrawal time is presented, and the effectiveness of cushion option for CPPI strategy is also discussed. We conclude with a brief discussion of the observations and suggestions for further research in Section 5.
2. CPPI strategy
The CPPI strategy is a self-financing strategy whose aim is to take potential gain on upward market move while guaranteeing at least an specified fixed amount of money at maturity time T. In the CPPI strategy, the investor initially sets a floor which is the lowest acceptable portfolio value. The cushion is calculated as the excess value of current wealth over the floor. The cushion multiplied by a pre-determined multiplier, defined as exposure, is allocated to the risky asset. Remaining funds are invested in the riskless asset. In the classic Black-Scholes market, where two basic assets are traded continuously during time horizon
$[0,T]$, and the fund manager invests into the two assets: a riskless asset (money market account), Bt, and a risky asset (stock or stock index), St, the price dynamics under
$ \mathbb{P}$ are given by


where r, b, s, µs, and σs are constant and Wt is a Brownian process defined on complete probability space
$(\Omega , \mathcal{F}, \mathbb{P})$. Here,
$ \mathbb{P}$ is real-world probability measure and the filtration
$\mathcal{F}= (\mathcal{F}_{t})_{[t\geq0]}$ represents the history of the Brownian motion up to time t. The basic idea of the CPPI approach (Zagst and Kraus, Reference Zagst and Kraus2011) is that the terminal portfolio value, VT, at the end of the investment horizon T stays above an investor-defined floor given as a percentage,
$\varphi \geq 0$, of initial value, V 0, i.e.

Since the market is arbitrage-free, it is impossible to find an investment that returns more than the risk-free rate of return,
$\mathit{r}$, with no risk. Hence, the maximum guaranteed portfolio value at maturity time, T, is limited by

The floor Ft,
$0\leq t \leq T$, denotes the present value of guarantee. By discounting with respect to deterministic interest rate, r, φt becomes

Accordingly, the floor follows the dynamics

The surplus of current portfolio value, Vt, above the floor Ft is called cushion. The price of cushion, Ct, at any time
$t \in [0,T]$ is given as

At any time
$t\in [0,T]$, the wealth invested into the risky asset, called exposure, is given by

where m is a constant multiplier reflecting the risk attitude of the investor. The remaining funds are then invested in the risk-free asset leading to a portfolio value process

By Equations (3) and (4), the cushion Ct satisfies

3. CPPI strategy in DC pension plan under discrete time trading setting
Let τ be set of n + 1 equidistant trading dates along time period
$[0,T] $, such as
$\tau= \{t_{0} \lt t_{1} \lt \ldots \lt t_{n-1} \lt t_{n}\} $, where
$t_{0}=0$ is the inception date of DC pension plan,
$t_{n}=T$ is the retirement date, and
$\triangle t:= t_{k+1}-t_{k}=T/n $ for
$k=0,1,..,n-1$.
As mentioned earlier, we consider two assets in the financial market for investing pension contributions: risky asset (stock or stock index) and riskless asset (money market account). Money market account, Bt, grows with constant interest rate, r, and its price dynamic with initial value
$B_{0}=b$ given in Equation (1). Additionally, we assume that the price dynamics of risky asset, St, is expressed as in Equation (2). Since trading takes place at equidistant trading dates, the observed stock price is as follows:

where
$S_{t_{0}}=s$ and
$\triangle W_{t_{k}}=W_{t_{k+1}}-W_{t_{k}}$ for
$k=0,...,n-1$.
The DC fund modeling has two key aspects:
i. There is no consumption before the retirement date.
ii. Labor income plays a central role in the wealth-accumulated phase.
iii. The inheritance gains are not considered which avoids the consideration of longevity and mortality risks.
Labor income is hard to model realistically due to its complicated stochastic components such as financial and political crisis, disability, and mortality. Here, labor income, Lt, is assumed to have a stochastic process reflecting the risk of the financial market. If the participants contribute to the pension fund at each equidistant trading date as a certain proportion, γ, of their labor income, the labor income dynamics are defined as a stochastic differential equation as follows:

with l, µL, and σL representing starting labor constant, average labor, and standard deviation, respectively, and
$W^*_{t}$ is a Brownian process. In what follows, we restrict the stochastic behavior of the labor income process for the tractability of analytic results. The case we consider is a labor income process that perfectly correlates with risky asset (
$d{W_{t}} = dW^*_{t} $) following the approach of Bodie et al. Reference Bodie, Merton and Samuelson(1992).
Based on this setup, the observed labor income becomes

where
$L_{t_{0}}=l$ and
$\triangle W_{t_{k}}=W_{t_{k+1}}-W_{t_{k}}$ for
$k=0,...,n-1$. Therefore, the DC with respect to labor process and the value of proportion, γ, is defined as

for all
$k=0,1,..,n$ with dynamics

We assume that there is a portfolio which has the same dynamics as labor income. For this reason, the labor income can be replicated perfectly between equidistant trading dates using assets in the market. In order to prove this, we need to show the relevant replicating portfolio. Assuming the relation which expresses the equivalence of risk premium between the labor income and the risky asset

we consider a self-financing replicating strategy
$\pi=(\pi_{B},\pi_{S},\pi_{L})$ and choose
$\pi_{L}=-1$ as given in Temocin et al. (Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2017). Then, we have the value of the fund as

Equating the diffusion terms and the drift terms to zero, we obtain the number of assets required as

Unlike the floor in the classical CPPI strategy, we consider a random floor which evolves not only with interest rate but also with the portion of each contribution. In this setup, floor, Ft becomes a stochastic process due to the dynamics of the labor income as described in (Temocin et al., Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2017). Hence, the floor at time t is defined as

for
$ k=0,1,...,n-1$, where
$0 \lt c \lt 1$ is a constant that denotes the proportion of the amount of contribution to be added to the floor with
$F_{0}=c\gamma_{t_{0}}$. The portfolio value is then given as

for
$t \in (t_{k},t_{k+1})$ and

for
$t=t_k$ for all
$k=0,1,..,n-1$.
Then by its definition, the cushion process becomes

for
$t \in (t_{k},t_{k+1})$ and

for
$t=t_k$ for all
$k=0,1,..,n-1$.
Now that we have described the CPPI-DC design, we next introduce the implementation of the cushion insurance by employing a special exotic option, hereby called the cushion option.
3.1. Cushion option in the frame of a CPPI strategy
Due to our trading structure, the risk of cushion becoming negative between trading dates is always present as the re-balancements are done only at trading dates. Considering the cushion dynamics, we can define probability of gap risk, Pgap just before contribution payment comes into the system as follows:

To minimize Pgap, we propose the exotic cushion option with payoff function

where
$K=C_{t_{k}}$. The main aim of this custom-made option is to generate an additional gain in case of a sudden decrease in the portfolio value. The proposed option is expected to benefit when the cushion becomes negative between times tk and
$t_{k+1}$. Hence, we compare the cushion amounts at these times with the purpose of activating the payoff only when there is a gap phenomenon in the given time period. Here, the strike price, K, represents the cushion with the aim of making sure that there is always sufficient capital for buying the option, so the option price will always be smaller than the cushion due to non-negative labor income. Since this is a theoretical derivative, our primary assumption is that there are parties in the market who sell these options. Then, based on the position of the pension fund, the beneficiary can buy the relevant option. By Girsanov’s Theorem (Shreve, Reference Shreve2004), we have the risk-neutral dynamics of the stock price as

where
$W^{\mathbb{Q}}$ is the Brownian motion under the unique risk-neutral measure
$\mathbb{Q}$. Thus, we have

Substituting
$W^{\mathbb{Q}}_{t_{k+1}}-W^{\mathbb{Q}}_{t_{k}}$ into the
$\mathbb{Q}$-dynamics of
$L_{t_{k+1}}$ yields


Hence, the payoff of the cushion option becomes

where

The next proposition gives the price of the cushion with this payoff.
Proposition 1. The cushion option under CPPI-DC design with payoff

has a price of
$P_{t_{k}}$ given as

where

with

Proof. The details of the proof is given in the Appendix.□
The cushion option is assumed to be purchased at time tk for all
$k=0,1,...,n-1$. Since
$C_{t_{k}} \gt P_{t_{k}}$, new portfolio value,
$V_{t_{k}}^{*}$, and cushion value,
$C_{t_{k}}^{*}$, at time tk are given by

and

respectively. Then, for
$C_{t_{k}} \gt 0$ for all
$k=0,1,..,n-1$, the portfolio value is expressed as

For
$C_{t_{k}}\leq0$ for all
$k=0,1,..,n-1$, the portfolio value,
$V_{t_{k+1}}=V_{t_{k}}e^{r\triangle t}+ \gamma L_{t_{k+1}}$, yields the value of the pension fund at
$t_{k+1}$. Henceforth, when
$C_{t_{k}} \gt 0$, the wealth process between equidistant trading dates is given as

whereas for
$C_{t_{k}}\leq0$,

for
$t \in (t_{k},t_{k+1})$,
$k=0,1,..,n-1$.
4. Implementation and numerical results
In order to indicate the influence of the cushion option on CPPI-DC plans under certain assumptions, we perform simulations because the realization of real data requires long years and a wide range of market conditions, DC plan, and country-specific characteristics may also change over the years. By means of 10000 Monte Carlo simulations, the CPPI strategy with cushion option and without cushion option is generated and the performance levels of both strategies are investigated under various market and DC plan assumptions. All analyses and runs are coded using MATLAB.
The simulation scenarios based on many factors are expected to expose sensitivity with respect to varying parameter values. As exotic options can be utilized for short-term leverage in financial markets, their contributions are evaluated in two basic time frames:
(i) short-term which corresponds to the generally assumed earliest time to terminate the pension plan; T = 3 years
(ii) long-term at which the participants fulfill the retirement conditions; T = 20 years.
The comparisons with respect to time frames and the parameters are performed based on the value of the fund with and without cushion options. The steps of the proposed approach start with setting up arbitrary fixed values for the contributing parameters. The algorithm then calculates the price of the cushion option for the strike price at each fixed trading date. The next step considers a CPPI scheme for each fixed trading date with and without cushion options for strike price and finds the wealth for each case. The process ends with a comparison of the setup with respect to the cushion option and different values of the contributing parameters.
Portfolio strategies are simulated using the set of parameters summarized in Table 1. The parameter values are chosen to be the same as in Temocin et al. (Reference Temocin, Korn and Selcuk-Kestel2017) in order to have a benchmark except for some adjustments in the interest rate, r, and market volatility, σS, to expose the influence of the cushion-option setup on fund’s development. The choice of 3 years for short-term is made with respect to the most commonly official withdrawal duration set by the life and pension insurance companies.
Table 1. Parameter values under discrete-time trading setting

Table 2 shows the mean and standard deviation of the final wealth for the CPPI strategy without and with the cushion option for a period of 3 years and a period of 20 years. According to the results, we see that cushion option is a profitable choice for both periods. Mean,
$E(V_{T})$, and standard deviation,
$\sigma(V_{T})$, of final wealth for the CPPI strategy under the cushion option are higher than the mean and standard deviation of final wealth for the CPPI strategy. Considering that downside protection is provided by the CPPI strategy, the higher standard deviation indicates the longer right tail of terminal wealth distribution, and therefore it is considered a positive performance indicator, despite its more usual role as a negative performance indicator.
Table 2. The final wealth of CPPI strategies for long and short terms

In Table 3, we illustrate the sensitivities with respect to the parameters for the time frames T = 20 years and T = 3 years. We see from the results of the simulations that the higher market volatility, σS, has a positive effect on moments of terminal wealth for without cushion option CPPI strategy in the 3-year time period. However, we cannot observe accurate information about its effect on the terminal wealth for the CPPI strategy under cushion option for the 20-year time period. An increase in the market drift, µS, raises the moment of the terminal wealth for CPPI strategies in both time periods. A rise on labor income drift, µL, as well as labor income volatility, σL, increases the moments of terminal wealth for CPPI strategies in both time horizon. Increasing the guarantee rate, c, resulting in the higher floor, has a negative effect on the moments of both strategies. That is, when the smaller amount of wealth is invested in the risky asset, we take fewer potential gains on the upward market move. CPPI with cushion option yields higher average return compared to no cushion when the contribution rate, γ, increases. When more amount of money is invested in the risky asset, investor can take more gains from increasing market. Higher multiplier, m, yields the moments of CPPI portfolio to be slightly higher in both time periods, but on the other hand higher m decreases moments of CPPI strategy with cushion option in both time horizon. The gap risk increases in the case of the high multiplier, m, and therefore the value of cushion option depending on gap risk raises. As expected, the high price of cushion option lowers the profits. Inversely, smaller multiplier, m, decreases the gap risk in line with the price of cushion option. For a small multiplier such as m = 2, the cushion option has no significant effect on the CPPI strategy. Note that the initial value for the portfolio is taken to be
$0.1$ in Tables 2 and 3.
Table 3. CPPI portfolio with and without cushion option under certain parameter values (T=20 years and T=3 years)

Figure 1 illustrates the portfolio trajectories of both strategies, highlighting their evolution over time. The figure compares the performance across two selected investment horizons. Taking a glance at the graphs, one can see that the portfolio value under the cushion option initially stands below the portfolio value of the CPPI strategy due to hedging cost for both horizons. When a sudden decrease occurs, portfolio value recovers quickly by means of cushion option and makes benefits from increasing in the market. However, portfolio value for the CPPI strategy needs time to recover and cannot make use of an advantage of potential gains on the upward move in the market.

Figure 1. Illustrative trajectories of CPPI portfolio-scheme based on the parameters chosen in Table 1 in the 3-year time period (a and b) and 20-year time period (c and d).
Figures 2 and 3 illustrate the tail properties and the distributional behavior of terminal portfolio value for both strategies with respect to different time frames. As clearly seen, the CPPI strategy under cushion option has a longer right tail in the value of terminal wealth compared to the other case. This illustrative distributional behavior of both strategies supports the results depicted in Table 2.

Figure 2. Short-term estimated kernel densities of final wealth for CPPI.

Figure 3. Long-term estimated kernel densities of final wealth for CPPI.
5. Concluding comments
Fund management for DC pension plans is critical for both individuals and social security systems. In this context, the literature explores portfolio insurance as a means to provide downside protection for portfolio values. The CPPI strategy with the random floor applied to DC pension plan under discrete-time trading setting allows us to foresee the development of a guaranteed fund. Considering trading only takes place at predefined dates, the portfolio value can drop below the floor between trading dates. Additionally, contribution at trading dates may not be enough to push up the floor. Therefore, in this paper, we propose a cushion option to reduce the gap risk and derive the price of option as well as the wealth process accordingly. By means of Monte Carlo simulations, the effectiveness of the cushion option on the CPPI strategy is tested by comparing portfolio performance for the CPPI strategy with and without cushion option. To support the effectiveness of cushion option, kernel densities are estimated for terminal wealth of both strategies.
This paper contributes to the valuation of DC plan funds by explicitly pricing a cushion option and demonstrating its utilization through numerical analysis. Monte Carlo simulation results indicate that the CPPI strategy incorporating a cushion option outperforms the standard CPPI strategy over both short-term (e.g., 3-year) and long-term (e.g., 20-year) horizons, as evidenced by higher moments of terminal wealth.
Even though the CPPI strategy provides downside protection, a sudden decline in the market may cause the portfolio value to drop below the floor. If the remaining time before termination date is not enough to recover the portfolio value, the investor faces the risk (gap risk) that the portfolio value stays under the floor representing the acceptable minimum portfolio value. The cushion option which is introduced in this paper is shown to be a profitable choice for a DC plan participant who considers a risk of early withdrawal.
The findings show that for both short- and long-term pension periods, CPPI with cushion option increases the expected value of the wealth and reduces the standard deviation especially for the long-term period. This proposed approach can be utilized to depict the plausible investment strategies having certain guarantees in pension fund system. It should be noted that the market and income are assumed to have similar dynamics due to their close correlation in real life. The influence of market risk through inflation will have an real reduction on the value of the income. As a future avenue of research, we plan to generalize the salary model by accounting for imperfect correlation between labor income and financial markets. Another possible extension is to incorporate regime-switching dynamics to better capture the changing behavior of the economy over the long term. In addition to the generalizations in financial modeling, the stochastic modeling approach presented in this paper has potential applications beyond the domain of finance. Stochastic models, pricing approaches, and risk management techniques can be applied in various fields, such as management (resource allocation and decision-making), biology (population dynamics and genetic processes), environmental networks (sustainable resource management), and financial networks (systemic risk in interconnected institutions). Exploring these interdisciplinary connections could provide new avenues for future research.
Furthermore, our setup can be applied to the hybrid pension scheme for reducing funding shortfall which is prominent risk on calculation of reserve with respect to Solvency II framework by incorporating inflation and longevity risks.
Sketch of the proof of Proposition 1 (Gulveren, Reference Gulveren2016)

where Q is a risk neutral measure, under which the discounted stock price
$e^{-rt}S_{t}$ is a martingale. Therefore,

In order to get payoff, two conditions (A and B) need to be satisfied:
Condition A:




where
$Z_{\triangle t}=W^{Q}_{t_{k+1}}-W^{Q}_{t_{k}}$ and
$\frac{Z_{\triangle t}}{\sqrt(\triangle t)}=z\sim N(0,1)$.
Condition B:




where
$Z_{\triangle t}=W^{Q}_{t_{k+1}}-W^{Q}_{t_{k}}$ and
$\frac{Z_{\triangle t}}{\sqrt(\triangle t)}=z\sim N(0,1)$.
Under these conditions:


where



adding and substracting
$\frac{\sigma_{L}^{2}\triangle t}{2}$, we deduce

By change of variable
$y=z-\sigma_{L}^{2}\sqrt{\triangle t}$,
