Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T12:02:55.490Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Place-Based (In)formalization: A Bolivian Marketplace for Consumer Electronics and Global Brands

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2017

Juliane Müller*
Affiliation:
University of Munich (LMU), DE
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Trade in consumer electronics and household appliances in Bolivia operates mainly from popular marketplaces. Multinational corporations enter these once informal, now enhanced economies. This article analyses the expansion of global brands into urban street markets, together with the local branding of electronics and the advancement of popular traders along transnational commodity chains. I argue that these socio-spatial transitions offer a counterintuitive articulation between the informal and the formal. Looking at specific localities along the commodity chain from East Asia to Chile and Bolivia, one sees not mere formalization of informal economies as often expected nor a rampant informalization as attributed to current economic globalization, but piecemeal formalization of traders as much as a partial informalization of all actors involved.

En Bolivia, la venta de equipos electrónicos se realiza principalmente en mercados populares. Empresas transnacionales están operando en esos mismos lugares. Este artículo analiza la expansión de marcas globales en el comercio popular y la creación de marcas locales al mismo tiempo que el avance de comerciantes a lo largo de cadenas de acopio transnacionales. Mi argumento es que esas transiciones económico-espaciales marcan una articulación contra-intuitiva entre lo informal y lo formal. Enfocando localidades específicas a lo largo de la cadena comercial desde el Este de Asia hacia Chile y Bolivia, no se observa una mera formalización de la economía informal como muchas veces esperada ni una informalización total atribuida a procesos actuales de globalización, sino una formalización incompleta de comerciantes y una informalización parcial de todos los actores involucrados.

Type
Anthropology
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (CC-BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. See http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
Copyright
Copyright: © 2017 The Author(s)

Introduction

If you want to buy a camera, a laptop, or a washing machine in La Paz, Bolivia, it is very likely that you end up in a shopping precinct called Eloy Salmón. Urban residents of all social strata buy computers and household appliances in this very populated area located in the district of Max Paredes, northwest of the city center, an area that has had a strong influx of indigenous migrants from the countryside since the 1950s, especially those of Aymara descent from the departamento (region) of La Paz.Footnote 1 With the growth of this district, periodic fairs and closed markets have multiplied and a lively form of street trading has been created. People sell fresh and processed foods, fabric, clothes, and many other goods from fixed sites on the sidewalks and from semi-enclosed stalls. A dense network of seller organizations controls the distribution of selling spots and settle disputes. At first hand, this seems to resemble a classic streetscape of informal trade as described by Keith Hart four decades ago: small-scale, self-employed vendors who operate mainly outside state bureaucracy’s formalities and whose clients are, like them, lower-strata rural migrants in the city.

Yet marketplaces have undergone continuous change over recent decades. Street vendors have become shop owners, wholesale vendors, and importers; new traders have entered into lower levels of supply. Initial traders created footholds for others, and business diversified. Trade in foreign consumer electronics in particular has provided opportunities for economic mobility. The markets for electronic devices are located along Eloy Salmón and another street called Huyustus. Here, the built environment has significantly changed as the most successful traders have constructed galerías (shopping arcades). In reaction to this upgrading of street-level trade and the multiplication of retail shops, the global electronics companies Samsung, Sony, and LG have opened showrooms and sales divisions in the heart of popular commerce.

Moreover, Eloy Salmón’s younger retailers in their twenties and thirties now model themselves after Silicon Valley. They represent an urban, technologically and popular culturally savvy generation of traders, who diversify business strategies and offers in order to attract new buyers and external companies in the industry. They create additional services such as free repairs and home delivery, and place special emphasis on their knowledge and expertise in sales, adapt themselves to the presentational aesthetic of an upmarket clientele, seek institutional clients, and try to participate in public tenders. An example is Bernabé Saavedra, the grandson of one of the pioneer trader families in the area, who were first-generation migrants to the city in the 1950s. He studied business administration and worked temporarily at the telecommunications company ENTEL. With a friend from college, he founded the Internet portal www.eloysalmon.com.bo, and his goal is to be “the Amazon of Bolivia.” When asked about it, he admits that “the project is not very formalized yet” but that this is intentional. He wants it to emerge “in a garage as with them,” referring to Amazon, Facebook, and other new economy start-ups. His aim is to offer employment after investing in logistics and e-payment, which are the main challenges. Already today, the retail platform uses a range of products that are sold in the immediate vicinity of Eloy Salmón; however, it is mainly intended for the area’s dominant electronics division. It offers the individual dealers, who are not properly overseen by the state, the opportunity of presenting themselves on the Internet.

Initiatives and processes like those at Eloy Salmón question the notion of informality in a novel way. The concept of the informal economy has been prominent and debated in the academic and political record. It entered the debate in the 1970s as a way of thinking about the urban poor of the “Third World.” Keith Hart introduced the term in order to “persuade development economists to abandon the ‘unemployment’ idea and accept that there was more going on in the grassroots economy than their bureaucratic imagination allowed for” (Reference HartHart 2012, 3). In its original conception, as Hart himself acknowledges, it was a rather static, binary idea of the market versus the state, horizontal “popular self-organization” versus vertical organization (Reference HartHart 2012, 2).

In Latin America, such binary notions have been especially prominent as the discussion has become fused with debates about the transition between the traditional and the modern, dependency versus modernization, and social marginalization versus economic growth (Reference QuijanoQuijano 1998). The Regional Employment Program of the International Labor Organization for Latin America (PREALC) rapidly adopted the idea of the informal enterprise as linked to immediate livelihood needs, different from the capitalist enterprise and strategies of accumulation (Reference Portes and SchaufflerPortes and Schauffler 1993). Hernando de Soto (Reference De Soto1989) famously broke with the idea that informal activities are equated with economies at the poverty level, but immediately introduced another antagonism, that between state regulation and informality. In his account, informal entrepreneurs in the Andean countries are not only highly dynamic and competitive, but they would flourish unhindered if national regulations were simplified and taxes and customs duties lowered. These two perspectives—on the one hand structuralist approaches, Marxist and dependency scholars, and the ILO (Reference Matos MarMatos Mar 1984; Reference QuijanoQuijano 1998; Reference Lins RibeiroLins Ribeiro 2009); on the other hand legalist and liberal perspectives, De Soto and others—have shaped the debates on informal economies. In either perspective, the formal and the informal are seen as antagonistic insofar as the expansion of one entity displaces the other. Scholars stress that informalization is encroaching on the formal economy in times of neoliberal globalization (Reference HartHart 2012, among many others). Formalization is imagined as a culturally neutral process toward the meeting of international law, national standards, and industry conventions. Yet, both are not uniform processes, as unilateral models might let us think, but respond to national and regional histories and policies, as well as to peculiar practices of place. This article centers on such local peculiarities. Bolivian traders, while advancing their businesses, don’t follow the institutional path and cultural models of traditional business circles in their country. Such place-specific processes of formalization have important consequences on how we address and conceptualize popular economies in relation to economic globalization and international commerce.

In Bolivia, we observe an upgrading of popular enterprise without the dissolution of social and cultural peculiarities of place. The Eloy Salmón street as well as other marketplaces and commercial hubs in Bolivia and neighboring countries are more than abstract transfer and distribution points within a commodity chain; they are places where transnational connections and local markets are made through the mediation of traders with social and cultural attributes as well as economic ones.

In the remainder of this article, I further discuss the concept of the informal economy and related notions of “low-end globalization” and “place-based economy” before looking at the marketplace of Eloy Salmón as well as another popular commercial street in La Paz, and the free trade zone of Iquique (Northern Chile). In terms of methodology, I draw on ethnographic research conducted between 2013 and 2016. Over a total period of ten months, I closely observed economic exchange and social relations at both marketplaces in La Paz. I spent innumerable hours in traders’ shops and participated in local festivities. I accompanied traders on purchasing trips to border areas and to the Pacific port and free zone city of Iquique. I have also been in ongoing contact with corporate employees. A large part of the data interpreted here come from casual conversations at the marketplaces and at peoples’ workplaces, as well as from my observation of daily interactions between corporations, traders, and clients, and from participant observations at social events. In addition, I conducted semistructured interviews with traders and corporate sales staff.

Popular Economies and Cross-Border Trade in Latin America and the Andes

Ever since the intensification of rural-urban migration in Bolivia after the 1952 revolution, and the country’s debt crisis and structural adjustment in the mid-1980s that scaled back jobs in manufacturing and coincided with a serious drought in the highlands, small-scale self-employment, unprotected and hardly taxed by the state, has continued to increase.Footnote 2 Urban markets and cross-border trade sustain hundreds of thousands of Bolivian lives. Research on market exchange since the 1970s (especially in foodstuffs and other goods of daily necessity) has described the dense network of commercial ties, interwoven with kin and godparent relations that stretch between the countryside and the city, across provinces and ecological zones (Reference BuechlerBuechler 1978; Reference Buechler and BuechlerBuechler and Buechler 1996; Reference Tassi, Medeiros, Rodríguez Carmona and FerrufinoTassi et al. 2013). Women play a central role as trade intermediaries between the rural-indigenous and urban-mestizo world (Reference BabbBabb 1998; Reference Buechler, Miles and BuechlerBuechler 1997; Reference Buechler and BuechlerBuechler and Buechler 1996; Reference SeligmannSeligmann 1989; Reference ScarboroughScarborough 2010). Fewer studies have focused on cross-border trade in manufactured goods and contraband, although recent research has addressed the dynamics of small-scale activities between Peru and Bolivia (Reference ØdegaardØdegaard 2008), Argentina and Brazil (Reference GrimsonGrimson 2002), and at the Triple Border of Paraguay, Argentina, and Brazil (Reference AguiarAguiar 2010; Reference Rabossi, Mathews, Lins Ribeiro and Alba VegaRabossi 2012).

Historically, market exchange in the Andes reaches back to the early colonial period (Reference Larson, Harris and TandeterLarson, Harris, and Tandeter 1995; Reference ManganMangan 2005; Reference LangerLanger 2009), and to precolonial times in case of the Northern Andes (Reference Ramírez, Larson, Harris and TandeterRamírez 1995). Ethnohistorical research has shown the depth of cross-Andean trade, embedded in social rather than in state institutions. Still, the growing scope and intensity of trading activities in Bolivia since the 1980s is generally explained in the context of structural adjustment, the informalization of Latin American economies, and privatization and liberalization on a global scale (Reference Itzigsohn, Fernández-Kelly and ShefnerItzigsohn 2008; Reference Fernández-Kelly and ShefnerFernández-Kelly and Shefner 2008; Reference GalembaGalemba 2008). Yet it can also be interpreted as a resurgence of native commerce as traders and service providers make use of novel opportunities: tradeable goods that appear in rapid succession, manufactured, showcased, and sold in and from East Asia. Although long-distance trade is not a new phenomenon, today ever more people tap into transnational commerce and world markets (Reference Smart and SmartSmart and Smart 2005).Footnote 3 Brazilians, Bolivians, and other traders and trading families in Latin America reach out to neighboring countries and China for the acquisition of goods (Reference Rabossi, Mathews, Lins Ribeiro and Alba VegaRabossi 2012; Reference Aguiar, Mathews, Ribeiro and Alba VegaAguiar 2012; Reference Tassi, Medeiros, Rodríguez Carmona and FerrufinoTassi et al. 2013). They are creating “global commodity chains from below” (Reference Pinheiro-MachadoPinheiro-Machado 2013) but do not necessarily remain at the bottom. In the contemporary economic conjuncture, trading becomes a way of upward mobility as people move into commodity sectors with higher profit margins, and source merchandise transnationally.

Within this emerging field of research, Gustavo Lins Ribeiro and others (Reference Lins RibeiroLins Ribeiro 2009; Reference Mathews, Lins Ribeiro and Alba VegaMathews, Lins Ribeiro, and Alba Vega 2012) have recently introduced the term “low-end globalization” (also called “globalization from below” and “popular globalization,” Reference Lins RibeiroLins Ribeiro 2009, Reference Lins Ribeiro2012) to emphasize the fact that these economic actors are outwardly oriented in their purchasing strategies, regionally and even globally well connected, but differ from powerful states, international institutions, and big corporations that dominate “high-end” globalization. “Low-end globalization” is conceptualized as a series of knots (popular markets) interconnected through networks of goods (mostly low-budget) and through traders who participate in globalization and appropriate its commodities, but do so from a subordinate position (Reference Lins RibeiroLins Ribeiro 2012, 37). Whereas Lins Ribeiro emphasizes the (albeit implicit) political, nonhegemonic dimension of these commercial circuits, others (Reference Rabossi, Mathews, Lins Ribeiro and Alba VegaRabossi 2012; Reference Mathews and YangMathews and Yang 2012) are more concerned with the social logic of commercial circuits, or with similarities to what has been seen as the informal economy. Indeed, a key idea of low-end globalization is to take the notion of informal trading beyond the confines of the nation-state, to move from the national economy to one single global economy: “We must speak not of the ‘informal economy’ in this society or that one, but rather of ‘globalization from below’ encompassing all societies” (Reference Mathews, Alba Vega, Mathews, Lins Ribeiro and Alba VegaMathews and Alba Vega 2012, 3).

My article engages with this literature, but I wish to partly readdress the debate. As others have remarked (Reference RabossiRabossi 2008; Reference Bandyopadhyay, Mathews, Ribeiro and Alba VegaBandyopadhyay 2012), differentiating between actors of high-end and low-end globalization—as if they were located in distinctive economic spheres—might hinder the comprehension of the multiple intersections of commercial worlds. As popular economies are usually highly visible in urban spaces, and formal enterprises are hidden in office blocks, corporate actors are more difficult to access and comprehend. Grasping globalization from above “through statistics” (Reference Mathews, Alba Vega, Mathews, Lins Ribeiro and Alba VegaMathews and Alba Vega 2012, 5) is only a tiny first step toward the analysis of the powerful players and their hypermobile capital flows in current globalization.

As transnational corporations move into popular marketplaces and local entrepreneurs upgrade their businesses both locally and transnationally, the notion of separate economic worlds must be questioned. Traders build shopping galleries and office blocks, whereas corporate employees go out into street markets. At the same marketplace of Eloy Salmón, original brands and copies coexist. The availability of falsified and even stolen devices in some areas, side streets and more hidden spaces, doesn’t hinder the corporations from doing business with those traders who upgrade and, at least partly, sell brands with an original serial number.Footnote 4

The shopping precinct of Eloy Salmón is a knot of commercial transaction in the electronics commodity chain from East Asia to Bolivia, and it is more than that. As popular markets in other parts of Latin America and all over the world, Eloy Salmón is a locality, the “anchor of politics, identity, community, and practice” (Reference AguiarAguiar 2013, 251). This anthropological notion of locality implies that the “everyday work of chain [and market] making” (Reference ÇalişkanÇalişkan 2010, 9) is situated at places that have their own history of trading. Cultural practices, visions, and evaluations of the local trade shape interactions and eventually feed back into commodity chains up- and downstream.Footnote 5

Informal Economy and Place

The importance of place for economic performance has been increasingly recognized across the social sciences, including geography and economics. The local clustering of small, complementary enterprises is assumed to be a promising path to growth and innovation for national economies worldwide (Reference PorterPorter 2000). However, informal economies are rarely approached or analyzed as economic clusters, especially when they rely heavily on commercial activities. Mirroring the early informal sector debate, they are viewed as low-skill and low-investment, and therefore deemed to possess low business potential. They do not fit the conventional top-down and policy-oriented literature (Reference PorterPorter 2000; for Latin America, see Reference Felzensztein, Stringer, Benson-Rea and FreemanFelzensztein et al. 2014; Reference Giuliani, Pietrobelli and RabellottiGiuliani, Pietrobelli, and Rabellotti 2005). If they are mentioned, they appear as “survival clusters” with few possibilities of withstanding the winds of change (Reference Altenburg and Meyer-StamerAltenburg and Meyer-Stamer 1999). However, existing spatial clustering of commercial activities are far more heterogeneous than defined in the business literature.

Without being able to discuss this literature in great depth, I want to make some observations about popular marketplaces as economic clusters. The physical proximity of traders enables the exchange of tacit information and practical knowledge, and low entry and transaction costs apply to small-scale production and informal trade in the global South just as to migrants’ businesses and trade diasporas worldwide. Minority businesses often organize territorially in the outskirts of cities and certain working-class neighborhoods, where they build a dense network of social interactions, which has the potential to create solidarity, trust, and cooperation (Reference Pérez SáinzPérez Sáinz 1998; Reference Itzigsohn, Fernández-Kelly and ShefnerItzigsohn 2008; Reference Colloredo-MansfeldColloredo-Mansfeld 2011). Self-employment is an option for rural indigenous and international migrants and their offspring, who suffer from structural disadvantages and ethnic discrimination in society and national labor markets (Reference ZhouZhou 2004; Reference Portes, Haller and GuarnizoPortes, Haller, and Guarnizo 2002). It is argued that such spatially clustered activities can remain low-skill and low-margin work and therefore marginalized from global economic developments, or they can generate skill formation and upgrading of business (Reference Pérez SáinzPérez Sáinz 1998). In fact, both types often coexist in the same geographic space. It is not always as the literature assumes, that one cluster becomes high-end and the other remains precarious. It is at the same marketplace that we find a Bernabé Saavedra, whose dream of the new economy doesn’t seem that unrealistic, and micro-scale traders who rent tiny sidewalk stalls and minuscule shops and struggle to make a living.

A dynamic approach, as exemplified by Werbner (Reference Werbner and Léo-Paul2007), that looks at interfirm relations and gradual transformations of specific sites is able to account for the generation of markets and the often-sudden visibility of popular and migrant economies. Still, from a cultural anthropological perspective, there is more going on. If we look at not only economic but cultural investments in a given location, we can trace and conceptualize a “place-based economy” that “reframes the mutual dependence recognized in cluster initiatives” (Reference Colloredo-Mansfeld and AntrosioColloredo-Mansfeld and Antrosio 2009, 154). The notion of a place-based economy pushes the approach toward an understanding of the cluster as a locality where economic activity is embedded in social networks and institutions, cultural work, collective perceptions, and shared meanings, as well as processes of socioeconomic differentiation. Before exemplifying such a locality (though the ethnographic analysis of Eloy Salmón), I will give some background information on this shopping precinct, the related wholesale market of Huyustus, and on the commodity chain of consumer electronics into Bolivia.

Popular Marketplaces for Consumer Electronics in La Paz

La Paz, the seat of the Bolivian government, is a traditional commercial center of the country, located at the intersection of the historical routes between the Andean highlands and Pacific coast. The city of El Alto emerged above the basin of La Paz as a result of waves of immigration since the 1950s; together the cities form a densely populated metropolitan area of 1.6 million people. It is one of the main distribution points for electronic and digital devices in Bolivia (Reference Tassi, Medeiros, Rodríguez Carmona and FerrufinoTassi et al. 2013, 101).

Since the 1950s, many migrants who came from communities near the Peruvian border started to work as street vendors in the five-hundred-meter-long Eloy Salmón. One of these traders, Fernández,Footnote 6 now in his sixties, remembers when sewing machines from Peru were first sold. He started off with a rudimentary roadside stand once he started working with his wife, who comes from a family of traders. Both have experienced the developments of the last decades: in the 1980s radios, black-and-white TVs, record players, and tape recorders supplemented sewing machines and typewriters, batteries, and other early products. In the 1990s, color TVs, stereos, and household appliances such as refrigerators and computers were added, before business began in the 2000s with laptops, mobile phones, and tablets. The import routes changed depending on the product and date. Ángel Fernández had traveled with colleagues to Panama (the free trade zone of Colón), to Miami, and lastly to Chile (free trade zone of Iquique). Others have made their way to Brazil and China, or order directly via the Internet and WhatsApp. As the Eloy Salmón traders have specialized in retail, and the once informal street market has evolved into a shopping precinct for all social classes, traders find less time to travel. It is the Huyustus market that has specialized in imports and wholesaling.

Huyustus is a large bazaar-like market, initially emerging periodically as a feria (fair) but now permanent. For a length of over two kilometers, one stall fits alongside another in three parallel rows. Huyustus is synonymous with this open-air marketplace, where the products alternate in succession. At the top end, consumer electronics are sold from stalls and shops that opened in the surrounding area. Traders have relatively small shops, despite the fact that 48-pixel TV screens, sound systems, or laptops are rather bulky. Goods are warehoused in adjacent streets. This whole area emerged in the 1980s, later than electronics sales in Eloy Salmón. Small retailers, who had family ties in places along the train route from La Paz to Arica and along the highways to Chile, began to travel to purchase goods; later they worked as couriers (piloteros) (Reference Tassi, Medeiros, Rodríguez Carmona and FerrufinoTassi et al. 2013, 120). They handled logistical matters between the Chilean ports and La Paz, including the customs formalities, and this knowledge has brought benefits.

The Huyustus market is a bit farther from the city center than Eloy Salmón and a little less accessible for upper-level individuals, although clients are as heterogeneous as in Eloy Salmón. Remarkably, supermarkets in the wealthier parts of La Paz also purchase consumer electronics from these popular wholesalers. It seems analytically unfruitful to distinguish formal distributers and stores from informal importers and retailers, given the high level of interrelation of the sectors. Both corporate and popular retailers buy from importers and wholesalers who are involved in contraband and avoid paying customs duties and sales taxes.

At both places, Eloy Salmón and Huyustus, businesses are informal in some areas (customs duties, sales and income taxes, commercial uses of public space), but formal in others (registration with municipal and national authorities, business licenses; membership in officially recognized traders’ association).Footnote 7 As has been shown for other cases, the local and national governments (Reference CrossCross 1998), in reaction to organized interests and collective struggles of traders, and their own need for political support, negotiate the implementation or nonimplementation of the law, which leads to a situation of “semiformal recognition” of these businesses (Reference Smart, Zerilli and NoniniSmart and Zerilli 2014). This recognition from above is enhanced by East Asian corporations that directly engage with the traders. Indeed, “corporate formalization” builds on these previously accorded “extralegal norms” (Reference Smart, Zerilli and NoniniSmart and Zerilli 2014, 229) between the La Paz local government, certain ministries, and trader’s organizations (Reference MüllerMüller 2016).

Free Trade Zones and Downgraded Formality

Free Trade Zones have been recommended since the 1950s by international institutions such as the World Bank and the US Agency for International Development (USAID). In South America, such zones were promoted by the authoritarian regimes of the 1960s to 1980s. The Free Trade Area of Ciudad del Este (Paraguay) was founded in 1960 by dictator Alfredo Stroessner; the legal basis for the two dockside free trade zones in Chile (Iquique and Punta del Este) was adopted under Augusto Pinochet in 1975. The Bolivian free zone of Cobija on the border with Brazil was founded in 1965 during the co-administration of military rulers Barrientos and Ovedo. These zoning projects, as in the case of Tacna (Peru), have aimed to give economic stimulus to the periphery of nation-states. Customs and tax exemptions, simultaneously furnished with infrastructure, were meant to accelerate the movement of goods, which would potentially attract international investors.

These territorially bounded zones of free trade can be considered South America’s “neoliberal exceptions” (Reference OngOng 2006) as they were established in a period when import substitution still prevailed. However, the zones’ status as customs extraterritorialities has remained surprisingly unaltered by the dramatic shifts in national economic policies and the return to state regulation among leftist governments in the region, and despite integration agreements such as MERCOSUR (Common Southern Market) and CAN (Andean Community of Nations). Although mainly intended as spots of industrial development and export, the zones have been mainly used by South American traders and import intermediaries from all over the world.

The free port and free trade zone of Iquique (Zona Franca de Iquique, or Zofri) is an international import and re-export hub for foreign manufactured goods. It is an enclosed compound of streets with hundreds of shops and galpones (warehouses). Small- and medium-sized entrepreneurs and family firms from around the world have been attracted by the fiscal incentives, minimal regulations, and the business environment of the zona franca. It is a multisectorial, ethnically heterogeneous trading center. Fewer than half of the registered companies are owned by Chileans.

Iquique has been a strategic place for Bolivian traders. By traveling the twelve-hour bus ride from the Bolivian highlands all the way down to Iquique, traders gained access to the latest consumer goods. They purchased wholesale from the international intermediaries and distributers, accumulating experiences and making contacts that have enabled them to expand the scope of their operations. Multinational corporations, before being present in Bolivia, have established branches in Zofri, where they got to know the Bolivian commercial partners. It is in the context of this heterogeneous commercial world of small family firms and big corporations, of businesses from around the world interested in South American markets, that Samsung and the like first made contact with the needs and customs of Bolivian traders. Instead of dealing with a handful of big retailers and department store chains (as electronics corporations would do in Chile and the global North; see Reference TsingTsing 2009 on Walmart-type supply-chain capitalism), they adapted to their new clients’ peculiarities, making deals with intermediaries and offering promotional banquets and other unusual incentives for small-scale Bolivian traders (Reference MüllerMüller 2018).

Zofri Iquique marks the first encounter of big enterprise and popular trade in an overall environment of downgraded formality associated with free trade zones, port free zones, and special economic zones around the world (Reference McCallaMcCalla 1990; Reference EasterlingEasterling 2014). We observe the convergence of bottom-up forms of economic informality and top-down evasion of state legislation that also extends into Bolivia. In the following, I analyze how the upscaling of popular business practices is concomitant with an ongoing politics of place rather than an orientation toward the national economy.

Local Upgrading and the Development of a Prestigious Shopping Precinct

Different transnational commodity chains and networks end up at the marketplace of Eloy Salmón. Eloy Salmón has been transformed from a place where everything from staples to manufactured goods was sold from open-air stalls and out of small shops, into a retail area for mainly consumer electronics. With the exception of stalls for food and beverages, everyone now sells and repairs household appliances, TV, computers, and the like. The trade in consumer electronics is spreading farther and farther down the road and into the side streets. Eloy Salmón is five blocks long, and in 2013 nearly all shops in the first three blocks sold electronics. In 2014, lively construction activities in the fourth section were noticeable. Four new buildings have already been put into operation; two of them are being used by a single company, which is a novelty, as the stores on Eloy Salmón are traditionally small. One of the buildings is rented by the official representation of Chinese corporation Changhong, the other is used by Dismac, a company from the formal sector of the more prosperous and “Western” city of Santa Cruz de la Sierra. The two other new buildings are galerías (galleries or shopping arcades).

Retail spaces of the galería type have existed since the 1990s. In contrast to urban policies and corporate investments that create “modern” shopping malls by destroying or marginalizing popular marketplaces (Reference Applbaum and CarrierApplbaum 2005; Reference MilgramMilgram 2015), in La Paz traders have themselves changed the environment by constructing shopping arcades. Instead of top-down projects that replace businesses as a way of formalizing them, in Eloy Salmón local traders themselves incrementally upgraded retail spaces and practices. According to the Association of Traders of Appliances of Eloy Salmón, there are now about 650 traders in the area of Eloy Salmón and its side streets; an increasing number of them operate inside these multiple-floor galleries that have significantly expanded the retail space available. While existing houses were at first simply converted into galleries by property-owning families who sublet retail space to individual dealers, in the late 1990s Ángel Fernández and his wife, together with thirty other traders, built one of the first new shopping arcades in Eloy Salmón. It is a five-floor building; the entrance area of the arcade, called Gran Poder, is bright and welcoming and the intermediate routes are free of stalls. Gran Poder is aimed at customers who deem this to be a sign of reliability and transparency. The gallery has the highest sales rate for devices with the manufacturers’ official serial numbers and warranties. Only those goods that the corporations can digitally track back all the way from Eloy Salmón to the factory have them. The serial number is a source of legitimacy vis-à-vis the global brands. A growing number of traders, although not properly registered and taxed within state institutions, make sure to deal with devices that are formally recognized by Samsung, Sony, and LG. This practice is stimulated by the corporations, which offer an extra payment to shop owners and vendors for every item sold of this kind.

The aforementioned Bernabé Saavedra utilizes the increased corporate recognition and public reputation of the Eloy Salmón to build his online retail platform: “From the beginning I wanted to include the entire Eloy Salmón because Eloy Salmón is a well-known market nationally and internationally” (interview, La Paz, October 2014; my own translation). As traders from Eloy Salmón have expanded their activities and networks, this street has become known as a market with an extraordinary variety of products at good prices. The board of directors of the Association of Traders claims that Eloy Salmón “has taken shape regionally and nationally” and that eight out of ten La Paz inhabitants have visited it for purchases.Footnote 8 Traders say they are even recognized in China, where mentioning the name of the marketplace transmits familiarity and reliability. They see the US multinational retailer Radio Shack, with its two branches in La Paz, as the only competitor to their market presence, thereby comparing the colorful street with its hundreds of traders with the franchise stores of a single company. The good reputation, the “prestige” of Eloy Salmón as the traders call it, acts as a collective trademark here. The turnover of individual traders relies on the reputation of the entire street and its attractiveness for a diversity of customers. This process is especially remarkable as popular markets are often equated with marginal people and lack of prestige; in fact it seems that former La Paz distributers of European descent thought that selling in Aymara markets would harm the good reputation of Western goods (Reference Tassi, Medeiros, Rodríguez Carmona and FerrufinoTassi et al. 2013, 207).

Saavedra’s effort to create an Internet platform and online commerce for Eloy Salmón builds on the generalized perception of the shopping precinct as the marketplace for electronics in La Paz, where one can create and endorse a marca, a brand. Rosvania, a family firm of household appliances, today formalized as a “Sociedad de Responsabilidad Limitada” (SRL) but grown out of the small-scale retail activities of the now wife and co-owner, a first-generation trader of Eloy Salmón, owns five different shops along the shopping street (and four others elsewhere in Bolivia), but only makes 8 percent of its profits there. The husband and associate director explains: “It is for the image” (interview, La Paz, September 2013). Although the main business operations of Rosvania take place in other markets and notably not in retail but wholesale, being present in Eloy Salmón is essential for being seen and perceived by the competition and customers. The fact that multinational corporations and companies from the city of Santa Cruz look to maintain physical proximity to the precinct confirms the traders’ notions of prestige. These actors from outside also frame their presence in Eloy Salmón as a marketing issue. The commercial director of Dismac, the aforementioned store for household appliances in Santa Cruz de la Sierra, expresses his opinion that “people want a brand” and that in Santa Cruz they have managed to establish their store brand; in La Paz they try to do so by constantly amplifying their retail space in Eloy Salmon (interview, La Paz, September 2013).

The prestige of Eloy Salmon has to do with qualities that go beyond those of a shopping precinct. It rests on more than commercial achievements. It has material as well as cultural and religious dimensions. The growth of the trade is associated with the growth of the brotherhoods and festivals: “The Morenada dance grows with the commerce” is heard again and again. The local patron saint Jesús del Gran Poder, celebrated during an entire week each June with processions that cover the whole city, is located in a parish in a side street of Eloy Salmón (Reference Barragán and CárdenasBarragán and Cárdenas 2009; Reference HimpeleHimpele 2003; Reference TassiTassi 2010).

The traders of Eloy Salmón have created a sophisticated festive cycle around the saint. Each of the ten “blocks” (bloques), subunits of the Brotherhood Morenada de la Eloy Salmón, puts on its own celebration throughout the year consisting of Mass and a procession, followed by a reception, dinner, and dancing at a nearby restaurant. Morenada is the most prestigious Bolivian folklore dance, with the heaviest and most expensive costumes. Almost all members of each block dance in the procession, women’s chola costumes changing from year to year.Footnote 9 While the movements and steps of the Morenada style hardly vary, the lyrics are individual. The block of Suma Maquineros, for example, sings of their beloved street, which they have proudly “cofounded” through the distribution of mechanical parts and batteries, with the refrain “Siempre de la Eloy Salmón” (“Always from Eloy Salmón”). Their matraca (rattle), a small percussion instrument that all the dancers of the Morenada hold in their right hands, has the form of a large battery. Moreover, processions will always start at the nearby church of Jesús de Gran Poder, march along the surrounding streets until they come to a halt amid the shops. The dancers literally celebrate with the goods; beer crates are stacked up next to refrigerator boxes in the immediate vicinity of the revelers. It is this analogy of the circulation of goods and reciprocal serving, and this juxtaposition of the material and spiritual, which creates additional prestige in the eyes of the traders.Footnote 10 As a response, the corporations have broadened their marketing efforts to include support for local fiestas. Samsung, Sony, and LG all sponsor musical instruments, bands, and banquets.

In sum, by enhancing the built environment and their business practices, traders at Eloy Salmón have created an enduring shopping precinct with the reputation of being the most important marketplace for electronic devices in La Paz. Global brands and national stores have entered the marketplace to be seen and known by Bolivian consumers. They choose Eloy Salmón in order to create and enhance their brand. This commercial branding, consisting of marketing strategies to differentiate one’s products from others with similar qualities (Reference MalefytMalefyt 2009), counts on prior economic and cultural investments of local traders. The corporations try to capture the economic value of the street’s prestige; so does entrepreneur Saavedra by creating a virtual version of the physical Eloy Salmón. Yet the symbolic value of the street is not exclusive but inclusive of all businesses. Even traders who do not stand out, who do not have the ability, capital, or social resources to build an individual commercial reputation, can still profit from the street’s public image. The branding initiatives of both corporate and popular enterprises rely on prior collective investments that have been economic as well as cultural.

Conclusions

Marketplaces such as Eloy Salmón have been conventionally seen as marginal compared with national economic development, as merely temporary solutions for urban unemployment, a means but not an end, only useful until formal employment would be created. Yet Eloy Salmón has remained. It has developed from street trading into an upscale retail spot of shopping arcades known nationwide as an area that has the entire range of consumer electronics on display. Although younger traders are increasingly differentiating and upgrading their businesses, they still rely on earlier cultural investments in the built environment, civic events, and the collective reputation.

These practices mark an upgraded informality, as the traders’ activities are not primarily directed toward the national economy and the state but toward local customs and the symbolic value of place. Their social engagement is not directed toward traditional entrepreneurial circles but toward the immediate environment. Practices mark a downgraded formality as traders do not need compliance with state regulations in order to meet corporate standards and business practices. They sell goods with manufacturers’ serial numbers, upgrade retail areas, and employ professional branding strategies without being taken over by established business sectors, and while still being considered informal by national political actors and traditional elites. They build not so much on the official authorization of the state but on corporate recognition of their practices and shops.

In sum, the East Asian–Bolivian distribution network for consumer electronics reveals an encompassing downgrading of formal economic activity (at the free zone of Iquique and in Bolivia) in parallel with a new legitimacy of popular enterprises. Here, two socio-spatial transitions are at work: (1) The sociocultural formalization of an economic cluster in the way that intergenerational investments in prestige and civic ritual form a “place-based economy” (Reference Colloredo-Mansfeld and AntrosioColloredo-Mansfeld and Antrosio 2009); (2) an upgrading of individual business operations created and enhanced by multinational corporations and national companies that actively engage with popular traders.

The processes show that the informal is not antagonistic or hostile to the formal; popular traders and entrepreneurs do not necessarily remain marginal or have to be taken up in what is conventionally perceived as the formal economy; they persist, formalize partially, build up place-based economies, and eventually thrive along transnational commodity chains. Traders not only add economic value (Reference BabbBabb 1998); their social institutions and cultural investments are potent organizers of the economy. This urges us to rethink the dualism of the supposedly modern, contractual, and legible on the one hand, and the supposedly traditional, oral, and disruptive on the other. Although the dichotomy between the formal and the informal, and between high-end and low-end globalization, might be seen as merely analytical (Reference Guha-Khasnobis, Kanbur, Ostrom, Guha-Khasnobis, Kanbur and OstromGuha-Khasnobis, Kanbur, and Ostrom 2006); ultimately, these conceptual models still rest on the idea of two halves of a social whole, either of the national or the global economy (see Reference HartHart 2012).

What we observe instead are highly complex transnational commodity networks and a diversity of economic actors interacting at local marketplaces. Comparable processes are happening in Latin America and other parts of the world as multinational corporations, especially from East Asia, search for new markets and tap into popular trading. We might have to think of concepts other than that of the informal economy, and terms other than uniform informalization (or neoliberalization) in order to grasp such socio-spatial transitions. To begin with, an ethnographic understanding of a place-based economy is one such approach. Other concepts should be added in order to address and evaluate the cultural dynamics and economic and political consequences of linkages between corporate and popular enterprises in world trade.

Acknowledgements

This article was born out of my postdoctoral research at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. I am very grateful to the Anthropology Department for discussions on several issues raised here, and especially to Rudi Colloredo-Mansfeld for his critical reading and very useful suggestions made on earlier versions of the text. Thank you also to the two German and four Bolivian students who were my fieldwork assistants during a month in 2013. The anonymous reviewers made very productive comments.

Footnotes

1 Aymara is the second largest indigenous group in Bolivia. In the census of 2001 1.287.627 persons (of a total of 5.076.251) identified as Aymara (INE 2001).

2 The revolution of 1952 and liberation of indigenous rural population from bonded labor on plantations generated internal migration movements of new dimensions.

3 The growth of popular trade is also a byproduct of the international economy of subcontracting and the rise of China as factory for the world (Pérez-Sáinz 1998).

4 The corporations claim that they hardly see knockoffs in Eloy Salmón. However, they can be found in the side streets and narrow pathways between Eloy Salmon and nearby markets. As they usually have stickers but no markings of the brand names, falsified consumer electronics, with the exception of mobile phones, seem easier to detect than counterfeits of other finished goods.

5 This approach has been informed by “the cultural turn” in economic analysis, an interdisciplinary movement within the social sciences (for an overview, see Reference Amin and ThriftAmin and Thrift 2004).

6 Name changed.

7 Popular traders with a fixed stall or rented or owned shop, be they importers, wholesalers, or retailers or all at the same time, are in the great majority one-person enterprises. As such they are registered with the local administration, and some also hold a national tax identification number; however they are often undervalued and sales transactions normally go untaxed.

8 Other sources verify this assertion.

9 The chola costume is a multilayered skirt associated with rural-urban market women all over Bolivia. Festive polleras in La Paz are very expensive, women named a price around US$1000 in 2013 and 2014.

10 For the cosmological significance of abundance among traders of the southern Andes and its association with the circulation of goods, ideas of reciprocity, and prosperity, see Reference TassiTassi 2010; Reference ØdegaardØdegaard 2011.

References

Aguiar, José Carlos G. 2010. Stretching the Border: Smuggling Practices and the Control of Illegality in South America. New Voices Series 6. Santiago de Chile: Global Consortium of Security Transformation.Google Scholar
Aguiar, José Carlos G. 2012. “‘They Come from China’: Pirate CDs in Mexico in Transnational Perspective.” In Globalization from Below: The World’s Other Economy, edited by Mathews, Gordon, Ribeiro, Gustavo Lins, and Alba Vega, Carlos, 3653. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Aguiar, José Carlos G. 2013. “Smugglers, Fayuqueros, Piratas: Transitory Commodities and Illegality in the Trade of Pirated CDs in Mexico.” Political and Legal Anthropological Review 36 (2): 249265. DOI: 10.1111/plar.12025CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altenburg, Tilman, and Meyer-Stamer, Jörg. 1999. “How to Promote Clusters? Policy Experiences from Latin America.” World Development 27 (9): 16931713. DOI: 10.1016/S0305-750X(99)00081-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amin, Ash, and Thrift, Nigel, eds. 2004. The Blackwell Cultural Economy Reader. Malden, MA: Blackwell. DOI: 10.1002/9780470774274CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Applbaum, Kalman. 2005. “The Anthropology of Markets.” In A Handbook of Economic Anthropology, edited by Carrier, James G., 275289. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. DOI: 10.4337/9781845423469.00029Google Scholar
Babb, Florence E. 1998. Between Field and Cooking Pot: The Political Economy of Marketwomen in Peru. Austin: University of Texas Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandyopadhyay, Ritajyoti. 2012. “In the Shadow of the Mall: Street Hawking in Global Calcutta.” In Globalization from Below: The World’s Other Economy, edited by Mathews, Gordon, Ribeiro, Gustavo Lins, and Alba Vega, C., 171185. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Barragán, Rossana, and Cárdenas, Cleverth, eds. 2009. Gran Poder: La Morenada. Colección Fiesta Popular Paceña, vol. 3. La Paz: Instituto de Estudios Bolivianos; Universidad Mayor de San Andrés.Google Scholar
Buechler, Hans, and Buechler, Judith-Maria. 1996. The World of Sofía Velasquez: The Autobiography of a Bolivian Market Vendor. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Buechler, Judith-Maria. 1978. “The Dynamics of the Market in La Paz, Bolivia.” Urban Anthropology 7 (4): 343360.Google Scholar
Buechler, Judith-Maria. 1997. “The Visible and Vocal Politics of Female Traders and Small-Scale Producers in La Paz, Bolivia.” In Women and Economic in Change: Andean Perspectives, edited by Miles, Ann and Buechler, Hans C., 7587. Society of Latin American Anthropology Publication Series. Washington, DC: American Anthropological Association.Google Scholar
Çalişkan, Koray. 2010. Market Threads: How Cotton Farmers and Traders Create a Global Commodity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.1515/9781400833924CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colloredo-Mansfeld, Rudi. 2011. “Work, Cultural Resources, and Community Commodities in the Global Economy.” Anthropology of Work Review 32 (2): 5162. DOI: 10.1111/j.1548-1417.2011.01058.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colloredo-Mansfeld, Rudi, and Antrosio, Jason. 2009. “Economic Clusters or Cultural Commons? The Limits of Competitive-Driven Development in the Ecuadorian Andes.” Latin American Research Review 44 (1): 132157. DOI: 10.1353/lar.0.0070CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cross, John C. 1998. Informal Politics: Street Vendors and the State in Mexico City. Stanford: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Soto, Hernando. 1989. The Other Path. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Easterling, Keller. 2014. Extrastatecraft: The Power of Infrastructure Space. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Felzensztein, Christian, Stringer, Christina, Benson-Rea, Maureen, and Freeman, Susan. 2014. “International Marketing Strategies in Industrial Clusters: Insights from the Southern Hemisphere.” Journal of Business Research 67 (5): 837846. DOI: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.07.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Kelly, Patricia, and Shefner, Jon. 2008. Out of the Shadows: Political Action and the Informal Economy in Latin America. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Galemba, Rebecca B. 2008. “Informal and Illicit Entrepreneurs: Fighting for a Place in the Neoliberal Economic Order.” Anthropology of Work Review 29 (2): 1925. DOI: 10.1111/j.1548-1417.2008.00010.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Giuliani, Elisa, Pietrobelli, Carlo, and Rabellotti, Roberta. 2005. “Upgrading in Global Value Chains: Lessons from Latin American Clusters.” World Development 33 (4): 549573. DOI: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.01.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grimson, Alejandro. 2002. “Hygiene Wars on the Mercosur Border: Local and National Agency in Uruguaiana (Brazil) and Paso de los Libres (Argentina).” Identities: Global Studies in Culture and Power 9 (2): 151172. DOI: 10.1080/10702890212202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guha-Khasnobis, Basudeb, Kanbur, Ravi, and Ostrom, Elinor. 2006. “Beyond Formality and Informality.” In Linking the Formal and Informal Economy: Concepts and Policies, edited by Guha-Khasnobis, B., Kanbur, R., and Ostrom, E., 118. New York: Oxford University Press. DOI: 10.1093/0199204764.003.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Keith. 2012. “How the Informal Economy Took Over the World. The Memory Bank. A New Commonwealth – Version 5.0.” http://thememorybank.co.uk/2012/10/17/the-informalization-of-the-world-economy/ (accessed May 7, 2015).Google Scholar
Himpele, Jeff D. 2003. “The Gran Poder Parade and the Social Movement of the Aymara Middle Class: A Video Essay.” Visual Anthropology 16 (2–3): 207243. DOI: 10.1080/08949460310019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Itzigsohn, José. 2008. “Neoliberalism, Markets, and Informal Grassroots Economies.” In Out of the Shadows: Political Action and the Informal Economy in Latin America, edited by Fernández-Kelly, Patricia and Shefner, Jon, 8196. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Langer, Erick D. 2009. “Bringing the Economic Back In: Andean Indians and the Construction of the Nation-State in Nineteenth-Century Bolivia.” Journal of Latin American Studies 47: 527551. DOI: 10.1017/S0022216X09990174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larson, Brooke, Harris, Olivia, and Tandeter, Enrique, eds. 1995. Ethnicity, Markets, and Migration in the Andes: At the Crossroads of History and Anthropology. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Lins Ribeiro, Gustavo. 2009. “Non-hegemonic Globalizations: Alter-native Transnational Processes and Agents.” Anthropological Theory 9 (3): 297329. DOI: 10.1177/1463499609346985CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lins Ribeiro, Gustavo. 2012. “La globalización popular y el sistema mundial no-hegemónico.” Nueva Sociedad 241: 3662.Google Scholar
Malefyt, Timothy De Waal. 2009. “Understanding the Rise of Consumer Ethnography: Branding Technomethodologies in the New Economy.” American Anthropologist 111 (2): 201210. DOI: 10.1111/j.1548-1433.2009.01113.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mangan, Jane E. 2005. Trading Roles: Gender, Ethnicity, and the Urban Economy in Colonial Potosí. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. DOI: 10.1215/9780822386667Google Scholar
Mathews, Gordon, and Alba Vega, Carlos. 2012. “Introduction: What Is Globalization from Below?” In Globalization from Below: The World’s Other Economy, edited by Mathews, G., Lins Ribeiro, G., and Alba Vega, C., 116. New York: Routledge. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139013758.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathews, Gordon, Lins Ribeiro, Gustavo, and Alba Vega, Carlos, eds. 2012. Globalization from Below: The World’s Other Economy. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathews, Gordon, and Yang, Yang. 2012. “How Africans Pursue Low-End Globalization in Hong Kong and Mainland China.” Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 41 (2): 95120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matos Mar, José. 1984. Desborde popular y crisis del Estado. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanos.Google Scholar
McCalla, Robert J. 1990. “The Geographical Spread of the Free Trade Zones Associated with Ports.” Geoforum 21 (1): 121134. DOI: 10.1016/0016-7185(90)90010-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgram, B. Lynne. 2015. “Unsettling Urban Marketplace Redevelopment in Baguio City, Philippines.” Economic Anthropology 2 (1): 2241. DOI: 10.1002/sea2.12016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, Juliane. 2016Plurale Ökonomie anders denken: Populärer Handel im Plurinationalen Staat Bolivien.” Psychosozial 145 (39): 95109.Google Scholar
Müller, Juliane. 2018. “Andean-Pacific Commodity Chains, Trust and Credit: China and the Distribution Network of Consumer Electronics into Bolivia.” Journal for Latin American and Caribbean Anthropology 23 (1).Google Scholar
Ødegaard, Cecilie Vindal. 2008. “Informal Trade, Contrabando and Prosperous Socialities in Arequipa, Peru.” Ethnos 73 (2): 241266. DOI: 10.1080/00141840802180520CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ødegaard, Cecilie Vindal. 2011. “Sources of Danger and Prosperity in the Peruvian Andes: Mobility in a Powerful Landscape.” Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 17: 339355. DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9655.2011.01683.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ong, Aihwa. 2006. Neoliberalism as Exception. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Pérez Sáinz, J. P. 1998. “The New Faces of Informality in Central America.” Journal of Latin American Studies 30 (1): 157179. DOI: 10.1017/S0022216X97004938CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pinheiro-Machado, Rosana. 2013. “Copied Goods and the Informal Economy in Brazil and China: Outlining a Comparison of Development Models.” Vibrant: Virtual Brazilian Anthropology 9 (1): 335359. DOI: 10.1590/S1809-43412012000100012Google Scholar
Porter, Michael E. 2000. “Location, Competition, and Economic Development: Local Clusters in a Global Economy.” Economic Development Quarterly 14: 1534. DOI: 10.1177/089124240001400105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portes, Alejando, and Schauffler, Richard. 1993. “Competing Perspectives on the Latin American Informal Sector.” Population and Development Review 19 (1): 3360. DOI: 10.2307/2938384CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portes, Alejandro, Haller, William J., and Guarnizo, Luis Eduardo. 2002. “Transnational Entrepreneurs: An Alternative Form of Immigrant Economic Adaption.” American Sociological Review 67: 278298. DOI: 10.2307/3088896CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quijano, Aníbal. 1998. La economía popular y sus caminos en América Latina. Lima: Mosca Azul Editores.Google Scholar
Rabossi, Fernando. 2008. “En la ruta de las confecciones.” Crítica en Desarrollo 2 (2): 151171.Google Scholar
Rabossi, Fernando. 2012. “Ciudad del Este and Brazilian Circuits of Commercial Distribution.” In Globalization from Below: The World’s Other Economy, edited by Mathews, Gordon, Lins Ribeiro, Gustavo, and Alba Vega, Carlos, 5468. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ramírez, Susana. 1995. “Exchange and Markets in the Sixteenth Century: A View from the North.” In Ethnicity, Markets, and Migration in the Andes: At the Crossroads of History and Anthropology, edited by Larson, Brooke, Harris, Olivia, and Tandeter, Enrique, 135164. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scarborough, Isabel M. 2010. “Two Generations of Bolivian Female Vendors.” Ethnology 49 (2): 87104.Google Scholar
Seligmann, Linda J. 1989. “To Be In Between: The Cholas as Market Women.” Comparative Studies of Society and History 31 (4): 694721. DOI: 10.1017/S0010417500016169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smart, Alan, and Zerilli, Filippo M.. 2014. “Extralegality.” In A Companion to Urban Anthropology, edited by Nonini, Donald M., 222238. Chichester: Wiley Blackwell. DOI: 10.1002/9781118378625.ch13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smart, Alan, and Smart, Josephine, eds. 2005. Petty Capitalists and Globalization: Flexibility, Entrepreneurship, and Economic Development. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Tassi, Nico. 2010. “The ‘Postulate of Abundance’: Cholo Market and Religion in La Paz, Bolivia.” Social Anthropology 18 (2): 191209. DOI: 10.1111/j.1469-8676.2010.00104.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tassi, Nico, Medeiros, Carmen, Rodríguez Carmona, Antonio, and Ferrufino, Giovana. 2013. “Hacer plata sin plata”: El desborde de los comerciantes populares en Bolivia. La Paz: Fundación PIEB.Google Scholar
Tsing, Anna. 2009. “Supply Chains and the Human Condition.” Rethinking Marxism: A Journal of Economics, Culture, and Society 21 (2): 148176. DOI: 10.1080/08935690902743088CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werbner, Pnina. 2007. “South Asian Entrepreneurship in Britain: A Critique of the Ethnic Enclave Economy Debate.” In Handbook of Research on Ethnic Minority Entrepreneurship, edited by Léo-Paul, Dana, 375389. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. DOI: 10.4337/9781847209962.00032Google Scholar
Zhou, Min. 2004. “Revisiting Ethnic Entrepreneurship: Convergence, Controversies, and Conceptual Advancements.” International Migration Review 38 (3): 10401074. DOI: 10.1111/j.1747-7379.2004.tb00228.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar