Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T00:32:00.011Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part I - Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 August 2018

Jakob Skovgaard
Affiliation:
Lunds Universitet, Sweden
Harro van Asselt
Affiliation:
Stockholm Environment Institute
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

1 The Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Their Reform An Introduction

Jakob Skovgaard and Harro van Asselt
1.1 Introduction

In September 2009, the leaders of 20 of the world’s largest economies gathered at the Group of 20 (G20) summit in Pittsburgh and announced a surprise gift for those demanding more concerted global action to fight environmental problems: a commitment to ‘phase out and rationalize over the medium term inefficient fossil fuel subsidies’ (G20 2009). At the time, fossil fuel subsidies were still a marginal subject on the international political agenda. Although a small but growing number of experts from governments, international organisations, non-governmental organisations (NGOs) and academia had started to discuss the challenge (e.g. Larsen and Shah Reference Larsen and Shah1992; Anderson and McKibben Reference Anderson and McKibben2000; Koplow and Dernbach Reference Koplow and Dernbach2001), references to the hundreds of billions of dollars channelled to fossil fuels were almost non-existent in the public discourse.

Fast-forward to 2015, and fossil fuel subsidies were making headlines across the world. The International Monetary Fund’s (IMF) estimated that global fossil fuel subsidies totalled a staggering USD 5.3 trillion (Coady et al. Reference Coady, Parry, Sears and Shang2015b), predictably drawing lots of public attention (Carrington Reference Carrington2015). At the national level, too, the actions by governments – or the lack thereof – started to enter the spotlight. For instance, the Indian government set out to reduce all subsidies from 2 to 1 per cent of gross domestic product (GDP) by 2020, starting with fuel subsidies (New Indian Express 2015). Elsewhere in the world, the British government faced widespread criticism for adopting new tax breaks for oil and gas exploration (Jowit Reference Jowit2015). Fossil fuel subsidies became a part of the mainstream political agenda, as was underscored when more than 40 countries – along with a range of international, business and nongovernmental organisations – committed to a communiqué to eliminate fossil fuel subsidies at the margins of the 21st Conference of the Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC).

Notwithstanding the heightened attention, governments in industrialised and developing countries continue to provide budget transfers, tax breaks, economic guarantees and specific goods and services to aid the production and consumption of fossil fuels. By any measure, this support is sizeable. The IMF’s estimate stands out because of their inclusion of the non-pricing of environmental and social externalities. But more conservative estimates are also huge. The International Energy Agency (IEA), for instance, estimates that global fossil fuel subsidies amounted to USD 325 billion in 2015 (IEA 2016: 99). Although that was a decline from nearly USD 500 billion in 2014 – mainly due to falling oil prices – it is still significant. To put these figures into perspective, global levels of official development aid in 2016 were USD 142 billion (OECD 2017); industrialised countries have pledged to mobilise USD 100 billion of climate finance per year by 2020 to support developing countries (UNFCCC 2010); and South Africa’s GDP in 2016 was USD 295 billion.

Fossil fuel subsidies persist across the world, in spite of efforts to reform them and mounting evidence of the environmental and economic benefits of doing so. Many countries – from Germany to Nigeria, from Canada to Indonesia, from Mexico to the United Arab Emirates – have sought to at least partially remove the subsidies provided to fossil fuels (Whitley and van der Burg Reference Whitley and van der Burg2015; Rentschler and Bazilian Reference Rentschler and Bazilian2017a; Sovacool Reference Sovacool2017). The benefits of reform are clear: removing fossil fuel subsidies would allow governments to make significant cost savings, and could yield significant environmental benefits. For example, removing fossil fuel subsidies in 37 (mainly developing, major emitting) countries between 2013 and 2020 would reduce global greenhouse gas emissions by 8 per cent by 2050, according to one estimate (Burniaux and Château Reference Burniaux and Château2014).

Notwithstanding the broad agreement among expert communities about the benefits of reforming fossil fuel subsidies and the high-level commitments to do so, the level of concerted political action is still low. By ‘concerted political action’, we refer to action by the most relevant actors to promote fossil fuel subsidy reform on the basis of prior coordination or communication (see also Holzinger and Knill Reference Holzinger and Knill2005). This observation holds for both the domestic and the international levels. While domestic reform has taken place in some countries, other countries have either not succeeded in their reform attempts or have not even attempted such reform. And while some international institutions have taken up fossil fuel subsidies within their remit, governance activity in other institutions has been conspicuously absent (Van de Graaf and van Asselt Reference Van de Graaf and van Asselt2017). The variation in the degree of effort to reform fossil fuel subsidies between countries and between different international institutions means that the level of concerted political action is low both within and between the two levels. We argue that this low level of concerted action is puzzling given the expert consensus on the benefits of reform and existing high-level commitments and that this puzzle points to the importance of the political dimensions of fossil fuel subsidies. While they undoubtedly matter, economic factors alone (e.g. fluctuating oil prices; see Clements et al. Reference Clements, Coady and Fabrizio2013) cannot explain why and how some countries have put in place fossil fuel subsidies, why they are maintained, and why – in some cases – they are successfully reformed.

We further hold that political factors can help explain why some international institutions have taken up the cause of fossil fuel subsidy reform and why others have remained silent; they can also help explain the causal mechanisms through which institutions seek to promote reform at the international and national levels. In this book, in short, we argue that it is useful to study fossil fuel subsidies and their reform as political phenomena.

We can provide a better understanding of why and how fossil fuel subsidy reform can succeed by uncovering the interests, strategies and power of various actors and institutions (both in favour of and opposed to subsidy reform), as well as the norms, ideas and belief systems underpinning subsidies or efforts to reform them, and the socio-political characteristics of a particular country. The aim of this book, therefore, is to provide insights – underpinned by theory and based on a variety of case studies – into the domestic and international political factors driving fossil fuel subsidies and their reform. Specifically, this book seeks to uncover (1) why, how and with what effects international institutions and actors address fossil fuel subsidies – and why, in some cases, they do not; and (2) why and how fossil fuel subsidies are maintained or reformed on the domestic level. By answering these two questions, we seek to understand why concerted political action on fossil fuel subsidy reform is limited.

The book accomplishes this by bringing together a collection of chapters that span domestic and international levels. A common analytical framework outlining different factors influencing the politics of fossil fuel subsidy reform (presented in this chapter) guides the authors in their analyses, allowing for a more comprehensive and systematic analysis than provided in previous literature on the politics of fossil fuel subsidies. Among others, the contributions cover definitional and structural challenges, case studies of countries that have and have not undertaken successful reform and analyses of international institutions and actors that have and have not started to address fossil fuel subsidies. Several chapters address the influence of international factors on domestic reform, linking the two levels.

This introductory chapter proceeds with a discussion of the existing literature on the politics of fossil fuel subsidies, which offers a foundation for the work presented in this book. Next, we present the analytical framework guiding the chapters in this book. The chapter concludes with an overview of the contributions to the book.

1.2 The Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Their Reform: State of the Art

Despite the significant political contestations surrounding fossil fuel subsidies and their reform, the literature – especially academic works – on the political dimensions of subsidies and their reform is surprisingly sparse. This is not to say that fossil fuel subsidies have evaded the literature altogether. Indeed, analyses abound on the macro-economic effects of fossil fuel subsidies (e.g. Oosterhuis and Umpfenbach Reference Oosterhuis, Umpfenbach, Oosterhuis and ten Brink2014; Coady et al. Reference Coady, Parry, Sears and Shang2015b, Reference Coady, Parry, Sears and Shang2017), the distributional consequences of subsidies (Arze del Granado and Coady Reference Arze del Granado and Coady2012; Coady et al. Reference Coady, Flamini and Sears2015a) and environmental implications, including subsidies’ effects on carbon dioxide emissions (Burniaux and Château Reference Burniaux and Château2014; Schwanitz et al. Reference Schwanitz, Piontek, Bertram and Luderer2014; Mundaca Reference Mundaca2017) and the possibilities for redirecting the savings from reform to climate change mitigation (Jakob and Hilaire Reference Jakob and Hilaire2015; Matsuo and Schmidt Reference Matsuo and Schmidt2017). Moreover, recent scholarship has started to investigate the political dimensions of fossil fuel subsidies.

Roughly, we can identify three strands of research relating to the politics of fossil fuel subsidies. The first consists of overviews on the issue, mainly on the basis of literature reviews and often focusing on strategies for reform rather than on explanations for the existence of fossil fuel subsidies (Victor Reference Victor2009; Commander Reference Commander2012; Strand Reference Strand2013; van Asselt and Skovgaard Reference van Asselt, Skovgaard, Van de Graaf and Sovacool2016; Rentschler and Bazilian Reference Rentschler and Bazilian2017a; Rentschler and Bazilian Reference Rentschler and Bazilian2017b; Sovacool Reference Sovacool2017). Much of this literature consists of policy reports by NGOs aimed at providing advice to stakeholders interested in reform (e.g. Beaton et al. Reference Beaton, Gerasimchuk and Laan2013; Merrill et al. Reference Merrill, Bassi, Bridle and Christensen2015; Whitley and van der Burg Reference Whitley and van der Burg2015), including lessons from single-case studies on attempts at reform (Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010; IISD 2014). Thus, while this strand is characterised by an interest in the politics of fossil fuel subsidy reform, it includes relatively few attempts to develop analytical frameworks that could form the basis of systematic case studies (but see Rentschler and Bazilian Reference Rentschler and Bazilian2017a). We argue that such systematic approaches can make it easier to draw lessons from several cases and gauge the respective influence of different factors.

A second strand of research seeks to do just this by explaining the existence and level of fossil fuel subsidies through comparative and quantitative studies (Overland Reference Overland2010; Cheon et al. Reference Cheon, Urpelainen and Lackner2013, Reference Cheon, Lackner and Urpelainen2015; Benes et al. Reference Benes, Cheon, Urpelainen and Yang2015; Kim and Urpelainen Reference Kim and Urpelainen2015; Inchauste and Victor Reference Inchauste and Victor2016; Ross et al. Reference Ross, Hazlett and Mahdavi2017). These existing studies tend to focus on consumption subsidies – particularly to petroleum products (e.g. petrol, kerosene) in developing countries – and pay less attention to other kinds of subsidies. While the quantitative studies have focused on the level of fossil fuel subsidies as the dependent variable (Cheon et al. Reference Cheon, Urpelainen and Lackner2013, Reference Cheon, Lackner and Urpelainen2015; Kim and Urpelainen Reference Kim and Urpelainen2015), the comparative case studies have focused on a limited set of country cases that differ on the dependent variable, namely successful reform (Overland Reference Overland2010; Inchauste and Victor Reference Inchauste and Victor2016).

In spite of their differences in approach, the first two strands have identified a largely overlapping set of factors influencing fossil fuel subsidies and the possibilities for reforming them. Several of these factors operate in the intersection between the political and economic spheres (Inchauste and Victor Reference Inchauste and Victor2016). Furthermore, the focus tends to be on structural factors. Among the analyses more attuned to the role of specific actors, Victor (Reference Victor2009) distinguishes between demand and supply factors influencing fossil fuel subsidies. The former concern the demand for subsidies from special interest groups, including both producers and consumers of fossil fuels. These special interest groups seek rents (in the form of subsidies) at the expense of the general welfare, i.e. the state budget (Victor Reference Victor2009; Inchauste and Victor Reference Inchauste and Victor2016). Key to this behaviour is the nature of fossil fuel subsidies as simultaneously a visible and specific benefit to these groups and an invisible and diffuse cost to the general public (Victor Reference Victor2009; Inchauste and Victor Reference Inchauste and Victor2016). The supply factors concern why governments choose to supply the subsidy rather than employ other policy instruments, which according to Victor (Reference Victor2009) is due particularly to the nature of fossil fuel subsidies as a visible and – in fossil fuel–exporting countries – easily available instrument. Related to this, Cheon et al. (Reference Cheon, Lackner and Urpelainen2015) identify the presence of state-owned national oil companies as a factor influencing the level of fossil fuel subsidies.

When it comes to more structural factors, scholars have focused on the role of fossil fuel reserves and global fossil fuel prices in influencing the level of fossil fuel subsidies and the possibilities for reform (Overland Reference Overland2010; Benes et al. Reference Benes, Cheon, Urpelainen and Yang2015; Kojima and Koplow Reference Kojima and Koplow2015; Rentschler and Bazilian Reference Rentschler and Bazilian2017b). Other structural factors include institutional or governance capacity (Commander Reference Commander2012; Cheon et al. Reference Cheon, Urpelainen and Lackner2013), the kind of state providing the subsidies (including how decentralised political power is; see Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015), whether the political system is democratic or authoritarian (Overland Reference Overland2010; Kim and Urpelainen Reference Kim and Urpelainen2015) and path dependency, which can make it difficult to remove fossil fuel subsidies once they are in place (Victor Reference Victor2009; Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015). The findings from this body of literature indicate that countries with weak institutional capacity, authoritarian rule, and significant fossil fuel reserves are more likely to subsidise fossil fuels.

A third strand has examined the politics of fossil fuel subsidies at the international level, including the efforts to promote fossil fuel subsidy reform (Besada and Olender Reference Besada and Olender2015; Van de Graaf and van Asselt Reference Van de Graaf and van Asselt2017). Some have focused on the question of how international institutions influence reform at the domestic level. Smith and Urpelainen (Reference Smith and Urpelainen2017) examine the voluntary commitments adopted under the G20 and Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) and explain how the reputational costs of flouting these commitments may drive countries to stick with planned reforms. Similarly, Aldy (Reference Aldy2017) argues that the G20 commitment and review of fossil fuel subsidies can help overcome domestic opposition to fossil fuel subsidy reform by providing legitimacy and facilitating learning between countries. Other studies have focused on the interplay between international institutions addressing fossil fuel subsidies. In this regard, Skovgaard (Reference Skovgaard2017) reveals how competing definitions of fossil fuel subsidies within the IMF and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) came about. A further question that has been addressed is why some international institutions have not addressed fossil fuel subsidies. Scholars of international relations and international law have been particularly vexed by the fact that fossil fuel subsidies have largely escaped the scrutiny of the World Trade Organization (WTO) – particularly when compared to renewable energy subsidies, several of which have been subject to legal challenges (Asmelash Reference Asmelash2015; Wold et al. 2015; De Bièvre et al. Reference De Bièvre, Espa and Poletti2017; Meyer Reference Meyer2017).

While the existing literature has thus provided valuable insights into the politics of fossil fuel subsidies, we believe that a comprehensive collection of scholarly analyses of the politics of fossil fuel subsidies, bridging the international and domestic levels, is both timely and useful.

1.3 An Analytical Framework for Understanding the Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies

As discussed earlier, the academic literature identifies different factors that determine how the politics of fossil fuel subsidies at the international and domestic level influence the eventual outcome of maintaining or reforming subsidies. In the analytical framework presented in this section, we distinguish a set of broad political factors at each level. The factors may influence fossil fuel subsidies and their reform at different stages of the policy cycle, including agenda-setting, policy formulation and, ultimately, (successful) implementation. To identify the various factors, we draw on social science fields and disciplines such as political economy, public policy and international relations.

Although both the domestic and international levels matter for our analysis, the political dynamics at each level are different. A key aspect of this difference is that fossil fuel subsidies are ultimately adopted and discontinued at the domestic level. The difference in political dynamics is evident: at the international level, there is an emerging consensus that fossil fuel subsidies should be reformed, whereas the domestic level is characterised by varying degrees of obstacles to, and support for, such reform. Consequently, at the domestic level we will focus on political factors that either hinder or promote fossil fuel subsidy reform. At the international level we will focus on the ways in which international institutions and actors address fossil fuel subsidies and how they influence the domestic level, including cases in which international institutions and actors give diverging signals and the absence of a signal from some institutions. We employ the distinction between the international and domestic levels in the analytical framework outlined below, as well as in the organisation of this book.

1.3.1 The International Level

Two sets of political dynamics can be distinguished with regard to fossil fuel subsidies and their reform at the international level. A first set of dynamics concerns the ways in which – and reasons why – different kinds of international institutions and actors have started to address fossil fuel subsidy reform or, in some cases, why they failed to do so. International efforts to tackle fossil fuel subsidy reform can be traced back to a (growing) number of international organisations (e.g. the IEA, IMF and OECD) and countries (mostly acting through forums such as the G20, APEC and the Friends of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform). We are interested in how and why these organisations and country groupings have begun to address fossil fuel subsidies. Similarly, we are interested in why other institutions, particularly the WTO and the UNFCCC, have largely refrained from addressing them. The absence of any effort from an international institution can in itself form an obstacle to promoting fossil fuel subsidy reform, since domestic actors opposed to reform can point to the inactivity of these institutions. The relevant institutions range from international organisations addressing economic, development and environmental issues to clubs of powerful – and less powerful – countries to NGOs.

We identify four broad and interdependent political factors that help explain whether and how international institutions address fossil fuel subsidies. The first factor concerns the role of individual actors within the institutions, be they individual employees or member states seeking to influence the institution’s stance on fossil fuel subsidies (see also Skovgaard Reference Skovgaard2017). Such actors include – but are not limited to – policy entrepreneurs that invest financial, material and reputational resources to bring about policy change (Kingdon Reference Kingdon2003: 122–24), as well as norm entrepreneurs articulating and promoting new norms (Finnemore and Sikkink Reference Finnemore and Sikkink1998: 896–99), including the norm of fossil fuel subsidy reform. The second factor is the constellation of member state interests (Sprinz and Vaahtoranta Reference Sprinz and Vaahtoranta1994). Which states participate in an institution matters a lot in this respect, especially in institutions that allow a single member state to block decisions (since the inclusion of one state opposed to fossil fuel subsidy reform could veto a decision). According to this perspective, fossil fuel exporters are generally expected to oppose promoting fossil fuel subsidy reform at the international level (since it would lower global demand for their fuel exports). Third, ideational factors include how fossil fuel subsidies and the norm of fossil fuel subsidy reform are framed and whether these framings ‘fit’ with the prevalent ideational structures and objectives of particular institutions (Johnstone Reference Johnston2001). Fossil fuel subsidies can be framed in terms of their environmental or economic consequences, among others, and one would expect economic framings to resonate better with economic institutions and environmental framings to resonate better with environmental institutions. Finally, interaction with other institutions (Oberthür and Stokke Reference Oberthür and Stokke2011) may influence whether and how an institution addresses fossil fuel subsidies. A concrete example would be the G20 tasking the IEA, the OECD, the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) and the World Bank with analysing the magnitude and consequences of fossil fuel subsidies.

A separate set of dynamics concerns the degree to which – and the pathways through which – international actors and institutions exert influence on fossil fuel subsidy reform at the domestic level. We identify three causal pathways that may be relevant to fossil fuel subsidies, drawing from the literature on the influence of the international level on domestic politics (Dobbin et al. Reference Dobbin, Simmons and Garrett2007; Bernstein and Cashore Reference Bernstein and Cashore2012). First, there is the functional-rationalist pathway of international actors and institutions affecting domestic politics by increasing the incentives for complying with the institution (Keohane Reference Keohane1984). For example, actors and institutions may provide resources for compensating those affected negatively by fossil fuel subsidy reform or increase the reputational costs of non-compliance with international commitments. A second pathway is coercion, through which external restraints are placed on domestic actors (Hurd Reference Hurd1999), for example, through the threat of sanctions (e.g. potentially the WTO) or conditionalities (e.g. the IMF or World Bank). Third, through an ideational pathway, international actors and institutions can affect the norms and ideas that shape how domestic actors perceive an issue (Finnemore and Sikkink Reference Finnemore and Sikkink1998), for instance, by promoting the norm that fossil fuel subsidies should be reformed. Besides the dissemination of norms, this pathway also covers learning – or the dissemination of knowledge on the ‘best’ way to achieve an objective based on the experiences of other actors (Dobbin et al. Reference Dobbin, Simmons and Garrett2007: 460) – such as reforming fossil fuel subsidies in a way that avoids public protests.

1.3.2 The Domestic Level

We distinguish three broad and interdependent political factors that influence fossil fuel subsidies and their reform at the domestic level. The first factor focuses on the interests, strategies and organisation of actors – including both individuals and organisations – that have sought to promote reform of fossil fuel subsidies or to keep them in place (cf. Sabatier and Weible Reference Sabatier and Weible2014). As was the case at the international level, these actors include – but are not limited to – policy and norm entrepreneurs. Regarding strategies, such actors may have actively sought to put fossil fuel subsidies on the national political agenda or instead thwarted such agenda-setting efforts, framed particular measures as fossil fuel subsidies with economic or environmental costs or as poverty-reduction or competition policies with economic benefits, built alliances and coalitions to promote or counter reform and communicated the benefits of fossil fuel subsidies or their reform to policymakers and the public. Rapid changes to other factors, such as oil prices, may offer windows of opportunity for these actors, since the timing of any significant policy change may be crucial to its chances of reform (Kingdon Reference Kingdon2003). Regarding organisation, as Victor (Reference Victor2009) underscores, the level of subsidies in a country (especially for fossil fuel production) is influenced by how well-organised the interest groups benefiting from these subsidies are. These interest groups may coalesce around the subsidies, making it difficult to get rid of those subsidies. The organisation of actors opposed to fossil fuel subsidies is also important; although they tend to be less organised into institutionalised interest groups than the actors supporting subsidies, alliances cutting across different political parties, ministries and NGOs may have an important influence on fossil fuel subsidy reform. A key aspect of this factor is that the benefits of maintaining fossil fuel subsidies tend to be visible and concentrated on specific groups (e.g. fossil fuel producers and recipients of consumer subsidies, such as car owners), whereas the benefits of fossil fuel subsidy reform are often less tangible and more diffuse across time and space (e.g. improved fiscal balances and environmental improvements benefiting the population as a whole, including future generations).

Third, ideational factors, such as the knowledge, ideas, norms and beliefs guiding different actors (Jenkins-Smith et al. Reference Jenkins-Smith, Nohrstedt, Weible, Sabatier, Sabatier and Weible2014), can have an influence on subsidy reform. At the domestic level, a recurring issue has been the question of whether a given policy or measure is defined as a fossil fuel subsidy, with opponents claiming that the support constitutes a subsidy and proponents arguing that it does not. New knowledge about fossil fuel subsidies, particularly about their environmental and socio-economic effects, can also be an important factor in the discussions concerning fossil fuel subsidies. Likewise, discourses linking fossil fuel subsidies to growth, development and competitiveness may be influential. Ideational factors may closely interact with political dynamics at the international level; for instance, the norm of fossil fuel subsidy reform promulgated at the international level could be taken up and promoted by domestic norm entrepreneurs (see above).

Lastly, structural factors, particularly the broader socio-political characteristics of a country, may influence fossil fuel subsidies and their reform. These factors are all unlikely to change in the short to medium term and are more difficult to change. They include a state’s governance capacity, structural power relations, and macro-economic factors – characteristics that (often in combination) may lead to the lock-in of fossil fuel subsidies. Governments with a low governance capacity tend to subsidise fossil fuels because they lack the capacity to implement other, more complex welfare policy instruments such as cash transfers (Victor Reference Victor2009; Commander Reference Commander2012; Cheon et al. Reference Cheon, Urpelainen and Lackner2013; Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015). In such situations, fossil fuel subsidies can become an important part of the social contract between the government and the population. Fossil fuel subsidies can also be embedded in structural power relations that support certain kinds of activities (fossil fuel production and consumption) that are defined as integral to the economy. Doing so can reinforce and further entrench such power relations by empowering particular actors (private companies) or favouring activities (fossil fuel extraction) over others. These socio-political characteristics are often intertwined with macro-economic factors such as the level of income or growth, income inequalities and the composition of the national economy, especially the economy’s degree of dependence on fossil fuels (i.e. the extent to which a country’s economy is diversified). While this book does not focus on macro-economic factors alone, we believe that including macro-economic factors among the other political factors outlined in this framework can provide a useful contribution. Several of these characteristics may contribute to locking in fossil fuel subsidies in countries, for instance, by creating constituencies that seek to maintain subsidies and keep the country on a fossil fuel–intensive pathway (Victor Reference Victor2009). Such possible feedback loops – in which fossil fuel subsidies strengthen the factors that keep them in place – are important factors worth exploring further.

1.4 Plan of This Book

The main body of this book comprises three parts, in addition to this introductory chapter and our conclusions. Part II outlines the scope of the problem of fossil fuel subsidies and the challenge of reforming them. The chapters in this part set the stage for the rest of the book by discussing key issues that are important to fossil fuel subsidies as a phenomenon and hence relevant to the politics of fossil fuel subsidies both at the international and domestic levels. A key aspect of this challenge is the absence of agreement on a definition of fossil fuel subsidies and the ensuing debates on whether and to what degree a given country subsidises fossil fuels. Different definitions – and, related to this, ways of measuring – are the principal reasons why global fossil fuel subsidy estimates vary, with the IMF’s estimate totalling ten times higher than that of the IEA. In Chapter 2, Doug Koplow explains the most common approaches to defining and measuring subsidies to fossil fuels that underpin current global estimates and discusses the key causes of estimate variance and measurement gaps. He further illustrates the importance of the choice of definition by discussing the variation in estimates of fossil fuel subsidies in the United States. Koplow argues that the areas of agreement among approaches to measure subsidies often are broader than the variance in estimates suggests. In Chapter 3, Shelagh Whitley and Laurie van der Burg focus on another aspect of fossil fuel subsidies, namely the rationale for subsidy reform. The authors draw attention to the various economic, social and environmental consequences of subsidies and highlight the benefits of, as well as opportunities for, their reform. Synthesising the findings from existing case studies of reform, Whitley and van der Burg suggest a set of key principles that can help make fossil fuel subsidy reform a success. In Chapter 4, Peter Newell and Phil Johnstone place fossil fuel subsidies and the struggle to reform them within the wider context of the politics of energy transitions and decarbonisation. Drawing on political economy literature, they focus on the structural factor of power relations that sustain what they term ‘fossil fuel incumbency’. Furthermore, they suggest that at the international level fossil fuels are characterised by ‘ungovernance’ – i.e. the absence of governance. Newell and Johnstone thus present the challenge to reform fossil fuel subsidies as a key site in the broader struggle to decarbonise the global economy.

Part III focuses on international political dynamics. The chapters in this part focus on governance efforts by international actors and institutions to promote fossil fuel subsidy reform – or the absence thereof – rather than efforts to maintain these subsidies. This is because the international level – as evidenced by G20 statements and the inclusion of fossil fuel subsidy reform in the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals – has been characterised by a broad consensus that fossil fuel subsidies should be reformed. Chapter 5, by Thijs Van de Graaf and Mathieu Blondeel, sets the stage by examining fossil fuel subsidy reform as a nascent international norm, thus focusing on ideational dynamics at the international level. Drawing on the constructivist literature on international norms, they explain the top-down emergence and incomplete diffusion of this norm. The chapter outlines how the norm was institutionalised in international forums following the G20 commitment and diffused among countries to varying degrees. Van de Graaf and Blondeel find that this development is due to the active role of norm entrepreneurs (e.g. NGOs such as the Global Subsidies Initiative and the Obama administration in the United States), political opportunity structures (especially the financial crisis) and the contested nature of the norm, which makes it easy to commit to the norm but also difficult to detect norm violation.

Whereas Van de Graaf and Blondeel focus on norm dynamics across and between different international institutions, the subsequent chapters study cases of specific international (intergovernmental as well as non-governmental) institutions which play or could play crucial roles in influencing the politics of fossil fuel subsidy and their reform at the domestic level. Chapter 6, by Jakob Skovgaard, addresses the role of international economic institutions (the G20, IMF, OECD and World Bank) in promoting fossil fuel subsidy reform in the United States, the United Kingdom, India, Indonesia and Denmark. Skovgaard analyses the ideational, learning and power-based pathways through which international economic institutions influenced the domestic politics of fossil fuel subsidies, examining to what degree the institutions caused or helped shape fossil fuel subsidy reform. He finds that while fossil fuel subsidy reform (or the absence thereof) in all countries was mainly driven by domestic factors, international institutions also exerted influence on the domestic politics of fossil fuel subsidies by promoting the norm of fossil fuel subsidy reform, encouraging learning (in the cases of India and Indonesia) and through power-based influences (in the case of Indonesia).

Turning to a set of key international institutions that are most conspicuous for not addressing fossil fuel subsidies, in Chapter 7, Ron Steenblik, Jehan Sauvage and Christina Timiliotis first analyse how the global trade regime has dealt with fossil fuel subsidies. They explain how international ideational dynamics have meant that existing rules and norms on subsidies have largely not been used to deal with fossil fuel subsidies. As a result, not a single challenge of fossil fuel subsidies has taken place in the WTO context. The authors discuss several ways in which the world trading system could help address fossil fuel subsidies, noting in particular the potential of regional and plurilateral trade agreements as well as soft-law approaches. Like the WTO, fossil fuel subsidies have also by and large flown under the radar of the international climate regime. In Chapter 8, Harro van Asselt, Laura Merrill and Kati Kulovesi show that notwithstanding mounting evidence of the climate impacts of fossil fuel subsidies – and, conversely, the climate benefits of their possible reform – consideration of policies to address fossil fuel production or consumption has been mostly absent in the rule development under the UNFCCC. However, they suggest that this situation is slowly changing and that the global climate regime can play a role in promoting subsidy reform through different pathways, i.e. by imposing reputational costs if voluntary commitments are reneged upon, improving transparency, offering incentives to steer financial flows away from fossil fuels, amplifying the emerging norm of fossil fuel subsidy reform and presenting a framework for learning and building institutional capacity.

Chapter 9, by Vernon Rive, addresses another key institution in the international politics of fossil fuel subsidies, namely the informal Friends of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform, which is the only intergovernmental initiative dedicated to the reform of fossil fuel subsidies. Adopting a constructivist norm perspective – and focusing on international ideational dynamics related to those described by Van de Graaf and Blondeel – Rive explores the origins of the initiative, its activities as a norm entrepreneur to promote subsidy reform and its interactions with other international institutions. He concludes that the Friends initiative has been hindered by its lack of an unequivocal definition of fossil fuel subsidies, although it has succeeded in promoting the norm of fossil fuel subsidy reform – especially through the endorsement of its 2015 Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform Communiqué by a range of countries and non-state actors – and in framing fossil fuel subsidies in terms of negative fiscal and climate consequences.

In Chapter 10, Nathan Lemphers, Steven Bernstein and Matthew Hoffmann analyse the role of the Global Subsidies Initiative, one of the most important and influential international NGOs working in the area of fossil fuel subsidy reform. Employing a framework that focuses on the mechanisms through which the status quo of carbon lock-in can be challenged, Lemphers and colleagues explain how the Global Subsidies Initiative has acted as a norm entrepreneur by building coalitions and capacity for fossil fuel subsidy reform and by helping normalise fossil fuel subsidy reform. As a result, the Initiative has been influential in scaling up and entrenching the commitment to reform fossil fuel subsidies through its interaction with international institutions and countries pursuing or seeking to further subsidy reform.

Part IV of the book focuses on the domestic politics of fossil subsidies in six selected countries. Some chapters focus on cases of (partial) successful reform (Egypt, India and Indonesia). Other chapters focus on countries that have undertaken fossil fuel subsidy reform only to a limited extent (Trinidad and Tobago) or not at all (Colombia and South Africa).

Chapter 11, by Kathryn Chelminski, begins this part by examining fossil fuel consumption subsidies in Indonesia. Looking at three different periods of reform in the past two decades, Chelminski assesses whether Indonesia can indeed be seen as a successful case of reform. Specifically, she looks at whether the reforms are lasting, whether they reduce government expenditure and whether they lead to increased government revenue and a better distribution of overall benefits. By doing so, she sheds light on the role of different factors in bringing about successful reform, including actor strategies such as political leadership communication campaigns and reallocating funds for social assistance. She also looks at the organisation of actors – particularly extractive industries, trade associations and national oil companies opposed to reform – as well as structural factors such as the financial crisis and fuel price fluctuations. The strategy of reallocating funds saved through fossil fuel subsidy reform is also the main focus of Chapter 12, by Abhishek Jain, Shalu Agrawal and Karthik Ganesan, who study the Direct Benefit Transfer Scheme for Liquefied Petroleum Gas in India. The programme is a large-scale conditional cash-transfer scheme implemented to reform cooking fuel subsidies. Drawing on extensive stakeholder consultations, Jain and colleagues discuss and explain the performance of the programme. They find that it was largely successful in its implementation and in meeting its objectives, thanks to political leadership at the national level, coordination between governmental departments, learning from past experience and raising awareness among the target audience.

The next two chapters both focus on producer subsidies. In Chapter 13, Jesse Burton, Tawney Lott and Britta Rennkamp contextualise their political economy analysis of fossil fuel subsidies in South Africa by presenting new estimates of subsidies to the coal and liquid fuels sectors of the country. Doing so allows the authors not only to better understand the economic and distributional impacts of the subsidies but also to investigate the motivations behind the support to those sectors. Focusing on the strategies and organisation of actors supporting the subsidy as well as structural factors, Burton and colleagues explain that the support to fossil fuel producers is not framed as a ‘subsidy’ by the government but rather as an investment necessary for economic development; such support has become locked in because of the benefits to elite actors within government and industry. In Chapter 14, Claudia Strambo, Ana Carolina González Espinosa, Angélica Puertas Velasco and Aaron Atteridge likewise precede their analysis with an overview of fossil fuel producer subsidies in the country. The authors examine why and how producer subsidies were put (and kept) in place in Colombia. They point to framing strategies employed by the coal sector and the national government – through which coal mining was treated alongside other extractive industries, notwithstanding important differences – as well as the structural factors of the legacy of decades-long internal conflicts and the resulting low governance capacity of the state.

Chapter 15, by Tom Moerenhout, discusses the case of Egypt, a country where subsidy reforms were implemented in a turbulent context, namely following the Arab Spring. Moerenhout explains why the aftermath of the Egyptian revolution was an opportune moment for subsidy reform. Drawing on behavioural realism, Moerenhout introduces the key political actors – including notably the military – and examines how actor constellations have changed since the reform began in 2014. He finds that the reason reform was possible in 2014 – the Egyptian people buying into a changing social contract – became undermined when the structural factor of economic hardship was not relieved and the government reverted to authoritarian rule.

In Chapter 16, Michelle Scobie looks at the situation of a small island state that is also an oil and gas producer, Trinidad and Tobago. Scobie examines the key actors in favour of, and opposed to, subsidy reform (including domestic actors as well as international actors such as the IMF). She considers the strategies or frames that those actors employ – focusing on arguments related to economic prudence, climate and energy justice and environmental stewardship – and the key structural factors determining the outcome of reform. She finds that while the constellation of actors and framings has hardly changed, policy change is possible. She thus suggests that contextual factors, such as the economic crisis and fluctuating oil prices, played a key role.

Finally, in Chapter 17, we synthesise the main findings from the various chapters with respect to our analytical framework and return to the overall puzzle that inspired this book: the disconnect between high-level political commitment to and emerging consensus on the benefits of reform and the low level of concerted action on reforming fossil fuel subsidies. The chapter concludes by identifying fruitful areas for further research on the politics of fossil fuel subsidies and their reform.

References

Aldy, J. E. (2017). Policy surveillance in the G-20 fossil fuel subsidies agreement: lessons for climate policy. Climatic Change 144(1), 97110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K. and McKibben, W. J. (2000). Reducing coal subsidies and trade barriers: their contribution to greenhouse gas abatement. Environment and Development Economics 5(4), 457–81.Google Scholar
Arze del Granado, F. J. and Coady, D. (2012). The unequal benefits of fuel subsidies: a review of evidence for developing countries. World Development 40(11), 2234–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asmelash, H. B. (2015). Energy subsidies and WTO dispute settlement: why only renewable energy subsidies are challenged. Journal of International Economic Law 18(2), 261–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaton, C. and Lontoh, L. (2010). Lessons Learned from Indonesia’s Attempts to Reform Fossil-Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Beaton, C., Gerasimchuk, I., Laan, T., et al. (2013). A Guidebook to Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Benes, K., Cheon, A., Urpelainen, J. and Yang, J. (2015). Low Oil Prices: An Opportunity for Fuel Subsidy Reform. New York, NY: Columbia University Center on Global Energy Policy.Google Scholar
Bernstein, S. and Cashore, B. (2012). Complex global governance and domestic policies: four pathways of influence. International Affairs 88(3), 585604.Google Scholar
Besada, H. G. and Olender, M. (2015). Fossil fuel subsidies and sustainable energy for all: the governance reform debate. Global Governance 21(1), 7998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burniaux, M. and Château, J. (2014). Greenhouse gases mitigation potential and economic efficiency of phasing-out fossil fuel subsidies. International Economics 140, 7188.Google Scholar
Carrington, D. (2015). Fossil fuels subsidised by $10m a minute, says IMF. The Guardian, 18 May 2015.Google Scholar
Cheon, A., Lackner, M. and Urpelainen, J. (2015). Instruments of political control: national oil companies, oil prices, and petroleum subsidies. Comparative Political Studies 48(3), 370402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheon, A., Urpelainen, J. and Lackner, M.. (2013). Why do governments subsidize gasoline consumption? An empirical analysis of global gasoline prices, 2002–2009. Energy Policy 56, 382–90.Google Scholar
Clements, B., Coady, D., Fabrizio, S. et al. (2013). Energy Subsidy Reform: Lessons and Implications. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Coady, D., Flamini, V. and Sears, L. (2015a). The Unequal Benefits of Fuel Subsidies Revisited: Evidence for Developing Countries. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Coady, D., Parry, I., Sears, L. and Shang, B. (2015b). How Large Are Global Energy Subsidies? Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Coady, D., Parry, I., Sears, L. and Shang, B. (2017). How large are global fossil fuel subsidies? World Development 91(C), 1127.Google Scholar
Commander, S. (2012). A guide to the political economy of reforming energy subsidies. IZA Policy Paper No. 52, Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.Google Scholar
De Bièvre, D. Espa, I. and Poletti, A. (2017). No iceberg in sight: on the absence of WTO disputes challenging fossil fuel subsidies. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 17(3), 411–25.Google Scholar
Dobbin, F., Simmons, B. and Garrett, G. (2007). The global diffusion of public policies: social construction, coercion, competition, or learning? Annual Review of Sociology 33, 449–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finnemore, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998). International norm dynamics and political change. International Organization 52(4), 887917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Group of Twenty (G20) (2009). Leaders’ Statement: The Pittsburgh Summit. Pittsburgh, PA: G20.Google Scholar
Holzinger, K. and Knill, C. (2005). Causes and conditions of cross-national policy convergence. Journal of European Public Policy 12(5), 775–96.Google Scholar
Hurd, I. (1999). Legitimacy and authority in international politics. International Organization 53(2), 379408.Google Scholar
Inchauste, G. and Victor, D. G., eds. (2016). The Political Economy of Energy Subsidy Reform. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
International Energy Agency (IEA) (2016). World Energy Outlook 2016. Paris: IEA.Google Scholar
International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD) (2014). India Energy Subsidy Briefing. Geneva: IISD.Google Scholar
Jakob, M. and Hilaire, J. (2015). Using importers’ windfall savings from oil subsidy reform to enhance international cooperation on climate policies. Climatic Change 131(4), 465–72.Google Scholar
Jenkins-Smith, H. C., Nohrstedt, D., Weible, C. M. and Sabatier, P. A. (2014). Advocacy coalition framework: foundations, evolution, and ongoing research. In Theories of the Policy Process, ed. Sabatier, P. A. and Weible, C. M.. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 183284.Google Scholar
Johnston, A. I. (2001). Treating international institutions as social environments. International Studies Quarterly 45(4), 487515.Google Scholar
Jowit, J. (2015). Growth at all costs: climate change, fossil fuel subsidies and the Treasury. The Guardian, 24 May 2015.Google Scholar
Keohane, R. O. (1984). After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kim, S. E. and Urpelainen, J. (2015). Democracy, autocracy and the urban bias: evidence from petroleum subsidies. Political Studies 64(3), 552–72.Google Scholar
Kingdon, J. W. (2003). Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. New York, NY: Longman.Google Scholar
Kojima, M. and Koplow, D. (2015). Fossil fuel subsidies: approaches and valuation. Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS 7220, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Koplow, D. and Dernbach, J. (2001). Federal fossil fuel subsidies and greenhouse gas emissions: a case study of increasing transparency for fiscal policy. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 26, 361–89.Google Scholar
Larsen, B. and Shah, A. (1992). World fossil fuel subsidies and global carbon emissions. Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS 1002, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Lockwood, M. (2015). Fossil fuel subsidy reform, rent management and political fragmentation in developing countries. New Political Economy 20(4), 475–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuo, T and Schmidt, T. S. (2017). Hybridizing low-carbon technology deployment policy and fossil fuel subsidy reform: a climate finance perspective. Environmental Research Letters 12(1), 19.Google Scholar
Merrill, L., Bassi, A. M., Bridle, R. and Christensen, L. T. (2015). Tackling Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Climate Change: Levelling the Energy Playing Field. Copenhagen: Nordic Council of Ministers.Google Scholar
Meyer, T. (2017). Explaining energy disputes at the World Trade Organization. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 17(3), 391410.Google Scholar
Mundaca, G. (2017). How much can CO2 emissions be reduced if fossil fuel subsidies are removed? Energy Economics 64, 91104.Google Scholar
New Indian Express (2015). FinMin draws path for subsidy rationalisation. The New Indian Express, 4 April 2015.Google Scholar
Oberthür, S. and Stokke, O. S., eds. (2011). Managing Institutional Complexity: Regime Interplay and Global Environmental Change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oosterhuis, F. and Umpfenbach, K. (2014). Energy subsidies. In Paying the Polluter: Environmentally Harmful Subsidies and Their Reform, ed. Oosterhuis, F. and ten Brink, P.. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 105–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2017). Development aid rises again in 2016 but flows to poorest countries dip. Available at www.oecd.org/dac/development-aid-rises-again-in-2016-but-flows-to-poorest-countries-dip.htm (accessed 19 April 2018).Google Scholar
Overland, I. (2010). Subsidies for fossil fuels and climate change: a comparative perspective. International Journal of Environmental Studies 67(3), 303–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rentschler, J. and Bazilian, M. (2017a). Principles for designing effective fossil fuel subsidy reforms. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 11(1), 138–55.Google Scholar
Rentschler, J. and Bazilian, M. (2017b). Reforming fossil fuel subsidies: drivers, barriers and the state of progress. Climate Policy 17(7), 891914.Google Scholar
Ross, M. L., Hazlett, C. and Mahdavi, P. (2017). Global progress and backsliding on gasoline taxes and subsidies. Nature Energy 2(1), 16201.Google Scholar
Sabatier, P. A. and Weible, C. M., eds. (2014). Theories of the Policy Process, 3rd edn. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Schwanitz, V. J., Piontek, F., Bertram, C. and Luderer, G. (2014). Long-term climate policy implications of phasing out fossil fuel subsidies. Energy Policy 67, 882–94.Google Scholar
Skovgaard, J. (2017). The devil lies in the definition: competing approaches to fossil fuel subsidies at the IMF and the OECD. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 17(3), 341–53.Google Scholar
Smith, J. and Urpelainen, J. (2017). Removing fuel subsidies: how can international organizations support national policy reforms? International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 17(3), 327–40.Google Scholar
Sovacool, B. K. (2017). Reviewing, reforming, and rethinking global energy subsidies: towards a political economy research agenda. Ecological Economics 135, 150–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sprinz, D. and Vaahtoranta, T. (1994). The interest-based explanation of international environmental policy. International Organization 48(1), 77105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strand, J. (2013). Political economy aspects of fuel subsidies: a conceptual framework. Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS 6392, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) (2010). Decision 2/CP.15, Copenhagen Accord. UN Doc. FCCC/CP/2009/11/Add.1 (30 March 2010). Bonn: UNFCCC.Google Scholar
van Asselt, H. and Skovgaard, J. (2016). The politics and governance of energy subsidies. In The Palgrave Handbook of the International Political Economy of Energy, ed. Van de Graaf, T., Sovacool, B. K., et al. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 269–88.Google Scholar
Van de Graaf, T. and van Asselt, H. (2017). Introduction to the special issue: energy subsidies at the intersection of climate, energy and trade governance. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 17(3), 313–26.Google Scholar
Victor, D. (2009). The Politics of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Whitley, S. and van der Burg, L. (2015). Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform: From Rhetoric to Reality. London: The New Climate Economy.Google Scholar
Wold, C., Wilson, G. and Foroshani, S. (2012). Leveraging climate change benefits through the World Trade Organization: are fossil fuel subsidies actionable? Georgetown Journal of International Law 43(3), 635–94.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×