Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T15:52:03.014Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Investing in French Overseas Companies: A Bad Deal? The Liquidation Processes of Companies Operating on the West Coast of Africa and in India (1664–1719)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 May 2019

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Although French chartered companies operating on the west coast of Africa and in India followed a similar model of organization, their liquidation processes differed depending of the area of their monopoly. As well as exploring the reasons for the distinction between these two regions of exclusive trade, this article demonstrates that the differing liquidation processes negatively impacted company shareholders in the two regions. Taking the perspective of shareholders farther, it explores the case of a specific investor and the informal economic profits he benefitted from. This approach contributes to deepening our understanding of the French early modern companies’ bankruptcies by examining informal aspects that would not be readily visible from an exclusively institutional point of view.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © 2019 Research Institute for History, Leiden University

French overseas companies in the early modern period were frequently declared insolvent, with the famous bankruptcy of the Company of the Indies in 1720, following the Mississippi Bubble, being one of many examples of their economic failure.Footnote 2 Other royal companies, too, suffered the same fate, with both the West and East India Companies, for instance, which were established in 1664, ultimately going bankrupt.Footnote 3 But how did these overseas companies’ insolvencies affect their shareholders? Although French chartered companies operating on the west coast of Africa and in India followed a similar model of organization, their liquidation processes differed depending of the area of their monopoly. As well as exploring the reasons for the distinction between these two regions of exclusive trade, this article examines whether the differing liquidation processes impacted differently on shareholders.

What set the French overseas companies apart from their Dutch and most of their English counterparts was the prominent role played by the state in their funding.Footnote 4 In the French case, the decision to declare a chartered company bankrupt was a choice made by the king or his naval minister, regardless of shareholders’ opinions. However, despite the repeated bankruptcies and the French Crown's control of their management, these companies still found investors. This article also aims, therefore, to examine these chartered companies’ failures from the shareholders’ perspective by exploring their possible informal economic profits. This approach contributes to deepening our understanding of the French early modern companies’ bankruptcies by examining informal aspects that would not be readily visible from an exclusively institutional point of view.

The article starts by examining the different types of liquidations witnessed among chartered companies operating on the west coast of Africa and in India between the creation of the East and West India Companies in 1664 and the dissolution of the East India Company in 1719. The various processes associated with the companies’ insolvencies need to be examined in detail if we are to understand why these processes differed and also whether they entailed differing consequences for shareholders. The second part of the article takes the perspective of a specific investor and the informal profits his investments in chartered companies brought him. The conclusion assesses how this change in perspective adds to our understanding of French early modern bankruptcies.

Formal and Informal Bankruptcies

French overseas companies operating on the west coast of Africa and in the Indian Ocean between 1664 and 1719 underwent multiple formal and varying degrees of informal bankruptcies. While the companies under scrutiny in this article followed a similar organizational pattern, their bankruptcy processes varied. When the West India Company was declared bankrupt in 1674, only ten years after being established, the king took full responsibility for all the company's debts, which amounted to around three million livres, while also contributing two hundred and fifty thousand livres to reimburse voluntary subscriptions.Footnote 5 The king's decision to take over all the company's debts and reimburse some of the subscriptions can be partly explained by his role in financing and managing the West India Company.

Firstly, his naval minister, Jean-Baptiste Colbert, had been the main initiator of the French West India Company in 1664, while the king himself was also a major shareholder. A document from 1684 shows how the king owned around a quarter of the West India Company's capital (27.4%), while just under half (44%) came from financiers close to the Crown.Footnote 6 Early modern French financiers were individuals involved in handling the revenues of the French monarchy; as well as collecting these revenues, they provided short-term loans to the king.Footnote 7 As such they were part of what is called by Guy Rowlands the French “fisco-financial” system.Footnote 8 Furthermore, some 11 percent of the company's capital came from a specific group of financiers, who had been ordered to pay fines in 1661 by an exceptional judicial institution, the Chamber of Justice.Footnote 9 Through the Chamber of Justice, the king forced these convicted individuals to invest part of their fines in the West India Company. As these subscriptions were not considered “voluntary,” they did not fall within the category of shares eligible for reimbursement by the king.

Another part of the explanation for the king's involvement in repaying the company's debts and other amounts owed to shareholders was that by terminating the West India Company, the king enabled lands falling under the company's jurisdiction to be tax farmed in order to finance the company's debts. The right to collect taxes in, for example, the French West Indies, which became known as the Domaine d'Occident, was granted to financiers in return for annual payments of three hundred and fifty thousand livres to the king. Of this, two hundred and fifty thousand livres was intended to be used to cover the company's debts.Footnote 10 All French overseas possessions in the Atlantic, with the exception of the Senegambian Coast, then became part of the Royal Domain and were opened up to all French private traders. The newly founded Senegal Company was granted a thirty-year exclusive privilege to trade on the Senegambian coast in 1674, and the whole west coast of Africa in 1681.Footnote 11

However, the prominent role played by the king and the naval minister in the West India Company can hardly be considered specific to that company. Indeed, the French East India Company, which was created by Colbert in the same year as the West India Company, shared many organizational features with its western counterpart, most particularly with regard to the state's ability to intervene. The patent letters establishing the two companies’ privileges and obligations were also almost identical and became the model for the Guinea Company and the reorganized East India Company that succeeded them in 1685.Footnote 12 The main differences were to be found in the areas covered by their exclusive trading privileges and their duration; a fifty-year privilege from the Cape of Good Hope to the South Sea for the East India Company, and a forty-year privilege from the west coast of Africa to the West Indies and the Americas in the case of the West India Company.Footnote 13 The king and the royal family were also major investors in the East India Company, as evidenced by the fact that, in 1667, the majority of the other shareholders were financiers and courtiers.Footnote 14 By 1668, and so only a few years after the chartering of the East and West India Companies, the king and his minister appointed themselves the directors.Footnote 15 As a result, the companies’ accounts were controlled by individuals chosen by Colbert, while management of both companies was largely in the hands of the minister.

Although the East India Company suffered financial difficulties as early as 1671, it was not officially declared bankrupt like the West India Company. Instead, in 1675 and for the first time in seven years, Colbert held a general assembly with the directors of the company to seek more funds.Footnote 16 The king had already given an additional four million livres to the East India Company, and the shareholders were then asked to contribute at least eight thousand livres each. But despite this increase in capital, Colbert ultimately had to open up the trade to private merchants in 1682.Footnote 17 Declaring the East India Company bankrupt does not seem to have been regarded as an option for Colbert or his successor as naval minister, Jean-Baptiste Colbert de Seignelay.

Seignelay's strategy was to start a process described by Kaeppelin as “informal bankruptcy.”Footnote 18 In 1684, he asked all the company's shareholders to increase their investments by one-quarter of their existing shareholdings. Otherwise, they would be excluded from the company and only a quarter of their existing investments would be repaid. One-eighth of the shareholders accepted this request. Seignelay then declared that the company had to be restructured. Instead of dividing the capital into many shares of one thousand livres, as Colbert had done, Seignelay created a system in which twelve investors each provided thirty thousand livres, or four-fifths of the capital needed.Footnote 19 In this way he drastically limited access to the shares and steered the French chartered companies even further away from the joint-stock model initially followed.Footnote 20

Although the East India Company was not declared bankrupt in 1685, it nevertheless underwent certain deep organizational changes that adversely affected its shareholders. Article 5 of the East India Company's patent letter and Article 8 of that of its western homologue guaranteed that investors’ personal property would be protected from creditors of the companies.Footnote 21 In the case of the West India Company, the fact that the king took full responsibility for the debts meant that the shareholders’ limited liability was respected. While this was not at stake during the East India Company's reorganization, there was no benefit in limited liability if the naval minister could arbitrarily ask for more funds from shareholders under penalty of being excluded from the company, even though Article 2 of the East India Company's patent letter explicitly stated that “no directors or shareholders will be forced to provide any funds beyond the capital they already invested in the Company at its creation.”Footnote 22 It appears from these first two cases that, for investors, it was better for the company to be officially declared bankrupt. The shareholders’ rights specified in the patent letter of 1664 were respected in the bankruptcy of the West India Company, even though only voluntary shareholders were repaid, whereas the informal liquidation of the East India Company blatantly ignored shareholders’ right not to be forced to increase their investments in the company.

However, the successors of the West India Company did not benefit from the Crown's protection and support to the same degree. Instead, the naval minister applied the strategy of replacing the current group of shareholders with a new group willing to provide more funds. Indeed, in 1685, patent letters creating the Guinea Company were issued. This company's area of exclusive trading privilege conflicted with a trading monopoly that had been granted to the Senegal Company a few years earlier. In order to revoke part of the privilege granted to the Senegal Company, the naval minister argued that the Senegal Company had not delivered the number of enslaved Africans it had committed to providing, that its area of monopoly was too vast, and that part of the area under exclusive trading privilege should therefore be given to a new company.Footnote 23

Seignelay created the Guinea Company on the same model as the reorganized East India Company, with a dozen main shareholders providing the total capital.Footnote 24 The same mechanism was used twenty-five years later, when the Guinea Company was replaced by the Asiento Company: the king granted the exclusive trading privilege of the Guinea Company to a new group of shareholders under the pretext that the Guinea Company had not met its obligations. More credibly, the abrogation of the Guinea Company's privilege happened while a larger commercial contract, the Spanish Asiento (granting a monopoly to supply enslaved Africans to Spanish America), was being negotiated. When France and Spain signed the treaty granting the Asiento to a French chartered company on 14 September 1701, the French King needed a company to take on the contract.Footnote 25 As a result, it was decided to establish the Asiento Company, with sixteen new shareholders taking over the exclusive trading privilege and the debts of the Guinea Company.

Unlike the investors in the West India Company, the Senegal and Guinea Companies’ shareholders were not compensated for the loss of their privileges. Since no official bankruptcy had been declared, no official indemnity was granted. The arbitrary nature of the termination (or partial termination) of the Senegal and Guinea Companies resembled the informal liquidation of the East India Company back in 1685. One major difference with the East India Company, however, was the higher rate of informal liquidations and changes of companies operating on the west coast of Africa: four in total until 1701. This contrasted with the East India Company, where, despite its weak financial position, the next liquidation was not seen until 1719, when the Company of the Indies was established thirty-four years after the East India Company's first reorganization.

The 1685 reorganization of the East India Company did not, however, prevent the company's downfall. Indeed, by 1702, the company was in such difficulties that the king lent it eight hundred and five thousand livres and pressured shareholders to increase their capital investment by 50 percent.Footnote 26 Once again, the king breached Article 2 of the East India Company's patent letter, which stated that shareholders would not be forced to increase their capital. By 1708, however, the directors of the East India Company were desperate to start bankruptcy proceedings. In October that year, therefore, they sent a joint letter to the naval minister, Jérôme Phélypeaux, count of Pontchartrain, explaining that some of the “creditors have already seized the possessions of multiple directors, have assaulted one of them, and the same creditors will exert pressure on the assets of the heirs of the directors and shareholders who have passed away.”Footnote 27 Rather, however, than allowing the directors of the company to start bankruptcy proceedings, the naval minister came up with some solutions for paying the most pressing creditors and, in 1708, granted licences allowing private traders to engage in commerce in the company's area of exclusive privilege. Not only were the shareholders coerced into investing more money, but their limited liability guaranteed by Article 5 of the East India Company's patent letter was also not respected.

By this time, the company was clearly perceived as a state matter as its failure would have incurred “immense costs.”Footnote 28 Apart from the financial consequences, it would have resulted in the loss of the settlements in Asia, and this, in turn, would have weakened the French presence in Euro-Asian commerce and intra-Asian trade. The period between the end of the seventeenth and early eighteenth century witnessed changes in the European power relations in Asia. The Dutch East India Company's position was gradually fading, while the English and the French were gaining strength in Asia.Footnote 29 For France, therefore, losing all its strongholds in the region during that period would have put an end to any chance of its developing a stronger commercial position in Asia and competing with its European rivals.

The solution devised was to postpone the bankruptcy proceedings to the end of the War of Spanish Succession. The French East India Company was consequently kept artificially alive for a further thirteen years, with the decision to prolong the company being purely politically motivated. As the company could not find replacements for directors who had died, a royal edict was issued to force their heirs to designate successors to attend the meetings of the company and, most importantly, to take on the deceased persons’ share of the debts.Footnote 30 In 1709, the shareholders finally reached a deal with merchants from Saint Malo in partnership with a wealthy businessman, Antoine Crozat. This partnership was granted the exclusive privilege to trade in India, without having to endorse the company's debts, and the right to retain the settlements in exchange for 10 percent of the partnership's profit.Footnote 31 When the charter granted to the French East India Company came to an end in 1715, it was extended for a further ten years, probably in an attempt to repay all the debts. In 1719, however, the newly created Company of the Indies created by John Law bought off the privileges and debts of the East India Company in return for issuing twenty-five million shares. One year later, John Law's Company of the Indies was declared bankrupt and the shares lost all their value.

By contrasting the different bankruptcies and informal liquidations of the companies operating on the west coast of Africa and in India, we can see that the East India Company was artificially maintained afloat for most of its existence. The West India Company, by contrast, was declared bankrupt ten years after being established, and its successor companies underwent regular informal liquidations, as shown by the frequent change in shareholders and in the names of the companies trading on the west coast of Africa. The divergent trajectories can be explained by the king's political interest in keeping French settlements in Asia as a means of maintaining trading connections. However, the artificial survival of the East India Company was to the detriment of its shareholders. Despite appearances to the contrary, the position of the shareholders in the East India Company was no better than that of their western counterparts. The regular and arbitrary changes in shareholders in the companies operating on the west coast of Africa mirror the frequent and forced increases in investment demanded of shareholders in the East India Company. The fact that the shareholders could neither declare the bankruptcy of nor sell their shares in their company is evidence in both cases of their total lack of power.

A Shareholder's Perspective

The rights of the shareholders—although explicitly stated in the patent letters—were blatantly disregarded in practice. Shareholders knew that the decision of the King or the Naval Minister ultimately prevailed. In the event of financial difficulties, the Crown could prematurely terminate a company's activities with little if any compensation for the shareholders. Alternatively it could choose to keep the company artificially afloat by requiring shareholders, willingly or otherwise, to increase their investment. From an institutional perspective, therefore, shareholders were essentially victims of the varying liquidation processes. Viewing the matter from an informal perspective may therefore provide a different understanding of the role of the companies’ bankruptcies or liquidations. If companies were repeatedly in precarious financial positions and the decision-making powers regarding the possibility of declaring them bankrupt were entirely in the hands of the King or the Naval Minister, could shareholders nevertheless hope for informal economic profits?

To explore the investors’ perspective in more detail, this section analyses the case of Hugues Mathé de Vitry-la-Ville, a shareholder in the Guinea Company and East India Company (1685) among other investments. Vitry-la-Ville is a relevant investor to focus on because he would appear to be representative of the group of shareholders to which he belonged. Firstly, and like the vast majority of investors in French overseas companies, he was a financier in the sense that he handled the king's revenues and was well connected through family ties to the world of finance.Footnote 32 He held the title of General Receiver of Finances of Châlons as he invested in other tax-collecting offices.Footnote 33

Secondly, like many of his fellow shareholders in the overseas companies, he invested in multiple enterprises. He was one of the main shareholders of the Compagnie du Bastion de France, which operated in North Africa, and was involved in tax collecting in Canada, which had been farmed out in return for payment of two hundred and twenty thousand livres after the bankruptcy of the West India Company.Footnote 34 In 1685, he became a shareholder in the Guinea Company and a director of the East India Company.Footnote 35 His fellow investors in the Guinea Company included Parent, who was a director of the reorganized East India Company (1685); Carrel, who was a tax farmer for the Domaine d'Occident; Dumas, who had invested in the first East India Company (1664) and the Senegal Company, as well as the Canada tax farm; and Pallu du Ruau, who had served as a director of the West India Company (1664). Meanwhile his fellow shareholders in the East India Company that was reorganized in 1685 included de Frémont, who had been a shareholder in the West India Company (1664) and invested in the Compagnie du Nord.

Thirdly, Vitry-la-Ville was declared bankrupt in 1687. While his inventory offers a unique insight into the informal investments and strategies of an overseas company shareholder, his poor financial situation was relatively common among financiers of his time. The assumption that financiers were all extremely wealthy is incorrect; it appears that most of them were not as rich as they were made out to be. Indeed, their main possessions consisted of royal revenues, bonds, and company shares, which were not as safe as ownership of land, since the value of these investments did not always correspond to the nominal value.Footnote 36 In his study on financiers during the reign of Louis XIV, Daniel Dessert concluded that 25 percent of them went bankrupt or ended up in an uncomfortable financial position. For the purpose of this article, Vitry-la-Ville and his fellow investors in the French overseas companies under scrutiny are primarily considered as businessmen rather than as holders of office. The focus here is placed on their informal economic profit and, in particular, their private trade in the trading areas of the companies they invested in.Footnote 37

Originally the companies had had a monopoly on these markets, both in India and on the west coast of Africa. However in 1682, the East India Company extended its privileges to private merchants by issuing a series of five-year licences that enabled merchants to access the Indian market, subject to a requirement to use the company's ships and to pay a fee amounting to 10 percent of the value of commodities shipped to India and from India.Footnote 38 Vitry-la-Ville had managed to gain access to this monopoly market a few years before he became a shareholder as, through his partnership with Jean-Baptiste Pocquelin, a shareholder of the East India Company before its reorganization, Vitry-la-Ville had sent 107,000 livres on one of the company's ships, the Saint François d'Assise, which sailed to India in October 1682.Footnote 39 Vitry-la-Ville and Pocquelin also asked whether they could use the company's infrastructure in India (i.e., its trading posts) in return for payment.Footnote 40

In February 1683, Vitry-la-Ville and Pocquelin sent 125,109 livres on the Blampignon, while in November of that same year they shipped one hundred thousand livres of commodities on each of the three vessels the company sent to India.Footnote 41 In January 1684, the East India Company paid them 254,590 livres for the first part of their merchandise, while in November 1684 they received 440,720 livres for the rest of the cargo.Footnote 42 Overall, they made 263,201 livres of profit. Most of the licences for accessing the East India Company's market in those years were granted to Pocquelin and Vitry-la-Ville.Footnote 43 Being shareholders in the company gave financiers the opportunity to use the company's infrastructure to engage in private trade. Unsurprisingly, therefore, the 1685 register of the company's shareholders included Vitry-la-Ville, who had seen for himself how profitable the Indian market could be; in other words, the company was economically attractive to Vitry-la-Ville not because of its formal and institutional aspects, but instead because of informal benefits such as market access.

Indeed, the inventory of Vitry-la-Ville's possessions drawn up after his bankruptcy in 1687 shows evidence of his private trade in India as a shareholder of the East India Company.Footnote 44 At the time of the inventory, Vitry-la-Ville still had two hundred and fifty thousand livres of textiles in a warehouse in Rouen, described in the sources as “painted textiles.” These textiles can be assumed to be from India, given that all the companies’ ships transporting Vitry-la-Ville's commodities in the early 1680s arrived in Rouen. Furthermore, the commodity itself, painted textiles, was one of the major Indian goods brought to France. Additionally, Vitry-la-Ville had thirty-five thousand livres of corals shipped to Surat and Siam. As well as precious metal, corals were also major exchange goods in the trade with Asia.Footnote 45 Since the Mediterranean was an important source for these commodities, they probably came from Vitry-la-Ville's involvement in the Compagnie du Bastion de France.Footnote 46 Corals connected the commodity chains between the two markets; therefore, it made economic sense for Vitry-la-Ville to be simultaneously a major shareholder in the Compagnie du Bastion de France—he owned one-quarter of the company—and one of the twelve main shareholders in the East India Company. Lastly, the inventory stated that Vitry-la-Ville owned eight thousand livres worth of commodities on the Gold Coast. These could have been textiles from India, as these commodities were an important exchange good in trade on the west coast of Africa. This shows once again how the various companies in which Vitry-la-Ville invested were connected.

Final confirmation of Vitry-la-Ville's private business as a shareholder in the overseas companies can be seen in the bottomry loan—a contract combining credit and insurance—that he made for four thousand livres to Jean-Baptiste Du Casse. Du Casse was himself one of the founders of the Guinea Company and a former shareholder of the Senegal Company. In contrast to most of the other shareholders, however, he had made his career in the Royal Navy.Footnote 47 As Du Casse was a key figure in the nascent French slave trade, the voyage that was partially insured by Vitry-la-Ville was probably a slave trade voyage.Footnote 48 This voyage may have been that of 1687, when Du Casse sailed to the Bight of Benin on the King's ship La Tempête, arriving at Martinique in 1688 with 287 enslaved Africans.Footnote 49 Apart from engaging in slave trade, Du Casse was tasked with making a detailed description of the potential commercial opportunities and other European forts in the region for the king and the Guinea Company. Through a bottomry loan, Vitry-la-Ville indirectly contributed to Du Casse's enterprise, which probably also entailed some private trade. In this way, he enabled Du Casse to trade in the region covered by the monopoly of the Guinea Company, in which both men were shareholders.

Vitry-la-Ville was far from being the only person involved in private trade through the company. Indeed, such involvements seem to have been common practice. The official archive of the East India Company records how Le Brun, another shareholder, had asked the company official in Pondicherry to sell emeralds for his account.Footnote 50 Being a shareholder in French overseas companies provided easier access to monopoly markets for private merchants such as Vitry-la-Ville, Pocquelin, Du Casse, Le Brun and others. While companies granted licences, access to these licences in the early days of both the African trade and the Indian trade was still restricted to certain individuals, many of whom were shareholders in the companies. It was the hope of earning a profit through informal access to markets that compensated shareholders for the investment they made in a company that did not perform well on a formal level. While the investments in multiple colonial enterprises were risky and controlled by the state, they could nevertheless enabled private merchants to diversify their investments, thereby spreading the risk across different markets and commodities. Additionally, these investments enabled businessmen to connect these various markets by controlling both ends of the commodity chains.

As shown, however, by the example of Vitry-la-Ville, the multiple investments in contracts, offices, and companies did not always produce the desired results as, despite their informal access to monopoly markets, financiers still went bankrupt. Whether his investments in overseas companies played a role in Vitry-la-Ville's bankruptcy is, however, unclear. While it cannot be clearly established how much profit was made from private trade by shareholders of the companies under scrutiny, it has been demonstrated that there was an informal side to shareholder investments and that the narrative cannot, therefore, be limited to the various liquidation processes of the companies. In 1701, the exploitation of markets under monopoly by shareholders of overseas companies moved to another level, with the next generation of shareholders in the Asiento Company.Footnote 51 Through these informal investments, French overseas companies increasingly acted as front companies for shareholders wanting to develop private trade. Could the various liquidation processes, and their impact on the companies' shareholders have been a necessary evil in order to gain access to the markets under monopoly?

Conclusion

From an institutional perspective, the French overseas companies’ repeated bankruptcies and informal liquidations were in most cases disadvantageous to the shareholders. Although investors could receive minor amounts of compensation during company reorganizations, as in the case of the East India Company in 1685, most of the time they did not. More importantly, the right to decide whether to initiate bankruptcy proceedings was entirely in the hands of the naval minister and the king. This meant that companies could be consistently terminated or maintained against the will of their shareholders. Despite following different trajectories, therefore, the failures of the companies operating in the Indian Ocean and those active on the west coast of Africa all had adverse consequences for their shareholders.

On the one hand, although the first and only official bankruptcy of the West India Company was positive for most of the shareholders, who are reported to have been refunded the value of their shares, shareholders of the successor companies were not so lucky. These successor companies—the Senegal Company and the Guinea Company—underwent similar types of informal liquidations in 1685 and 1701 respectively, with no official bankruptcy being declared, but shareholders being put under pressure either to increase their investment in or to leave the company. On the other hand, while the East India Company did not undergo any major reorganization processes between 1685 and 1719, it does not mean that shareholders benefitted from a safer investment than their western counterparts. Instead, the latter was regarded as a state matter and was artificially kept alive to the detriment of investors, with shareholders being asked in 1708 to invest more capital, while the king also refused to let them leave the company.

However, despite the arbitrary powers of the King and the naval minister in the management of the overseas companies, shareholders invested in many such enterprises. From the shareholders’ point of view, they could still hope to make a profit, not necessarily formally, but probably more commonly by gaining access to markets under monopoly. Private trade through these companies’ infrastructures gave shareholders a competitive advantage and could compensate them for the money they invested in the companies. Furthermore, involvement in multiple overseas enterprises increased the merchants’ opportunities to connect both ends of commodity chains and to earn more profit. More information on other shareholders might confirm that they could use these state-sponsored companies as fronts for furthering their own business interests, while knowing that their investments in the official companies were likely to be lost.

Even though it is not possible to assess the exact informal profit made by shareholders, the existence of private trade has to be acknowledged when analysing companies’ liquidation processes and their impact on shareholders. The companies’ frequent formal and informal bankruptcies have to be understood, therefore, from both an institutional and an informal perspective. While further research on a larger group of shareholders will deepen our understanding of the relationship between investors and companies in general, the example of Vitry-la-Ville encourages us to change our perspective on French early modern companies bankruptcies. In light of his investments, it appears that the king and the naval minister provided shareholders with informal access to markets under monopoly through the various overseas companies and, in return for this, the companies were provided with regular capital reinvestments by the shareholders.

Footnotes

*

Elisabeth Heijmans is post-doctoral researcher at Leiden university. Her PhD focused on the directors of early modern French overseas companies and her current research relates to practices of law in the Dutch early modern empire.

This article has been written as part of the ERC-2012-StG-312657-FIGHT project.

2 On the reorganization of the Company of the Indies in 1719–1723 and its bankruptcy in 1793–1794, see Reference HaudrèreHaudrère, La Compagnie française des Indes; Reference FaureFaure, La Banqueroute de Law; Reference GirardGirard, “La Réorganisation de la Compagnie des Indes,” 5–34, 177–97; Reference Cross, Biard, Bourdin and LeuwersCross, “L'Anatomie d'un scandale,” 251–66.

3 For the East and West India and Senegal Companies, see Reference KaeppelinKaeppelin, La Compagnie des Indes orientales et François Martin; Reference AmesAmes, “Colbert's Indian Ocean Strategy,” 536–59; Reference MimsMims, Colbert's West India Policy; Reference ColeCole, Colbert and a Century of French Mercantilism; Reference LyLy, L’évolution du commerce français d'Afrique noire; Reference Banks, Van Ruymbeke and RoperBanks, “Financiers, Factors and French Proprietary Companies in West Africa,” 79–116.

4 The case of the Company of Royal Adventurers Trading into Africa (1660–1672) is an example of royal incursion in the financing and managing of an English chartered company. See Reference Heijmans, Antunes, Svalastog and RouletHeijmans et al., “Comparer les Compagnies de commerce européennes,”169.

5 Reference MimsMims, Colbert's West India Policy, 176.

6 Reference Dessert and JournetDessert and Journet, “Le lobby Colbert,” 1317.

7 Reference DurandDurand, Les fermiers généraux, 64; Reference DessertDessert, Argent, pouvoir et société, 719.

8 Reference RowlandsRowlands, Dangerous and Dishonest Men, 12.

9 Since all financiers were involved in collecting taxes for the king, the latter was entitled, through the Chamber of Justice, to ask financiers to show their account books. Despite some financiers benefitting from exemptions because of their direct relationship with the great noble families, many considered the Chamber of Justice to be Louis XIV's most impressive weapon against his creditors. Indeed, every Chamber of Justice enabled the Crown to cancel part of its debts and revoke some of the numerous venal offices. On the Chamber of Justice, see Reference Bosher, Cobban and BosherBosher, “Chambres de Justice in the French Monarchy,” 19–40. For a reappraisal of the Chamber of Justice, see Reference GoldnerGoldner, “Corruption on Trial,” 5–28.

10 Reference MimsMims, Colbert's West India Policy, 178.

11 Reference LyLy, L’évolution du commerce français d'Afrique noire, 120.

12 Only three of the forty-eight articles in the patent letter enumerating their privileges differed; see Reference CordierCordier, Les compagnies à charte et la politique coloniale. The patent letters of the companies are available at the Bibliothèque nationale de France [BNF] in Collection des actes royaux [CAR] 756, Edit … pour l'establissement de la Compagnie des Indes occidentales and 767, Edit … pour l'establissement de la Compagnie des Indes orientales; Archives nationales d'outre-mer [‘ANOM’] F2a11: Déclaration du Roy pour l’établissement d'une compagnie sous le titre de la Compagnie de Guinée, Paris, 1685, 10.

13 Reference BonnassieuxBonnassieux, Les grandes compagnies de commerce, 259. Reference ColeCole, Colbert and a Century of French Mercantilism, 4.

14 For details of the shareholders of the Compagnie des Indes orientales, see Dessert and Journet, 1314.

15 Reference HaudrèreHaudrère, La Compagnie française des Indes, 1:25.

16 These meetings were supposed to occur annually and bring together not only the directors, but also the shareholders.

17 Reference KaeppelinKaeppelin, La Compagnie des Indes orientales et François Martin, 129–34.

18 Reference KaeppelinKaeppelin, La Compagnie des Indes orientales et François Martin, 140–6.

19 The shareholders included Seignelay himself, de Frémont, de Lagny, Soullet, Pocquelin, De l'Isle, Desvieux, Parent Céberet du Boullaye, Le Brun, and Mathé de Vitry-la-Ville.

20 Reference Heijmans, Antunes, Svalastog and RouletHeijmans et al., “Comparer les Compagnies de commerce européennes,” 17.

21 BNF CAR 756, Article 8 and BNF CAR 767, Article 5.

22 BNF CAR 767, Article 2: “Les directeurs ny les Particuliers Interressés ne pourront estre tenus pour quelque chose ou prétexte que ce soit, de fournir aucune somme au delà de celle pour laquelle ils se seront obligés dans le premier establissement de la Compagnie, soit par manière de supplément ou autrement.”

23 ANOM F2A 11 “Arrest pour l’établissement de la compagnie de Guinée 1685: introduction.”

24 “Subroge à leurs intérêts un groupe de financiers nommés par le Roi de leur consentement. Frémont Morel de Boistiroux Soullet Mathé de Vitry-la-Ville Pocquelin de Lille des Vieux Parent Céberet du Boullay Le Brun et Tardif,” cited in Reference Dessert and JournetDessert and Journet, “Le lobby Colbert,” 1303–36.

25 ANOM F2a7: Asiento contract.

26 ANOM C2 9 f°39, 14 April 1703, East India Company directors.

27 ANOM C2 13 f°84, letter from the East India Company directors to Pontchartrain, 2 October 1708: “Quelques-uns de leurs créanciers ont déjà fait saisir réellement les biens de plusieurs directeurs on a attenté à la personne de l'un deux et les mêmes créanciers vont exercer leurs contraintes sur les effets des héritiers des décédés, tant actionnaires que directeurs.”

28 ANOM C2 13, f°10, letter addressed to the Controller General 1708: “que cette chute entrainerait avec elle la perte entière des établissements que la Compagnie a aux Indes et qui ont couté des sommes immenses.” Cited in Reference KaeppelinKaeppelin, La Compagnie des Indes, 567.

29 Reference NierstraszNierstrasz, In the Shadow of the Company, 77.

30 ANOM C2 12 f°160; f°179, f°202, Letters of the Directors to Pontchartrain and “Arrêt du conseil,” 18 January 1707 in Dernis, Recueil ou collection des titres, 253.

31 For an introduction to Antoine Crozat, see Reference ClaeysClaeys, Dictionnaire biographique des financiers en France, 576–7.

32 His grandfather had previously been general controller of Champagne; see Reference DessertDessert, Argent, pouvoir et société, 643–44.

33 Archives nationales [AN] E//673/A f°155, arrêt du conseil d’État, 4 March 1698: He was receveur des tailles des élections of Troyes and Reims and involved in the affaires extraordinaires under Colbert.

34 Reference DessertDessert, Argent, pouvoir et société, 393.

35 AN MC//ET/CV/915, Direction de Vitry-la-Ville, 24 March 1787.

36 Reference DessertDessert, Argent, pouvoir et société, 129–30.

37 For an extensive analysis of investment strategies and motivations of shareholders see Reference HeijmansHeijmans, The Agency of Empire, 41–84.

38 ANOM C2 5, East India Company directors, 17 November 1682.

39 ANOM C2 5, East India Company directors, 16 October 1682.

40 ANOM C2 5, East India Company directors, 21 January 1682.

41 ANOM C2 5, East India Company directors, 27 February 1683 and 17 November 1683.

42 ANOM C2 5, East India Company directors, 5 January 1684 and 16 November 1684.

43 “Table de la navigation des Français aux Indes de 1665 à 1720”; in Reference KaeppelinKaeppelin, La Compagnie des Indes, appendix.

44 AN MC// ET/ CV/ 915 Direction de Vitry-la-Ville, 24 March 1787.

45 ANOM C2 66 f°5 letter from Martin to the company directors on 22 February 1701: “entre les marchandises de débit à Pondichéry le corail qui a la meilleure,” and Reference FurberFurber, Rival Empires of Trade in the Orient, 261.

46 AN E//649/A, arrêt du conseil d’État: “J'ay des coraux travaillés dont partie sont chargés sur les vaisseaux du Roy pour Siam, en grains et branches de la valeur par estimation de 3 000 livres; Coraux bruts en chemin de Port Louis pour estre chargé pour Surat 17 caisses de la valeur de 32 000 livres.” Reference TrivellatoTrivellato, The Familiarity of Strangers, 226.

47 Reference HrodejHrodej, L'amiral Du Casse: l’élévation d'un Gascon sous Louis XIV, vol. 2 (Paris: Librairie de l'Inde, 1999), 661.

48 Jean-Baptiste Du Casse became governor of Saint Domingue in 1691 and was a major actor in the negotiation of the Asiento contract (the contract to supply slaves to the Spanish Americas) in 1701; see Reference HrodejHrodej, “L'amiral Du Casse,” 30.

49 http://www.slavevoyages.org/voyage/33751/variables, most recently consulted on 10 May 2018.

50 ANOM C2 66 f°11, letter from Martin, 2 February 1701.

51 Reference HeijmansHeijmans, The Agency of Empire, 71–79.

References

Bibliography

Archives nationales d'outre-mer (Aix-en-Provence) [ANOM]:Google Scholar
-Série C2 administration en FranceGoogle Scholar
-Série C2 correspondance à l'arrivéeGoogle Scholar
-Série F documents divers: F2a7–11 Compagnies de commerceGoogle Scholar
Archives nationales (Paris) [AN]:Google Scholar
-AN série E Conseil du Roi:Google Scholar
-AN minutier central des notairesGoogle Scholar
Bibliothèque nationale de France [BNF]:Google Scholar
-Mélanges ColbertGoogle Scholar
Dernis. Recueil ou collection des titres, édits, déclarations, arrêts, règlemens et autres pièces concernant la Compagnie des Indes orientales établie au mois d'août 1664. 4 vols. Paris, 1755.Google Scholar
BNF, Collection des actes royaux [CAR] 756, Edit … pour l'establissement de la Compagnie des Indes occidentalesGoogle Scholar
BNF, Collection des actes royaux [CAR] 767, Edit … pour l'establissement de la Compagnie des Indes orientalesGoogle Scholar
Ames, Glenn Joseph. “Colbert's Indian Ocean Strategy of 1664–1674: A Reappraisal.” French Historical Studies 16,:3 (1990): 536–59.Google Scholar
Banks, Kenneth. “Financiers, Factors and French Proprietary Companies in West Africa, 1664–1713.” In Constructing Early Modern Empires: Proprietary Ventures in the Atlantic World, 15001750, edited by Van Ruymbeke, B. and Roper, L. H., 79116. Leiden: Brill, 2007.Google Scholar
Bonnassieux, Pierre. Les grandes compagnies de commerce. Paris: Plon, 1892.Google Scholar
Bosher, John Francis. “‘Chambres de Justice’ in the French Monarchy.” In French Government and Society 1500–1850: Essays in Memory of Alfred Cobban, edited by Cobban, Alfred and Bosher, John Francis, 1940. London: Athlone Press, 1973.IGoogle Scholar
Claeys, Thierry. Dictionnaire biographique des financiers en France au XVIIIe siècle. Paris: SPM, 2011.Google Scholar
Cole, Charles Woolsey. Colbert and a Century of French Mercantilism. New York: Columbia University Press, 1939.Google Scholar
Coornaert, Emile. “European Economic Institutions and the New World: The Chartered Companies.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Europe from the Decline of the Roman Empire, edited by Rich, E. E. and Wilson, C. H., 4:220–74. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Cordier, Louis. Les compagnies à charte et la politique coloniale sous le ministère de Colbert. Paris: Université de Nancy, 1906.Google Scholar
Cross, Elizabeth. “L'Anatomie d'un scandale: l'Affaire de la Compagnie des Indes révisitée (1793–1794).” In Vertu et politique: les pratiques des législateurs, edited by Biard, Michel, Bourdin, Philippe, and Leuwers, Hervé, 251–66. Rennes: Presses Universitaires de Rennes, 2015.Google Scholar
Dessert, Daniel. Argent, pouvoir et société au Grand Siècle. Paris: Fayard, 1984.Google Scholar
Dessert, Daniel, and Journet, Jean-Louis. “Le lobby Colbert: un royaume ou une affaire de famille?Annales. Économies, Sociétés, Civilisations 30:6 (1975): 1303–36.Google Scholar
Durand, Yves. Les fermiers généraux au XVIIIe siècle. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1971.Google Scholar
Faure, Edgar. La Banqueroute de Law, 17 juillet 1720. Paris: Gallimard, 1977.Google Scholar
Furber, Holden. Rival Empires of Trade in the Orient, 1600–1800. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Girard, A.La Réorganisation de la Compagnie des Indes (1719–1723).” Revue d'histoire moderne et contemporaine XI (1908–1909): 5–34; 177–97.Google Scholar
Goldner, Erik. “Corruption on Trial: Money, Power, and Punishment in France's ‘Chambre de Justice’ of 1716.” Crime, Histoire & Sociétés / Crime, History & Societies 17:1 (2013): 528.Google Scholar
Haudrère, Philippe. “Les actionnaires de la première Compagnie française des Indes orientales, 1664–1684.” In Les Français dans l'océan Indien (XVIIe-XIXe siècles), edited by Haudrère, Philippe, 31–6. Rennes: Presses Universitaires de Rennes, 2014.Google Scholar
Haudrère, Philippe. La Compagnie française des Indes au XVIIIe siècle. 2e éd. 2 vols. Paris: Les Indes Savantes, 2005.Google Scholar
Heijer, Henk den. De geoctrooieerde compagnie. De VOC en de WIC als voorlopers van de naamloze vennootschap. Amsterdam: Deventer, 2005.Google Scholar
Heijmans, Elisabeth. The Agency of Empire: Personal Connections and Individual Strategies in the Shaping of the French Expansion (1686–1746). PhD diss., Leiden University, 2018.Google Scholar
Heijmans, Elisabeth, Antunes, Cátia, and Svalastog, Julie M.. “Comparer les Compagnies de commerce européennes: Les compagnies néerlandaise, anglaise et française sur la côte occidentale d'Afrique au cours du XVIIe siècle.” In Le monde des compagnies. Les premières compagnies dans l'Atlantique 1600–1650: I. Structures et mode de fonctionnement, edited by Roulet, Eric, 161–87. Aachen: Shaker Verlag, 2017.Google Scholar
Hrodej, L'amiral Du Casse: l’élévation d'un Gascon sous Louis XIV, vol. 2. Paris: Librairie de l'Inde, 1999.Google Scholar
Hrodej, Philippe. “L'amiral Du Casse: de la marchandise à la Toison d'Or.” Annales de Bretagne et des pays de l'Ouest 104:4 (1997): 2339.Google Scholar
Isenmann, Moritz ed. “Le monde marchand face au défi colbertien.” In Merkantilismus: Wiederaufnahme einer Debatte. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag, 2014.Google Scholar
Kaeppelin, Paul. La Compagnie des Indes orientales et François Martin: étude sur l'histoire du commerce et des établissements français dans l'Inde sous Louis XIV (1664–1719). Paris: Challamel, 1908.Google Scholar
Lespagnol, André.Négociants et commerce indien au début du XVIIIe siècle: l’épisode des ‘Compagnies malouines’ 1707–1719.” Annales de Bretagne et des pays de l'Ouest 86:3 (1979): 427–57.Google Scholar
Lüthy, Herbert. La banque protestante en France de la révocation de l'Edit de Nantes à la Révolution. 2 vols. Paris: SEVPEN, 1959.Google Scholar
Ly, Abdoulaye. L’évolution du commerce français d'Afrique noire dans le dernier quart du XVIIe siècle: la compagnie du Sénégal de 1673 à 1696. Bordeaux; Metz: Karthala, 1955.Google Scholar
Mims, Stewart L. Colbert's West India Policy. Yale Historical Publications. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1912.Google Scholar
Nierstrasz, Chris. In the Shadow of the Company: The Dutch East India Company and Its Servants in the Period of Its Decline (1740–1796). Leiden: Brill, 2012.Google Scholar
Pettigrew, William A. Freedom's Debt: The Royal African Company and the Politics of the Atlantic Slave Trade, 1672–1752. Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Rowlands, Guy. Dangerous and Dishonest Men: The International Bankers of Louis XIV's France. Palgrave Studies in the History of Finance. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2015.Google Scholar
Trivellato, Francesca. The Familiarity of Strangers: The Sephardic Diaspora, Livorno, and Cross-Cultural Trade in the Early Modern Period. Reprint edition. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
Archives nationales d'outre-mer (Aix-en-Provence) [ANOM]:Google Scholar
-Série C2 administration en FranceGoogle Scholar
-Série C2 correspondance à l'arrivéeGoogle Scholar
-Série F documents divers: F2a7–11 Compagnies de commerceGoogle Scholar
Archives nationales (Paris) [AN]:Google Scholar
-AN série E Conseil du Roi:Google Scholar
-AN minutier central des notairesGoogle Scholar
Bibliothèque nationale de France [BNF]:Google Scholar
-Mélanges ColbertGoogle Scholar
Dernis. Recueil ou collection des titres, édits, déclarations, arrêts, règlemens et autres pièces concernant la Compagnie des Indes orientales établie au mois d'août 1664. 4 vols. Paris, 1755.Google Scholar
BNF, Collection des actes royaux [CAR] 756, Edit … pour l'establissement de la Compagnie des Indes occidentalesGoogle Scholar
BNF, Collection des actes royaux [CAR] 767, Edit … pour l'establissement de la Compagnie des Indes orientalesGoogle Scholar
Ames, Glenn Joseph. “Colbert's Indian Ocean Strategy of 1664–1674: A Reappraisal.” French Historical Studies 16,:3 (1990): 536–59.Google Scholar
Banks, Kenneth. “Financiers, Factors and French Proprietary Companies in West Africa, 1664–1713.” In Constructing Early Modern Empires: Proprietary Ventures in the Atlantic World, 15001750, edited by Van Ruymbeke, B. and Roper, L. H., 79116. Leiden: Brill, 2007.Google Scholar
Bonnassieux, Pierre. Les grandes compagnies de commerce. Paris: Plon, 1892.Google Scholar
Bosher, John Francis. “‘Chambres de Justice’ in the French Monarchy.” In French Government and Society 1500–1850: Essays in Memory of Alfred Cobban, edited by Cobban, Alfred and Bosher, John Francis, 1940. London: Athlone Press, 1973.IGoogle Scholar
Claeys, Thierry. Dictionnaire biographique des financiers en France au XVIIIe siècle. Paris: SPM, 2011.Google Scholar
Cole, Charles Woolsey. Colbert and a Century of French Mercantilism. New York: Columbia University Press, 1939.Google Scholar
Coornaert, Emile. “European Economic Institutions and the New World: The Chartered Companies.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Europe from the Decline of the Roman Empire, edited by Rich, E. E. and Wilson, C. H., 4:220–74. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Cordier, Louis. Les compagnies à charte et la politique coloniale sous le ministère de Colbert. Paris: Université de Nancy, 1906.Google Scholar
Cross, Elizabeth. “L'Anatomie d'un scandale: l'Affaire de la Compagnie des Indes révisitée (1793–1794).” In Vertu et politique: les pratiques des législateurs, edited by Biard, Michel, Bourdin, Philippe, and Leuwers, Hervé, 251–66. Rennes: Presses Universitaires de Rennes, 2015.Google Scholar
Dessert, Daniel. Argent, pouvoir et société au Grand Siècle. Paris: Fayard, 1984.Google Scholar
Dessert, Daniel, and Journet, Jean-Louis. “Le lobby Colbert: un royaume ou une affaire de famille?Annales. Économies, Sociétés, Civilisations 30:6 (1975): 1303–36.Google Scholar
Durand, Yves. Les fermiers généraux au XVIIIe siècle. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1971.Google Scholar
Faure, Edgar. La Banqueroute de Law, 17 juillet 1720. Paris: Gallimard, 1977.Google Scholar
Furber, Holden. Rival Empires of Trade in the Orient, 1600–1800. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Girard, A.La Réorganisation de la Compagnie des Indes (1719–1723).” Revue d'histoire moderne et contemporaine XI (1908–1909): 5–34; 177–97.Google Scholar
Goldner, Erik. “Corruption on Trial: Money, Power, and Punishment in France's ‘Chambre de Justice’ of 1716.” Crime, Histoire & Sociétés / Crime, History & Societies 17:1 (2013): 528.Google Scholar
Haudrère, Philippe. “Les actionnaires de la première Compagnie française des Indes orientales, 1664–1684.” In Les Français dans l'océan Indien (XVIIe-XIXe siècles), edited by Haudrère, Philippe, 31–6. Rennes: Presses Universitaires de Rennes, 2014.Google Scholar
Haudrère, Philippe. La Compagnie française des Indes au XVIIIe siècle. 2e éd. 2 vols. Paris: Les Indes Savantes, 2005.Google Scholar
Heijer, Henk den. De geoctrooieerde compagnie. De VOC en de WIC als voorlopers van de naamloze vennootschap. Amsterdam: Deventer, 2005.Google Scholar
Heijmans, Elisabeth. The Agency of Empire: Personal Connections and Individual Strategies in the Shaping of the French Expansion (1686–1746). PhD diss., Leiden University, 2018.Google Scholar
Heijmans, Elisabeth, Antunes, Cátia, and Svalastog, Julie M.. “Comparer les Compagnies de commerce européennes: Les compagnies néerlandaise, anglaise et française sur la côte occidentale d'Afrique au cours du XVIIe siècle.” In Le monde des compagnies. Les premières compagnies dans l'Atlantique 1600–1650: I. Structures et mode de fonctionnement, edited by Roulet, Eric, 161–87. Aachen: Shaker Verlag, 2017.Google Scholar
Hrodej, L'amiral Du Casse: l’élévation d'un Gascon sous Louis XIV, vol. 2. Paris: Librairie de l'Inde, 1999.Google Scholar
Hrodej, Philippe. “L'amiral Du Casse: de la marchandise à la Toison d'Or.” Annales de Bretagne et des pays de l'Ouest 104:4 (1997): 2339.Google Scholar
Isenmann, Moritz ed. “Le monde marchand face au défi colbertien.” In Merkantilismus: Wiederaufnahme einer Debatte. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag, 2014.Google Scholar
Kaeppelin, Paul. La Compagnie des Indes orientales et François Martin: étude sur l'histoire du commerce et des établissements français dans l'Inde sous Louis XIV (1664–1719). Paris: Challamel, 1908.Google Scholar
Lespagnol, André.Négociants et commerce indien au début du XVIIIe siècle: l’épisode des ‘Compagnies malouines’ 1707–1719.” Annales de Bretagne et des pays de l'Ouest 86:3 (1979): 427–57.Google Scholar
Lüthy, Herbert. La banque protestante en France de la révocation de l'Edit de Nantes à la Révolution. 2 vols. Paris: SEVPEN, 1959.Google Scholar
Ly, Abdoulaye. L’évolution du commerce français d'Afrique noire dans le dernier quart du XVIIe siècle: la compagnie du Sénégal de 1673 à 1696. Bordeaux; Metz: Karthala, 1955.Google Scholar
Mims, Stewart L. Colbert's West India Policy. Yale Historical Publications. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1912.Google Scholar
Nierstrasz, Chris. In the Shadow of the Company: The Dutch East India Company and Its Servants in the Period of Its Decline (1740–1796). Leiden: Brill, 2012.Google Scholar
Pettigrew, William A. Freedom's Debt: The Royal African Company and the Politics of the Atlantic Slave Trade, 1672–1752. Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Rowlands, Guy. Dangerous and Dishonest Men: The International Bankers of Louis XIV's France. Palgrave Studies in the History of Finance. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2015.Google Scholar
Trivellato, Francesca. The Familiarity of Strangers: The Sephardic Diaspora, Livorno, and Cross-Cultural Trade in the Early Modern Period. Reprint edition. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2012.Google Scholar