Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T06:10:44.391Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From German East African Rupees to British East African Shillings in Tanganyika: The King and the Kaiser Side by Side

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 December 2022

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Pallaver situates German East Africa within the framework of the broader East African region as a way to illuminate the processes of currency standardization in the colonial context. The monetary geography of the region was determined first by the circulation of the rupee and later by Great Britain’s interests to create a common currency for its East African colonies. Pallaver argues that transimperial, international, and regional contexts influenced currency circulation across and within colonies, drawing attention to forms of colonial money and their use by distinct groups, such as African laborers and Indian traders.

Résumé

Résumé

Pallaver situe l’Afrique orientale allemande dans le cadre de la région élargie de l’Afrique de l’Est comme un moyen d’éclairer les processus de normalisation monétaire dans le contexte colonial. La géographie monétaire de la région a été déterminée d’abord par la circulation de la roupie et plus tard par les intérêts de la Grande-Bretagne à créer une monnaie commune pour ses colonies d’Afrique de l’Est. Pallaver soutient que les contextes transimpériaux, internationaux et régionaux, ont influencé la circulation de l’argent à travers et au sein des colonies, attirant l’attention sur les formes de monnaie coloniale et leur utilisation par des groupes distincts, tels que les travailleurs africains et les commerçants indiens.

Resumo

Resumo

Neste artigo, Pallaver enquadra a África Oriental alemã na região mais vasta da África Oriental no seu todo, com vista a compreender os processos de padronização da moeda no contexto colonial. A geografia monetária desta região foi, em primeiro lugar, determinada pela circulação da rupia e, mais tarde, pelos interesses da Grã-Bretanha, que pretendia criar uma moeda comum nas suas colónias da África Oriental. Pallaver defende que os contextos trans-imperiais, internacionais e regionais influenciaram a circulação da moeda entre as várias colónias e dentro de cada uma delas, chamando assim a atenção para a existência de várias moedas coloniais e para a sua utilização pelos diversos grupos, nomeadamente os trabalhadores africanos e os comerciantes indianos.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the African Studies Association

Introduction

During European rule in Africa, colonial authorities transitioned away from imposing imperial currencies in favor of developing new territorial currencies. The processes were common to most colonies, but each colony transitioned according to a particular variety of circumstances and initiatives. This article places German East Africa (GEA) in the framework of the broader East African region as a way to shed light on processes of currency standardization and regulation in the colonial context. For the colonial state, implementing a system of territorial money was a way to facilitate the raising of revenues and to create macroeconomic conditions that favored commercial exchanges between the colony and the imperial metropole. At the same time, a territorial colonial currency was a potent political tool projecting power and fostering identity by limiting foreign influence (Cohen Reference Cohen1998:35). Colonial currencies had “a clear demarcating and ‘mapping’ function,” as the borders between the colonies differentiated between competing claims of colonial powers (Mwangi Reference Mwangi2001:766). A statement by the British Colonial Office in 1920, commenting on the possibility of accepting German East African (GEA) rupee coins in the British protectorates of East Africa, epitomizes the orthodoxy: “It is not altogether satisfactory, even at this time of the day, that the King and the Kaiser should circulate side by side in the British Protectorates […].”Footnote 1 However, the individual colonial states, in their intent to construct discrete spaces of currency circulation, had to consider the realities of currency use that had been in place before the establishment of colonial rule. Indeed, the coastal regions of East Africa and the Zanzibar archipelago had for decades been part of a trading area where the Indian rupee was the dominant currency in commercial exchange. For this reason, the European powers that colonized the area all used rupees, which were each engraved with the symbols of the individual issuing powers. Britain kept the Indian rupee, which was also the currency of British India, whereas the other colonial powers introduced their own rupees. Germany created the Deutsch-Ostafrikanische Rupie, and Italy introduced the rupia italiana in Somalia. Thus, Britain, Germany, and Italy all adapted their colonial currencies to the “monetary geography” (Cohen Reference Cohen1998:8) of East Africa as it was defined by the Indian rupee.

Seen from GEA, the analysis of the spatial relations of currency circulation illuminates how the economic and geographical space of the rupee predated colonialism and how transimperial, transcolonial, and international contexts influenced the policies of currency design. Later, Great Britain’s interests reshaped the monetary geography of the region, as GEA was occupied by the British during the First World War and then became a League of Nations mandate. The discussion about the establishment of the mandate unfolded at a time when Uganda and Kenya were experiencing a profound currency instability known as the “East African rupee crisis” (Maxon Reference Maxon1989; Mwangi Reference Mwangi2001; Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a). The crisis ultimately led to the separation of Kenya and Uganda from the “rupee area” and the introduction of a new currency, the East Africa (EA) shilling. In Tanganyika, Britain as the mandate power aimed at economic standardization and thus at the establishment of a common currency for Kenya, Uganda, and Tanganyika (McCarthy Reference McCarthy1977:583). Yet, the fact that Tanganyika was a League of Nations mandate required that any currency decisions take into consideration the interests of Africans, who had to be protected, as enshrined in the mandate charter (Brennan Reference Brennan2012:11; Gorman Reference Gorman2014).

These transcolonial and international contexts also influenced currency circulation within the colonies, which was characterized by the use of different forms of colonial money. In order to illuminate these spaces of currency circulation and how they shifted over time, this article examines the forms of colonial money and their use by distinct groups within GEA. Denominations used were often specific to different groups of currency users—Africans, Indians, and European settlers. Subsidiary coins, for example, were largely employed by African traders, laborers, and producers, whereas paper notes were used by Indian shopkeepers and traders. The spatial organization of currency relations was thus also shaped by the circulation of different forms of money and their use by discrete groups who played diversified roles in the processes of economy building and were therefore affected by currency policies in different ways.

The first part of this article briefly reconstructs the history of the rupee as regional money in East Africa. The second section investigates relations between specific coinage, money use, and delineations of economic space in the creation of a separate rupee for GEA. Such an analysis goes beyond the existing factual accounts of German East African currency and banking history (Deeken Reference Deeken1913; Hintze Reference Hintze1912; Wehling Reference Wehling1929; Meyer Reference Meyer1996). The third section explores currency matters in the relationship between Britain and Germany under the conditions of the First World War. The final section, focusing on the transition from rupees to EA shillings, discusses how the subsequent reconfiguration of political spaces intersected with currency policies and the interests of different groups of currency users.

Indian, German, and Italian Rupees: Transregional Currency Circulation and Territorialization

German colonial rule was established in a region of East Africa in which the Indian rupee had been in circulation for decades. The circulation of the Indian rupee had been favored by the trade relationships between East Africa and Western India and the crucial role played by Indian merchants in the Zanzibar economy. Yet, before the 1860s, the rupee had not been commonly circulated in Zanzibar. As Catherine Eagleton (Reference Eagleton and Pallaver2022) has recently argued, its adoption as the primary currency of Zanzibar and the East African coast was the result of a regulation of the monetary system introduced by the Sultan of Zanzibar to solve problems of currency stability caused by the outbreak of the American Civil War. Before the war, multiple currencies were circulating in Zanzibar, including gold sovereigns, Maria Theresa thalers—a silver coin struck by the Vienna mint that was extremely popular in the region—and French francs. Owing to the war, imports of American cotton cloth—a commodity greatly in demand in East Africa—were dramatically reduced. German merchants thus began to import English cotton cloth rather than Maria Theresa thalers. The scarcity of Maria Theresa thalers led to the fluctuation in the values of the circulating currencies. Pressed by Zanzibar’s merchants, the Sultan issued a proclamation that listed the coins that were legally accepted in Zanzibar and fixed their value in Maria Theresa thalers. Following the advice of the British consul in Zanzibar, in 1863 the Sultan also added the Indian rupee to the list of accepted coins (Eagleton Reference Eagleton and Pallaver2022:223–26). After these regulations were imposed, Indian rupees started to become more and more abundant, to the extent that at the time of European colonization the Indian rupee and its fractional coin, the copper pice (1/64 of a rupee), were the only currency in daily use in Zanzibar and in the coastal regions of East Africa under the Sultan’s domain.

During the initial phase of German colonial rule in the region, the German East African Company (Deutsch Ostafrikanische Gesellschaft, DOAG) administered the protectorate on behalf of the German Reich. In 1890, the Reich granted the DOAG the right to issue coins. Given the predominance of the Indian rupee, the DOAG decided to issue rupees and pice (pesa), with the inscription of its name and symbols (its coat of arms) and those of the Reich (the German eagle with crown or the effigy of the emperor) (Schnee Reference Schnee1920:693). Engraving the coins with the symbols of the German Reich was a way to distinguish the GEA rupee from the Indian rupee and thus differentiate spaces of currency circulation. Yet, in terms of value, the DOAG one-rupee coin had the same size and silver content as the Indian one-rupee coin. The latter continued to circulate not only within the company’s territory, but also in the British protectorates to the North and in Zanzibar. The DOAG’s creation of a modified rupee was obviously aimed at maintaining existing regional trade links.

In 1891, the DOAG ceased to exist, and the German state created the colony of Deutsch-Ostafrika (German East Africa, GEA). However, DOAG rupees and pesa continued to be issued until 1902, when the state regained its right to mint coins (du Toit Reference du Toit1950:37–39; Deeken Reference Deeken1913:38). Beginning in 1904, the German imperial government issued the new GEA rupee. The exchange rate between the GEA rupee and the pound sterling was fixed at 15 GEA rupees for 1 pound sterling, the same rate that existed between the Indian rupee and sterling (Hintze Reference Hintze1912:83; Deeken Reference Deeken1913:45)Footnote 2. The region’s well-established economic ties with Zanzibar arguably prompted the decision to maintain a rupee currency in GEA. In 1902, Zanzibar received 67 percent of GEA’s exports and provided 57 percent of its imports (Eberlie Reference Eberlie1960:196). For the same reasons, the other European colonial powers in the region, Great Britain and Italy, also opted for the adoption of the rupee.

In 1888, the Imperial British East Africa Company (IBEAC) had received the right to issue money in the form of one-rupee coins and copper pice together with the Royal Charter that allowed it to administer the British-occupied territories in East Africa (MacDermott Reference MacDermott1893:11). After the transfer of the administration to Britain in 1895, the British government declared the Indian rupee and its fractional coins the official currency of the East Africa Protectorate (EAP, from 1920 Kenya) and Uganda. According to the Foreign Office and colonial officers based in East Africa, by adopting a currency in use in a vast area of the Indian Ocean region under British control, including not only Zanzibar and British India, but also Aden, British Somaliland, Ceylon, the Seychelles, and Mauritius, the amounts of rupees in circulation could be naturally controlled by trade operations, and the demand for additional currency could be easily met by importing new coins from India (Clauson Reference Clauson1944:16–17; Pallaver Reference Pallaver2015:481).

In 1910, the Italian rupee was adopted in Somalia (Caroselli Reference Caroselli1922:377; Sessa Reference Sessa2020). The Italian colonial government drew inspiration from GEA, where, in the words of a well-known Italian colonial officer, Germany had “overcome its most tenacious nationalist and imperialist preconceptions” and adopted a rupee currency (Caroselli Reference Caroselli1922:377). The value of the Italian rupee was fixed at 15 to the pound sterling, as in GEA. Carlo Rossetti (Reference Rossetti1914:64), the Director of the Italian Colonial Office, explained the move by stressing the prerequisites of a good colonial administration, namely a monetary system that considered commercial relations with neighboring territories rather than with the “motherland.” Somalia’s dominant trade relations were with Zanzibar and Aden, which both used the Indian rupee. Conscious of its own marginal position in the region, Italy even tried to persuade Britain to agree to a monetary convention on the model of the Latin Union called the “Union of the Indian Ocean.” In this union, all the different types of rupees ought to be accepted as payment. The British, however, refused because they did not trust the stability of the Italian rupee (Rossetti Reference Rossetti1914:57; Caroselli Reference Caroselli1922:368).

The decision to adopt a rupee currency was clearly shaped by existing local and regional monetary conditions. All one-rupee coins (DOAG, GEA, IBEAC, Italian, and Indian) had the same fineness (.917), weight (11.664 grams) and diameter (30–31 mm). They only differed in their national symbols that, as mentioned above, served to define and delimit the borders of the colonies with the circulation of a single legal tender. With regard to the subsidiary coins, before 1898 all types of copper pice (DOAG, IBEAC, EAP, and Zanzibar) were equally accepted in British East Africa, GEA, Zanzibar, and Italian Somalia. This was clearly a way to facilitate trade within the region. When in 1898 the Indian rupee became the official currency of the EAP and Uganda, the governments of the other East African colonies issued regulations sanctioning their own coinage alone as legal tender.Footnote 3 Yet in border areas, multiple currency use persisted in spite of the new regulations. In the Ugandan region bordering GEA, for example, the British authorities occasionally received GEA rupees as revenue and exchanged them for Indian rupees at the German consulate in Mombasa.Footnote 4 GEA rupees received and accepted as payments for hut tax were given to Arab merchants who traded with the German colony.Footnote 5 Existing interregional trade connections and the porousness of colonial borders clashed with the homogenizing intentions of the colonial powers in terms of currency circulation.

Rupees and Hellers: A Currency Suitable for German East Africa

The introduction of the rupee in GEA highlights the relevance of transregional, transcolonial, and local contexts to designs of imperial monetary policies. In its other African colonies—Togo, Cameroon, and German Southwest Africa—the German government introduced the German mark, thereby extending Germany’s monetary system to its colonies (Deeken Reference Deeken1913). Karl Helfferich—the director of the colonial division of the German Ministry for Foreign Affairs and the main driver of Germany’s colonial monetary reforms—explained his vision during a conference organized by the Institut Colonial International (ICI), which discussed best practice in colonial monetary reforms. In his view, the choice of the GEA rupee was a means of creating an efficient colonial monetary system, which required the consideration both of the commercial interests of the “motherland” and those of the indigenous people.Footnote 6 On the same occasion, Bernard Dernburg—former head of the German Imperial Colonial Office—argued that it was necessary “to adapt a bit to the ideas of the indigenous people” and to pay particular attention to the small denomination coins largely used by Africans (ICI 1912:143–44; Krozewski Reference Krozewski and Pallaver2022).

At the beginning of the twentieth century, a change in the small denomination coins in use became urgent. The main reason was that despite colonial currency reforms, cowry shells had continued to be used as currency in Uganda and parts of GEA. One reason for this was that—as opposed to cowries—the copper pice had too high a value to be suitable for small payments, especially in those areas situated far from the coast (Pallaver Reference Pallaver2015). Discussions on the reform of the subsidiary coinage occurred in GEA and the British Protectorates at about the same time, and this led to the introduction of the decimal division of the rupee.Footnote 7 In 1903 and 1905 respectively, the rupee was divided into one-hundred hellers in GEA and into one-hundred East African (EA) cents in the EAP and Uganda.Footnote 8 In 1904, GEA issued one-heller and half-heller coins, followed in 1908 by five-heller coins and ten-heller coins.

Those who used the various currencies accepted some coins but rejected others. The material of the coins was often the reason for the rejection. In GEA, for example, half-heller coins proved to be unpopular because they were too thin and were easily lost. Their minting was discontinued in 1906, and they were withdrawn from circulation in 1915.Footnote 9 The five-heller coin was very large compared to other coins, in order to comply with Africans’ alleged preference for big coins.Footnote 10 However, as it often happened, this might have been a misunderstanding on the part of those who designed the coins, as African currency users actually did not appreciate the coin precisely because it was too big (Jahresbericht 1911–12:XI). In 1913, therefore, the authorities replaced this coin with a smaller one minted in nickel and drilled with a hole as the ten-heller coin, which was well liked by African currency users (Meyer Reference Meyer1996:114). The small denomination EA cents issued in Uganda and the EAP were all coined with a hole. According to the colonial government, this was a way to promote their use by Africans, who in Uganda put cowries on strings (Pallaver Reference Pallaver2015). In the case of the heller, the motivation was different, though. Ten-heller and five-heller coins were minted with a hole to distinguish them from silver rupees which had a similar color (Deeken Reference Deeken1913:53–54; Jahresbericht 1907–8:40–41).

Among all the coins issued in GEA, one-heller coins were the most in demand by Africans and minted in the largest quantities during the German colonial period. One-heller coins became popular in trade in the region of Lake Tanganyika and Lake Victoria: 100,000 rupees in one-heller pieces were introduced in the area and gradually replaced cowry shells (Jahresbericht 1911–12:53). The success of the one-heller coins was similar to that of one-cent coins in Uganda and the EAP (Pallaver Reference Pallaver, Hofmeester and de Zwart2018:299). As Akinobu Kuroda has recently argued, exchanges in rural marketplaces required currencies small enough to negotiate prices at a minimum unit on a tiny scale (Reference Kuroda2020:30–31). The use of one-heller coins allowed for a more effective calculation of the exchange rate between the pesa and the heller. According to Paul Samassa, “That the blacks would now be content with the heller, as some had hoped, where they used to take the pesa, has not occurred; rather, they continue to demand pesas and convert them, as best they can, into heller, rounding upward” (Samassa Reference Samassa1909:241). Thus, when the heller replaced the pesa, people in the colony, despite using heller coins, continued to reckon in pesa; in these conversions, one-heller was the most suitable denomination for rounding up. Heller coins also facilitated the payment of labor, as German planters often paid their African laborers at the end of each working day using one-heller coins.Footnote 11

According to John Iliffe (Reference Iliffe1979:132–33), colonial monetization in GEA was quite successful not only because the colonial state prioritized the process but also because people had a long experience in using money in the form of commodity currencies in nineteenth-century long-distance trade (see Pallaver Reference Pallaver, Serels and Campbell2019c). Indian intermediaries, who had been assigned a special function in the economic development of the colony by the governor Albrecht von Rechenberg (1906–12), played an important role in the process of colonial monetization. Indians held a monopoly in retail trade and mediated “between the villages and the railway,” collecting huge amounts of subsidiary coins from African consumers (Aiyar Reference Aiyar2015:65; Bertz Reference Bertz and Spear2021; Gregory Reference Gregory1971:103–5). Indian retailers exchanged subsidiary coins for rupee coins with German settlers and employers, who used the small coins to pay their laborers. Africans largely preferred coins to pay for both produce and labor, and many kept part of their savings in rupee coins.Footnote 12 They generally disliked notes, as they could easily be destroyed by water, fire, and insects (ICI 1912:143, 158). Moreover, banknotes did not lend themselves to making small payments, as they were generally only issued in high denominations (Comaroff & Comaroff Reference Comaroff and Comaroff2005; Killingray Reference Killingray1978:45; Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019b). The banknotes introduced in 1905 by the Deutsch-Ostafrikanische Bank were all high denomination—five, ten, fifty, one hundred, and five hundred rupees—and as such were used for large payments, which Africans generally did not make (Hintze Reference Hintze1912:104–16; Deeken Reference Deeken1913:48).On the other hand, Indian traders and shopkeepers were more familiar with the use of banknotes. Indians were the main commercial intermediaries in the colony, which is why they had large quantities of both coins and banknotes. For this reason, the Indian community was the one most dramatically affected by the laws that imposed the forced exchange of coins for banknotes during the First World War, as we discuss in the next section.

Currency Policies and Currency Users in German East Africa: Wartime Disconnections

One of the main problems that the German colonial administration faced during the First World War was the shortage of means of exchange. On March 1, 1915, the British initiated a naval blockade that completely stopped the supplies to the German colony, including that of coins. As a way to call in cash, the Deutsch-Ostafrikanische Bank increased its rate of interest from 4 to 5 percent. The outflow was sustained by the payment of salaries to government staff monthly rather than quarterly. In spite of this measure, by mid-1915 cash became even more scarce. The military campaign suffered as a result, because porters and soldiers could not be paid, and food for the army could not be bought. The government calculated that until November 1, 1915, 300,000 silver rupees had “disappeared” from circulation, being hoarded or traded outside the colony. When the colonial government moved its headquarters from Dar es Salaam to Tabora, it set up a provisional mint there which started production in 1916. With metal collected from all over the colony, including from German shipwrecks and used cartridge cases, the mint produced fifteen-rupee gold coins—known as Tabora sovereigns—as well as twenty-heller and five-heller brass coins.Footnote 13 In order to pay their African laborers, plantation owners also issued private tokens called “marken” (stamps), the value of which was expressed in hellers.Footnote 14

Along with the minting of coins, the government printed “interims banknoten” of one, five, ten, and twenty rupees on the paper used for government publications. These were therefore rather “crude” and even more easily damaged by water and insects than normal banknotes. The notes were used to pay African soldiers and porters, to purchase stores and foodstuffs for the army, and to pay the salaries of the Europeans employed by the army, whose number had increased from 260 in peacetime to 3,500 during the war.Footnote 15 But given the widespread preference for coins among Africans and the low quality of these banknotes, the printing of notes was insufficient to relieve the colony from cash scarcity. For this reason, in January 1916 the government prohibited people from owning more coins than necessary for personal requirements and for the continuation of business. Under the new ordinance, people were required to exchange their silver coins for banknotes. The authorities could confiscate excessive amounts of silver coins if people refused to accept paper money, on the agreement that the amounts requisitioned were to be repaid within six months after the termination of hostilities, plus 3 percent interest per annum.Footnote 16 If people refused to accept interim notes or to declare the amount of coins they possessed, they were fined 5,000 Rs (rupees) and/or imprisoned for three months. A total of about Rs18,000,000 were issued as interim notes during the war.Footnote 17 These currency regulations increased the general distrust of paper money. What is more, British intelligence discredited German paper currency by forging millions of twenty GEA rupee notes and circulating them in GEA (Strachan Reference Strachan2004:121).

As more and more German territory was occupied by British, Belgian, and South African forces between 1916 and 1918, people were allowed to exchange the GEA rupee and its subsidiary coins at par with the Indian rupee.Footnote 18 This was the only way to secure the cash needed to supply the Allied army. Porters and soldiers were given German currency individually to buy small provisions, such as chickens and eggs, whereas larger purchases such as cattle were made by supply officers.Footnote 19 The early decision to adopt a rupee currency in both GEA and British East Africa facilitated the acceptance of different rupee coins across colonial borders. But this was not without problems. During 1916, as a temporary solution to currency shortages, the salaries of porters and soldiers from the EAP and Uganda were partly paid by the British in GEA rupees that had been confiscated.Footnote 20 Once they returned to the EAP and Uganda, porters were allowed to use these rupees to pay taxes to the government.Footnote 21 However, since GEA rupees were not legal tender in the British colonies, when porters and soldiers used them or tried to exchange them in local shops, they incurred a high loss. Local shopkeepers in the Voi district, for example, exchanged one GEA rupee for 42 EA cents, rather than for one-hundred EA cents or one Indian rupee, as was the practice in GEA. In this scenario, porters were losing about 58 per cent of the pay they had received for their service for the military.Footnote 22 Despite these problems, the tendency of the British colonial government was to pay porters with whatever currency they had, as a way to avoid unrest. Once the porters had been paid and demobilized, there was lesser risk that they could organize and cause unrest. Later, at the time of demobilization at the end of the war, porters from Uganda and Kenya were paid by the British almost exclusively with Indian one-rupee notes, despite the general dislike of this form of money. In 1921, these notes were demonetized overnight by the British colonial government, raising intense criticism from various sectors, including the Indian community in Kenya and the Lukiiko in Uganda, as well as widespread discontent among the general population.Footnote 23

After the establishment of the civil administration in January 1917, the British authorities kept the GEA rupee in circulation. They lacked an alternative to replace it and were also afraid of a negative reaction from the “natives.”Footnote 24 For these reasons, Britain guaranteed that German coins would not be demonetized or withdrawn until they could be exchanged with British currency at par.Footnote 25 In order to pay for imports, traders were allowed to take German coins to the banks in exchange for drafts in Nairobi at a commission of 1.5 percent.Footnote 26 Subsidiary coins remained valid currency, though legal tender restrictions limited transactions for the public to the amount of Rs2 and for the government to Rs50. This regulation disadvantaged those in the colony who held small coins in large quantities, notably Indian traders and shopkeepers. A further repercussion was that Indian traders, especially those who had their dukas (shops) along the central railway that connected Dar es Salaam to Lake Tanganyika, started to refuse to accept hellers from their African customers, given that hellers had little use for buying imports. In pre-war days, German employers had used hellers to pay their African laborers. However, owing to the war and the occupation of GEA, they only employed a very limited number of laborers. The money was thus simply transferred from African consumers to Indian shopkeepers, who could neither put the coins into circulation nor exchange them for rupee coins or notes. It was estimated that in Tanga Indian traders held Rs100,000 in small coins, whereas the banks held only Rs50,000. A deputation of Indian merchants in Dar es Salaam asked the Political Officer to take action to relieve them from this coinage, as was the practice in the EAP. There, bankers and traders could take surpluses of subsidiary coins to the Treasury, where they exchanged them for rupee coins or banknotes.Footnote 27 Given the critical role of Indians in the colony’s trade and the risk that the entire petty trade in the colony could be brought to a standstill, their request had to be accepted.Footnote 28

Unlike coins, neither interim notes nor pre-war notes were accepted in the occupied territory of GEA. The fear was that the German government could print new banknotes and introduce them into these areas to support the German forces that continued to fight in GEA. Interim notes were only allowed for exchanges among the Germans themselves, but “any attempt to pass notes on to the natives or non-Germans [was] duly punished.”Footnote 29 Indians, being the main intermediaries in the colony’s trade, owned large amounts of silver coins. For this reason, during the first years of the war they were the majority of those “compelled to hand over silver coin and to accept notes in lieu.”Footnote 30 Thus, large quantities of interim notes that were not accepted by the British government remained in the hands of Indians.

After the war, the Indian community of GEA was severely hit by the government’s decision to not redeem the interim notes that had been forced on them during the war. As the British did not accept them, all claims of redemption hinged on the ultimate assets of the Deutsch-Ostafrikanische Bank, which was only able to cover a tiny part of the claims. Indians made numerous requests for the redemption of the notes and for support from the British government for their claims, arguing that notes taken to Germany by repatriated Germans had been redeemed at 1.5 marks to the rupee.Footnote 31 The Indian Association in Dar es Salaam sent a letter to the British government requesting the recovery of pre-war notes and interim notes.Footnote 32 The Indian Merchant Chamber and Bureau in Bombay sent letters of protest to the government of India, stating that “thousands of Indian residents for a number of years in German East Africa […] have been rendered penniless ….”Footnote 33 From Zanzibar, the members of the Shia Ismaili Council sent a letter to the Aga Khan in London, stating that owing to the considerable amounts of German currency notes “lying unchangeable in the hands [of individuals],” the state of Indian people was “very pittyful.” Together with this formal letter, the Aga Khan received many private letters from prominent members of the Indian community in East Africa requesting support in the matter.Footnote 34 This situation contributed to the massive financial losses experienced by Indian traders during the first years of the war due to the collapse of trade (Bertz Reference Bertz and Spear2021:5). Robert Sohr, Manager of Messrs. Scott Ellis and Co. in Mombasa, noted that the people were suffering severely owing to their “wealth being tied up in these notes.”Footnote 35 Claims had to be laid against the German government, but Horace Archer Byatt, the governor of the occupied territory, doubted their chance of success. He admitted that in 1916 the British authorities had “flooded” GEA with interim notes forged in Nairobi for GBP2,000,000. This could only have a bad influence on the attitude of the German government toward the Indian claims.Footnote 36 In 1927, the German Clearing Office eventually wrote individually to claimants, offering to redeem 25 percent of the face value for the interim notes and 80 percent for those issued before the war. The government of Tanganyika Territory approved the offer.Footnote 37 But claimants received for the notes only a fraction of their face value, and ultimately they had to bear part of the costs of the war. In addition, this increased the general mistrust of paper money in the colony.

“Our Special East African Province:” The East African Rupee Crisis and Currency in Tanganyika Territory

From 1916 to early 1919, British officials in London and GEA worked to transform the German colony into a British possession and considered what to do with the GEA currency. Byatt, the British governor from 1917 to 1924, had always regarded the rupee as “out of place” in Africa. At the same time, he realized that it would have been inexpedient to uproot the use of this currency in East Africa and replace it with the pound sterling.Footnote 38 Before the outbreak of hostilities, the Colonial Office had discussed and even drafted an order in council to introduce a new rupee, the East African Rupee, thereby separating the currency of the East African protectorates from that of India. Discussions on currency during the war reached the conclusion that GEA had to adopt the same currency and become part of Britain’s “special East African province.”Footnote 39 However, the idea of a new rupee was abandoned at the end of the war, owing to the “East African rupee crisis.”

The crisis was the result of the collapse of the gold standard system during the First World War. Currencies were left to float, and in the British colonies in the Indian Ocean region this meant that the fixed exchange value of the rupee with the sterling had to be abandoned. At the same time, the price of silver increased, and this determined an appreciation of the silver Indian rupee. Thus, in 1919 the Indian rupee began to appreciate against sterling, more than doubling its value in just one year (Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a:549). British settlers in Kenya were those most severely affected by the currency crisis, as they stored their capital in sterling but had to pay local expenses in rupees. They saw their incomes rapidly eroding and began to campaign for a currency reform. Conversely, Indian traders were favored by the increased value of the rupee, as they sold their products in India and stored their capital in rupees (Maxon Reference Maxon1989; Mwangi Reference Mwangi2001; Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a). Responding to settlers’ claims, in April 1920 the British replaced the Indian rupee with the EA florin (Fl), at the exchange rate of 1Fl=1Rs. Beginning in January 1921, however, the value of the Indian rupee started to fall again, reverting to pre-war levels. As a result, the currency changed once again: Britain introduced the EA shilling (sh), at the rate of exchange of 2EAsh=1Rs.Footnote 40 Debates surrounding the currency crisis intersected with those related to the establishment of a British mandate over former GEA, which had been under discussion since 1919. The transfer of GEA to Britain as a League of Nations mandate put under scrutiny the fundamentals of British colonial rule by introducing an international oversight on Britain’s policies and their respect of African interests, including the possible problems resulting from a currency change.

When the florin became legal tender in Kenya and Uganda, the GEA rupee was left to circulate at par with the florin in GEA. The intention was to introduce florin coins, but their minting required too much time. The currency instability was hampering trade in East Africa, and it was thus decided to introduce florin banknotes while the coins were being produced. The limited amounts of florin coins available were reserved for the purchase of cotton in Uganda, where local producers did not accept banknotes.Footnote 41 In 1920, GEA rupee coins began to be exchanged for florin banknotes.Footnote 42 No doubt, a currency change in GEA was less urgent than in Kenya, where the settlers were very vocal in their campaign for a rapid solution to the currency instability (Maxon Reference Maxon1989; Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a). For this reason, the GEA rupee and its subsidiary coins were left to circulate, as it was “highly undesirable” to “flood the country with paper exclusively,” given the general mistrust described above.Footnote 43 Yet, it soon became clear that it was impossible to regulate the currency in one colony and not in the other, as currency circulated across borders despite British regulations. When the value of the Indian rupee started to fall in December 1920, rupees were smuggled in large amounts from India to the former GEA to be exchanged for florin notes.Footnote 44 Byatt suggested the simultaneous demonetization of the rupees in the three territories in order to prevent demonetized coins from Kenya and Uganda from being used in Tanganyika.Footnote 45 Officials agreed, however, that a valid alternative to paper banknotes had to be found before any attempt was made to demonetize the rupee. A telegram stated that failing to do so might lead to “a loss of confidence and serious unrest in minds of natives and it is essential above all that there should be no grounds for dissatisfaction under British administration.”Footnote 46 The international overview related to the mandate necessarily required a consideration of the “material and moral well-being and social progress” of Africans (Manisty Leggett Reference Leggett and Humphrey1922:744), including in the process of currency reform.

Meanwhile, this wait-and-see attitude in the settlement of the currency question seriously hampered trade in Tanganyika.Footnote 47 Locally, the high cost of imported articles along with the scarcity of cash was causing widespread discontent among the population.Footnote 48 In international trade, the problem was that even if GEA rupees could be used within the territory, they could not be remitted outside it. Thus, when goods were imported in Tanganyika and sold there, the cash proceeds became “frozen” within the country and could not be remitted to Britain. This situation prompted complaints by the British commercial companies operating in Tanganyika.Footnote 49 These complaints, together with the general popular discontent, persuaded the colonial government to make the existing temporary and provisional arrangements more permanent. By mid-1922, the EA shilling was also introduced in Tanganyika, and people were required to exchange old coins for new ones.Footnote 50 An official notice of June 9, 1922, stated that the British government had decided to create one single currency for Kenya, Uganda, and Tanganyika. The announcement clearly explained the denominations and the exchange rates between the different currencies in circulation, and also stated that the new shilling was accepted in Uganda and Kenya. People were encouraged to “go to the Bank or the Boma [fort] and […] get [their] German money changed.” In the initial stages, only German rupees could be exchanged, but later also copper-bronze coins, “so that before long the country will have British money only.”Footnote 51 Unlike in Kenya and Uganda, where rupees were rapidly demonetized, the change in Tanganyika was gradual. GEA rupees were left to circulate alongside florin notes until the rupees could be fully replaced with EA shillings.Footnote 52 Initially, only one shilling coins and fifty-cent coins plus banknotes of various denominations circulated. For this reason, heller coins were not exchanged, as the new EA cents were not yet available (Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a). From December 1, 1922, hellers could be exchanged for EA cents at the rate of one heller for two cents. Given that Africans were the main users of small coins and to avoid that they would “suffer by the change of currency,” the period granted for the redemption of the hellers was longer than for other coins.Footnote 53 During the East African rupee crisis, in Kenya and Uganda the British had attempted to mark down the existing cents from florin cents to shilling cents, in this way reducing their value by half.Footnote 54 This operation, known as the “shilling swindle,” was significantly proposed only for Uganda and Kenya, but was not taken into consideration for Tanganyika, as the mandate required Britain to consider the rights and interests of the African population.

However, the currency transition was complicated by the lack of coins that needed to be supplied to all the three territories. This hampered trade and caused an increase in the price of many imported goods.Footnote 55 According to a letter sent to the Dar es Salaam Times, in April 1923 the price of oil in Tabora had doubled, the price of a box of matches had increased from 6 to 8 cents, and that of a cigarette box from 24 to 40 cents.Footnote 56 Shillings and EA cents were gradually accepted as currency, but paper money continued to be unpopular. An official report later stated that people regarded “with suspicion the validity of this form of currency of which their experience in the past has not been fortunate.” Footnote 57 The reference was clearly to the interim notes of the war period.

Conclusion

This article has addressed how matters of colonial monetization and currency use, including the details of currency denominations, were interlocked with local, interregional, and imperial-colonial economic relationships, and constituted an essential part of the story of economy formation in the colonial context. The monetary geography of East Africa was redefined and delineated in relation to local and regional conditions, creating an economic space whose borders were determined first by the circulation of the rupee and later redefined by the interests of Great Britain to create a common currency area for its East African colonies. Beginning in the 1860s, the rupee of British India had become the main means of exchange in Zanzibar and along the East African coast. In the early period of colonial rule, the centrality of Zanzibar in East African trade relationships defined economic and currency policy. Accordingly, the colonies of Britain, Germany, and Italy in East Africa all adopted rupees in various forms. Moreover, local conditions, and often colonial assumptions regarding preferences by local money users, influenced the choice of specific denominations and the designs of the coins. Yet, with the creation of different rupees, the monetary geography of East Africa also began to reflect territorially delineated colonial currencies associated with competing European nation-states, namely by distinguishing the GEA rupee from the British Indian rupee and the subsidiary coinage of GEA and the EAP.

The First World War brought about the usual disruptions of wartime, with coin shortages and temporary currency coupons. However, the war also aggravated the grievances of specific money users. Emergency measures burdened Indian retailers with forms of currency they could not put to economic use in trade. After the war, changes in the exchange rate between the rupee and the pound sterling, which initially disadvantaged the white settler community and benefited Indian retail traders, prompted the move from rupees to EA shillings. In the new currency environment, Indian commerce suffered not only due to the disconnection of the currency from the rupee but also because Indians received insufficient compensation for losses related to wartime currency policies. Meanwhile, policymakers preparing the mandate administration for Tanganyika evaluated the possible impact of currency arrangements on African money users more cautiously, even if the mandate soon began to resemble British colonial rule (Callahan Reference Callahan1993:453–77). Currency use and policies of colonial monetization not only mirrored economies, but to some extent also formed them. As economies differentiated increasingly in relation to the communities of Africans, Indians, and European settlers, currency policy affected those using the money in different ways as well.

Acknowledgements

Research for this article was generously supported by the Gerda Henkel Foundation (Research Project AZ 37/F/16) and by the Italian Ministry of Education, University and Research (Research Project PRIN2015_JXPLWF). The author wishes to thank Gerold Krozewski, Tinashe Nyamunda, and all the participants to the workshop “Transnational Money and the Formation of Economies and States in Africa, 1870s–1960s” at Osaka University (November 2018).

Footnotes

1. Minutes, February 26, 1920, The National Archives, London [TNA] CO/691/40.

2. The GEA rupee was valued at 1.333 German mark and issued in the denominations of one, half, and quarter rupees.

3. Bowring to Foreign Office, July 11, 1902, TNA FO/2/956; Order in Council, East Africa Currency, May 19, 1898, TNA FO 881/7027x.

4. Bowring to Jackson, Mombasa, July 15, 1902, TNA FO/2/956; the same happened with IBEAC rupees received by German authorities.

5. Sadler to Foreign Office, Entebbe, August 18, 1902, TNA FO/2/956.

6. In Kiautschou, Germany retained the Chinese currency already in use. Here, too, Helfferich stated that the needs of the indigenous people were more important than the commercial interests of the metropole (ICI 1912:143–44).

7. For British East Africa, see Pallaver Reference Pallaver2015:444–49; in Somalia, Italy issued the besa (1/100 rupee) in 1909 (Tuccimei Reference Tuccimei1999:145).

8. The hellers replaced the pesa, which ceased to be accepted after April 1, 1911 (Hintze: 1912:95; Meyer Reference Meyer1996:114).

9. Schnee, Circular-Order to all Government Departments having treasury offices, Dar es Salaam, July 24, 1912, Kenya National Archives, Nairobi [KNA] AA/28/2. Also in Uganda, half-cent coins were unpopular and their minting was discontinued (Pallaver Reference Pallaver2015:498).

10. Five-hellers had a diameter of 37 mm, whereas one-hellers measured 20 mm.

11. Byatt to Colonial Office [CO], Wilhelmstal, April 27, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

12. Imperial Pay Office to the DA and QMG East Africa Force, Dar es Salaam, August 22, 1917, TNA CO/691/1.

13. Since July 1916, twenty-heller coins were minted using copper (Henderson Reference Henderson1943:109).

14. One such coin was issued by the Afrikanische Plantagen Georg Hirsch in Morogoro. It had on one side a pair of antlers over the letter H enclosing a heart, and on the other side the value, the numeral 15 in large figures over the word “heller”; see Currency Officer to EACB, Dar es Salaam, June 2, 1922, KNA AA/28/2.

15. Memorandum on Paper Currency in German East Africa, Dar es Salaam, August 18, 1924, TNA CO/323/917.

16. Schnee, Ordinance, Tabora, January 14, 1916, KNA AA/28/2.

17. Byatt to CO, January 11, 1919, TNA CO/691/21.

18. General Routine Order no. 537, June 21, 1916, TNA CO/691/5.

19. Imperial Pay Office to the DA and QMG East Africa Force, Dar es Salaam, August 22, 1917, TNA CO/691/11. During the war, the British enrolled about 200,000 porters from the EAP and 190,000 from Uganda (Hodges Reference Hodges1978:114; Crowder Reference Crowder and Boahen1985:295; Page Reference Page1978:94). By 1918, half of the total male population of the African reserves in the East Africa Protectorate had been conscripted (Killingray Reference Killingray1989:489). The majority of them were recruited from 1917 and demobilized in 1918.

20. Ewart to War Office, Korogwe, August 1916, TNA CO/691/2.

21. Weatherhead to Treasurer, Entebbe, April 26, 1918, Uganda National Archives [UNA] A/46/1455; Treasury to Chief Secretary Entebbe, July 12, 1916, UNA A/46/1455.

22. Hobley to Nairobi Chief Secretary and Treasury, Mombasa, September 6, 1916, KNA PcCOAST/1/6/92.

23. For a reconstruction of the reasons behind this action and its consequences, see Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019b.

24. Report on Tanganyika Territory, 1920, TNA CO/691/36.

25. Minutes, April 30, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

26. Byatt to CO, Wilhelmstal, June 19, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

27. Grant to the Administrator, Dar es Salaam, August 12, 1917, TNA CO/691/6; Byatt to CO, Wilhelmstal, April 27, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

28. Read to Treasury, July 4, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

29. Circular 41/25 to all Political Officers, August 9, 1916, TNA CO/691/12.

30. Byatt to CO, Wilhelmstal, April 19, 1917, TNA CO/591/5.

31. Read to Treasury, London, August 21, 1919, India Office Record, British Library, London [IOR] L/E/7/1192.

32. Polak to Montagu, June 26, 1919, IOR L/E/7/1192.

33. Indian Merchants Chamber and Bureau to Government of India, Bombay, October 9, 1919, IOR L/E/7/1192.

34. Aga Khan to Milner, Nice, April 11, 1919, IOR L/E/7/1192; Various signatories to Aga Khan Zanzibar, February 28, 1919, IOR L/E/7/1192.

35. J. and R. Grant to CO, London, June 1, 1920, TNA CO/691/41.

36. Telegram from Byatt to CO, February 22, 1920, TNA CO/691/30.

37. Parliamentary Notice, January 31, 1927, IOR L/E/7/1192.

38. Byatt to CO, Wilhelmstal, April 30, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

39. Minutes, April 30, 1917, TNA CO/691/5.

40. For a detailed chronology, see Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a, Table 1: 547. The exchange values were 1Fl= 2sh; GBsh1=10Fl; and 1EA sh=GBsh1.

41. EACB to Kenya Currency Officer, September 21, 1920, KNA AA/28/2.

42. Report on Tanganyika Territory, 1920, TNA CO/691/36.

43. Telegram, Byatt to CO, March 6, 1921, TNA CO/691/43.

44. Telegram, Byatt to CO, December 21, 1920, TNA CO/691/36.

45. Telegram, Byatt to CO, May 22, 1921, TNA CO/691/44.

46. Telegram, Hollis to CO, February 19, 1921, TNA CO7691/43.

47. Standard Bank of South Africa to EACB, London, July 25, 1921, TNA CO 691/52.

48. Dar es Salaam Times September 2, 1922.

49. Chamber of Commerce to CO, London, July 7, 1921, TNA CO/691/52.

50. Government Notice no. 260, Dar es Salaam, December 23, 1922, KNA AA/28/2.

51. Notice, Dar es Salaam, June 9, 1922, KNA AA/28/2.

52. Minutes, July 7, 1921, TNA CO/691/52.

53. Currency Officer Dar es Salaam to EACB, December 13, 1922, KNA AA/28/1.

54. Owing to protests by different groups in the colonies and in Britain, the scheme had to be abandoned; see Pallaver Reference Pallaver2019a.

55. Dar es Salaam Times, September 2, 1922; see also Brennan Reference Brennan2012:27.

56. Letter by Juma bin Ramathani to Dar es Salaam Times, April 28, 1923.

57. Report on the Mandated Territory of Tanganyika for the year 1923, London 1924.

References

Aiyar, Sana. 2015. Indians in Kenya. The Politics of Diaspora. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bertz, Ned. 2021. “The Indian Diaspora in Tanzania.” In Oxford Research Encyclopedia of African History, edited by Spear, Thomas, 124. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, James R. 2012. Taifa. Making Nation and Race in Urban Tanzania. Athens: Ohio University Press.Google Scholar
Callahan, Michael D. 1993. “Nomansland: The British Colonial Office and the League of Nations Mandate for German East Africa, 1916–1920.” Albion: A Quarterly Journal Concerned with British Studies 25 (3): 443–64.10.2307/4050877CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caroselli, Francesco S. 1922. “Il sistema monetario in rupie nella economia e nella finanza della Somalia italiana.” Giornale degli economisti e rivista di statistica 62: 365–80.Google Scholar
Clauson, Gerard. 1944. “The British Colonial Currency System.” The Economic Journal 54 (213): 125.10.2307/2959827CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, Benjamin J. 1998. The Geography of Money. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Comaroff, Jean, and Comaroff, John L.. 2005. “Beasts, Banknotes and the Colour of Money in Colonial South Africa.” Archaeological Dialogues 12 (2): 107–32.10.1017/S1380203806211863CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crowder, Michael. 1985. “The First World War and its Consequences.” In UNESCO General History of Africa, vol. 7, edited by Boahen, Albert A., 283311. Paris: Heinemann.Google Scholar
Deeken, Matthias. 1913. Das Geldwesen der deutschen Kolonien, Münster: Westfälischen Vereindruckerei.Google Scholar
du Toit, P.J. 1950. “Notes on the Coinage of German East Africa (Tanganyika).” Tanganyika Notes and Records 31: 3741.Google Scholar
Eagleton, Catherine. 2022. “How and Why Did the Rupee Become the Currency of Zanzibar and East Africa?” In Monetary Transitions. Currencies, Colonialism and African Societies, edited by Pallaver, Karin, 211–37. London: Palgrave Macmillan.10.1007/978-3-030-83461-6_9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eberlie, R.F. 1960. “The German Achievement in East Africa.” Tanganyika Notes and Records 55: 181214.Google Scholar
Gorman, Daniel. 2014. “Organic Union or Aggressive Altruism: Imperial Internationalism in East Africa in the 1920s.” Journal of Imperial and Commonwealth History 5 (3): 294309.Google Scholar
Gregory, Robert G. 1971. India and East Africa: A History of Race Relations within the British Empire, 1890–1939. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Henderson, W.O. 1943. “The War Economy of German East Africa, 1914–1917.” The Economic History Review 13 (1–2): 104–10.10.2307/2590519CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hintze, Willy. 1912. Das Geldwesen in den Deutschen Schutzgebieten. Berlin: Guttentag.Google Scholar
Hodges, Geoffrey W.T. 1978. “African Manpower Statistics for the British Forces in East Africa, 1914–1918.” The Journal of African History 19 (1): 101–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iliffe, John. 1979. A Modern History of Tanganyika. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511584114CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Institut Colonial International (ICI). 1912. Compte Rendue de la session tenue à Bruxelles les 29, 30 et 31 Juillet 1912, Brussels.Google Scholar
Jahresbericht über die Entwicklung der Schutzgebiete in Afrika und der Südsee im Jahre 1907–8, Berlin 1909.Google Scholar
Jahresbericht über die Entwicklung der Schutzgebiete in Afrika und der Südsee im Jahre 1911–12, Berlin 1913.Google Scholar
Killingray, David. 1978. “Repercussions of World War I in the Gold Coast.” The Journal of African History 19 (1): 3959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Killingray, David. 1989. “Labour Exploitation for Military Campaigns in British Colonial Africa 1870–1945.” Journal of Contemporary History 24 (3): 483501.10.1177/002200948902400306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krozewski, Gerold. 2022. “Colonial Money in Africa and National Economy-Building in Britain and Germany: Examining Relations of Agency, 1890s–1930s.” In Monetary Transitions. Currencies, Colonialism and African Societies, edited by Pallaver, Karin, 239–63. London: Palgrave Macmillan.10.1007/978-3-030-83461-6_10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuroda, Akinobu. 2020. A Global History of Money. Abingdon: Routledge.10.4324/9781003016205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacDermott, P.L. 1893. British East Africa or IBEA. A History of the Formation and Work of the Imperial British East Africa Company. London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Leggett, Manisty, Humphrey, Edward. 1922. “The Tanganyika Territory.” Journal of the Royal Society of Arts 70 (3643): 737–52.Google Scholar
Maxon, Robert. 1989. “The Kenya Currency Crisis, 1919–21 and the Imperial Dilemma.” Journal of Imperial and Commonwealth History 17 (3): 323–48.10.1080/03086538908582796CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCarthy, Dennis M.P. 1977. “Organizing Underdevelopment from the Inside: The Bureaucratic Economy in Tanganyika, 1919–1940.” The International Journal of African Historical Studies 10 (4): 573–99.10.2307/216930CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, Claus-Peter. 1996. Das Geld-, Bank- und Währungswesen im ehemaligen deutschen Schutzgebiet Deutsch-Ostafrika. Aachen: Verlag der Augustinus Buchhandlung.Google Scholar
Mwangi, Wambui. 2001. “Of Coins and Conquest: The East African Currency Board, the Rupee Crisis and the Problem of Colonialism in the East African Protectorate.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 43 (4): 763–87.Google Scholar
Page, Melvin E. 1978. “The War of Thangata. Nyasaland and the East African Campaign, 1914–1918.” The Journal of African History 19 (1): 87100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pallaver, Karin. 2015. “‘The African Native Has No Pocket’: Monetary Practices and Currency Transitions in Early Colonial Uganda.” International Journal of African Historical Studies 48 (3): 471–99.Google Scholar
Pallaver, Karin. 2018. “Paying in Cents, Paying in Rupees: Colonial Currencies, Labour Relations and the Payment of Wages in Kenya (1890–1920).” In Colonialism, Institutional Change and Shifts in Global Labour Relations, edited by Hofmeester, Karin and de Zwart, Pim, 295325. Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam Press.Google Scholar
Pallaver, Karin. 2019a. “A Currency Muddle: Resistance, Materialities and the Local Use of Money during the East African Rupee Crisis (1919–1923).” Journal of Eastern African Studies 13 (3): 546–64.10.1080/17531055.2019.1628103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pallaver, Karin. 2019b. “Pockets full of rupees, but bodies very weak: the Carrier Corps and their demobilization at the end of WWI in East Africa.” Afriche e Orienti, 21 (3): 7996.Google Scholar
Pallaver, Karin. 2019c. “What East Africans got for their Ivory and Slaves: The Nature, Working and Circulation of Commodity Currencies in 19th-century East Africa.” In Currencies of the Indian Ocean World, edited by Serels, Steven and Campbell, Gwyn, 7192. London: Palgrave Macmillan.10.1007/978-3-030-20973-5_4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossetti, Carlo. 1914. Il regime monetario delle colonie italiane. Roma: Tipografia dell’Unione Editrice.Google Scholar
Samassa, Paul. 1909. Die Besiedlung Deutsch-Ostafrikas. Berlin: Weicher.Google Scholar
Schnee, Heinrich. 1920. Deutsches Kolonial Lexikon. Leipzig: Quelle & Meyer.Google Scholar
Sessa, Claudio. 2020. Colonialismo monetario: l’esperienza italiana in Somalia e la difficile transizione (1905–1950). Ph.D. diss., University of Genoa.Google Scholar
Strachan, Hew. 2004. The First World War in Africa. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Tuccimei, Ercole. 1999. La Banca d’Italia in Africa. Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Wehling, Franz. 1929. Die Entwicklung der Deutsch-Ostafrikanische Rupie. Ein Beitrag zur Deutschen Kolonialpolitik. Münster: Aschendorffsche Verlagsbuchhandlung.Google Scholar