Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-06T02:15:01.603Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Indefinitely repeated contests with incumbency advantage

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Cary Deck
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Finance, and Legal Studies, The University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa, AL 35487, USA
Zachary Dorobiala*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Finance, and Legal Studies, The University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa, AL 35487, USA
Paan Jindapon
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Finance, and Legal Studies, The University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa, AL 35487, USA
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We study an indefinitely repeated Tullock contest in which the stage-game winner gains an incumbency advantage in the next stage-game. The incumbent's advantage allows the incumbent to carry over a proportion of their expenditure in the previous contest to the next contest. Theoretically, this advantage is not predicted to have a large impact on total expenditure. However, in a controlled laboratory experiment, we find the incumbency advantage increases total expenditure by a significant amount. Further, we find that carryover has a discouraging effect on challengers while encouraging incumbents react in a retaliatory manner.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2024.

1 Introduction

Many activities can be viewed as contests where each party makes costly expenditures in the hopes of claiming a prize. Given the wide array of situations that can be viewed as contests, it is unsurprising that a large literature has been devoted to the study of such games (see Konrad Reference Konrad2009 and Dechenaux et al. Reference Dechenaux, Kovenock and Sheremeta2015 for surveys). However, the vast majority of the literature focuses on one-shot games, while many situations are better described as dynamically interconnected indefinitely repeated play games. One prominent example is competition between political parties in different election cycles. In such settings, the incumbent may hold an advantage. In this paper, we explore how such an advantage impacts behavior in an indefinitely repeated play contest. Formally, in our setting, a portion of the winner's expenditure in one contest can be carried over to the next contest. In controlled laboratory experiments, we find such carryover increases expenditure for both the incumbent who won in the previous period and the challenger who lost. Further, we find that carryover has a discouraging effect on challengers, while incumbents react in a retaliatory manner.

This paper connects the literature on indefinitely repeated contests with the literature on contests with carryover and incumbency advantage. Brookins et al. (Reference Brookins, Ryvkin and Smyth2021) compares indefinitely repeated and finitely repeated Tullock contests with equal expected durations. They find expenditures to be lower in the indefinitely repeated game, suggesting cooperative behavior between the contestants. Brookins et al. (Reference Brookins, Ryvkin and Smyth2021) also examines how the discount rate impacts cooperation and reports some evidence that cooperation is stronger when the discount rate is lower, but they do not consider any linkages between contests.Footnote 1 While Schmitt et al. (Reference Schmitt, Shupp, Swope and Cadigan2004) consider a setting with linkages in which both players can carryover investment from one period to the next, they do so in a finite horizon game. Schmitt et al. (Reference Schmitt, Shupp, Swope and Cadigan2004) find that carryover is sensitive to the decay rate and shifts expenditure to earlier periods, consistent with theoretical predictions. Interestingly, they also find that total expenditure is lower with carryover than without, even though they still observe overbidding as is common in contest experiments. Grossmann et al. (Reference Grossmann, Dietl and Lang2010) does examine carryover in an infinitely repeated contest, but does so in a setting where there is no incumbency advantage. Using dynamic programming, they derive equilibrium in steady states and further analyze the effects of revenue sharing on competitive balance between the two players. Baik and Lee (Reference Baik and Lee2000) also study carryover, but in a two-period model with a contest structure that is very different from that in Schmitt et al. (Reference Schmitt, Shupp, Swope and Cadigan2004), Grossmann et al. (Reference Grossmann, Dietl and Lang2010), and our paper. While there are papers that examine incumbency advantage (e.g., Hafer Reference Hafer2006, Polborn Reference Polborn2006, Virág Reference Virág2009, and Häfner & Nöldeke Reference Häfner and Nöldeke2019), these papers have done so in different settings from ours.

2 Theoretical framework

Consider an infinitely repeated Tullock contest with two players who, in each period, compete for a strictly positive prize V by choosing a non-negative expenditure level. We assume that both players are risk neutral and the common discount factor for their future income is β ( 0 , 1 ) per period. We denote player i's expenditure and his corresponding probability of winning V in period t by e i , t and p i , t , respectively. In our baseline model, we assume the standard Tullock contest success function for both players: p i , t is the ratio of e i , t to the sum of e i , t and e - i , t . Specifically, the probability of winning V in period t for player i is

(1) p i , t = e i , t e i , t + e - i , t

if e i , t + e - i , t > 0 , and p i , t = 1 2 if e i , t + e - i , t = 0 . Player i's expected payoff in period t is

(2) π i , t = p i , t V - e i , t .

The first-order condition for player i in choosing e i , t to maximize π i , t given e - i , t is

(3) p i , t e i , t V = e i , t ( e i , t + e - i , t ) 2 V = 1 ,

and therefore, his best response in period t can be written as

(4) e i , t = e - i , t V - e - i , t .

It follows that there exists a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium supported by the above best response in every period. Specifically, there is a Nash equilibrium in the stage-game where each player chooses the expenditure level of V 4 and the expected payoff for each player is V 4 each period.Footnote 2

We now consider how the model changes when the winner of the previous contest (the Incumbent) has an advantage. Specifically, we assume the Incumbent can carry over a fraction of his expenditure from the previous period and combine it with his expenditure in the current period, while the other player (the Challenger) cannot. In this setting, p i , t is also affected by either e i , t - 1 or e - i , t - 1 depending on whether it is player i or - i who is the incumbent. Formally, a player is said to be in state I in period t if that player won the contest in period t - 1 and a player is in state C in period t if the player lost the contest in period t - 1 . Since the carryover amount is proportional to the Incumbent's previous expenditure, but the Incumbent could have been the Incumbent or the Challenger last period, we index each period of the model by how many consecutive periods the Incumbent has maintained his status denoted by τ . Thus, τ = 1 represents a period in which the current Incumbent was the Challenger in the previous period and τ 2 indicates a period in which the Incumbent was already the Incumbent in the previous period. We let τ = 0 denote the most recent period in which the current Incumbent was not the Incumbent. Let p I , τ and p C , τ denote the probabilities that the Incumbent and the Challenger win in period τ , respectively.

We let u I ( e C , 0 ) and u C ( e C , 0 ) be the total discounted expected utility of the Incumbent and the Challenger, given e C , 0 , from period τ = 1 onwards, and v I ( e I , τ - 1 ) and v C ( e I , τ - 1 ) be the total discounted expected utility of the Incumbent and the Challenger, given e I , τ - 1 , from period τ 2 onwards. Note that the Incumbent in period τ = 1 was the Challenger in period τ = 0 so a fraction of e C , 0 is carried over to period τ = 1 , while a fraction of e I , τ - 1 is carried over to period τ for τ 2 , because there is no role change in those periods. Let δ ( 0 , 1 ) be the proportion of expenditure that the contest winner in the previous period can carry over to the current period. The Bellman equation for each player, with a role change in period 1 and without a role change for τ 2 consecutive periods, is given by

(5) u I ( e C , 0 ) = max e I , 1 p I , 1 V - e I , 1 + β p I , 1 v I ( e I , 1 ) + p C , 1 u C ( e C , 1 )
(6) u C ( e C , 0 ) = max e C , 1 p C , 1 V - e C , 1 + β p C , 1 u I ( e C , 1 ) + p I , 1 v C ( e I , 1 )
(7) v I ( e I , τ - 1 ) = max e I , τ p I , τ V - e I , τ + β p I , τ v I ( e I , τ ) + p C , τ u C ( e C , τ )
(8) v C ( e I , τ - 1 ) = max e C , τ p C , τ V - e C , τ + β p C , τ u I ( e C , τ ) + p I , τ v C ( e I , τ ) ,

where

(9) p I , 1 = e I , 1 + δ e C , 0 e I , 1 + δ e C , 0 + e C , 1 , p C , 1 = e C , 1 e I , 1 + δ e C , 0 + e C , 1 .

and

(10) p I , τ = e I , τ + δ e I , τ - 1 e I , τ + δ e I , τ - 1 + e C , τ , p C , τ = e C , τ e I , τ + δ e I , τ - 1 + e C , τ ,

for τ 2 . The first-order conditions of the above Bellman equations for the Incumbent and the Challenger in period τ 1 are

(11) p I , τ e I , τ V + p I , τ e I , τ β [ v I ( e I , τ ) - u C ( e C , τ ) ] + β p I , τ v I ( e I , τ ) e I , τ = 1
(12) p C , τ e C , τ V + p C , τ e C , τ β [ u I ( e C , τ ) - v C ( e I , τ ) ] + β p C , τ u I ( e C , τ ) e C , τ = 1

with all of the derivative terms in (11) and (12) provided in Appendix A. While the marginal cost of expenditure appears on the right-hand side of each equality, there are three components of the marginal benefit on the left-hand side. The first term is the change in the expected prize amount due to the higher probability of winning in the current period. The second term is the expected return from being an Incumbent rather than the Challenger in the next period due to the higher probability of winning in the current period. The third term is the expected change in the value of winning the contest in the next period due to the carried over amount from the current period.

Without knowing the functional forms of u I , u C , v I , or v C in (11) and (12), it is not possible to predict the specific path that expenditures will take in this game from an arbitrary initial condition. However, we can derive the differences v I - u C and u I - v C in steady state where e I , τ = e ¯ I and e C , τ = e ¯ C . Specifically, as shown in Appendix A, we can write

(13) v I ( e ¯ I ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) = u I ( e ¯ C ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) = [ ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) ] [ 1 + β ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) ] 1 - β ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) .

As an example, if V = 1 , 000 and β = 3 5 , we find that on the steady-state path, e ¯ I = 174.2 and e ¯ C = 277.4 . Comparing this outcome to the situation where there is no carryover and each player's investment in the stage-game equilibrium is V 4 = 250 in every period, we find that the Incumbent invests less, because the carryover from the previous period reduces the marginal benefit of the investment in the current period, while the Challenger invests more because of the possibility that 3 5 of his investment in the current period will be carried over to the next period. If we consider the first period of a repeated contest with winner carryover (i.e., when τ = 0 ) when neither player is the Incumbent, it follows immediately that each player will invest more than 250.

3 Experimental design

To explore how winner carryover impacts behavior in an indefinitely repeated contest, we implement a 2 × 1 between-subject experimental design. For simplicity, both here and in the experiment, we use the term period when referring to the stage-game contest and the term round when referring to the indefinitely repeated super-game.

In the No Carryover baseline, a pair of subjects competed in a series of contests where the probability that contestant i would win the prize V = 1000 lab dollars in a period was e i , t e i , t + e - i , t . To help the participants understand the structure of the contest, it was described as a raffle where each contestant could buy tickets at the cost of 1 lab dollar per ticket, and then, one raffle ticket would be drawn at random to determine who received the prize that period. Given the parameter values, the numerical prediction for the No Carryover Baseline is the standard result of e i = V 4 = 250 and each player has an equal chance of winning the contest and has an expected payoff of V 4 = 250 each period.

In Winner Carryover the player who won the contest in the previous period had an advantage in the current period.Footnote 3 Specifically, the player who won the previous contest would have 3 5 of the tickets he purchased in the previous period automatically carried over and entered into the raffle in the current period.

A laboratory session consisted of eight participants in a single treatment. Upon entering the laboratory, subjects were seated at individual computer stations and followed along as a researcher read aloud an initial set of instructions common to all treatments describing a one-shot contest.Footnote 4 Participants then completed four unpaid one-shot practice contests against the computer. Participants were informed that they would play against the computer and that the computer was programmed to purchase a random number of tickets up to 1,000 in each practice contest.

After the practice contests, the subjects again followed along as a researcher read aloud treatment-specific instructions. Participants were informed that half of them had been randomly assigned to the “Crimson” group and the other half had been randomly assigned to the “Gray” group. Participants were informed of their own group assignment and of the fact that group assignments remained fixed throughout the study. Finally, participants were informed they would always be matched with a different person from the other color group each round in such a way that not only did no pair of contestants interact in multiple rounds, no participant's own action in one round could indirectly influence anyone the participant would meet in a subsequent round. This was achieved with a turnpike matching protocol (Cooper et al., Reference Cooper, Dejong, Forsythe and Ross1996).

Once the instructions had been read and any clarifying questions answered, participants proceeded to complete four rounds in the assigned condition. At the end of each period, participants received the following feedback: who won the prize that period, their own earnings for the period, the other contestant's earnings for the period, the number of tickets they purchased, the number of tickets the other contestant purchased, any tickets carried over from the previous period when applicable, and their probability of having won the prize that period. At the end of each of the first three rounds, participants were reminded of the process used to rematch contestants.

To implement the indefinite round horizon with β = 5 6 , the following procedure was used. Before the experiments were conducted, a six-sided die was rolled repeatedly until a six appeared. The number of periods in a round was equal to the number of rolls that had occurred when a six first appeared. This procedure was repeated separately for each round. To maintain consistency across sessions, the duration of rounds in all sessions was based on the same four sequences of die rolls. The actual number of periods in rounds 1 through 4 were 2, 4, 6, and 4, respectively. To allow for behavior to be observed for several periods for each pair, the participants were informed of the process that was used to determine the number of periods in a round, but not the realization. Further, participants were informed that they would complete 12 periods in a round after which it would be revealed if 1) the actual number of periods was 12 or less or 2) the actual number of periods exceeded 12. If the actual number of periods in the round was 12 or less, then after the 12 th period the participants were informed of the actual duration of the round and all payoffs were based on that duration. If the actual number of periods exceeded 12, then after the 12 th period, it would be revealed that the round would continue and that it would be revealed after each subsequent period if the round would end.

At the end of the study, one round was randomly selected and subjects were paid based on the randomly selected round (see Azrieli et al., Reference Azrieli, Chambers and Healy2020). Lab dollars were converted into $US at the rate of 100 lab dollars = $US 1 and this was common information. To account for the fact that half of the participants would lose money in the first period of a round and that some participants might lose money in several periods, each participant also received an endowment of 1,500 lab dollars. The average salient earnings, including the endowment, were $US 9.66. In addition, participants received a flat payment of $US 5 for completing the one-hour session.

The study was conducted at the University of Alabama's TIDE Lab. Data are reported from 80 participants who completed the study comprising five sessions per treatment.Footnote 5 The participants were drawn from the lab's standing pool of study volunteers who are overwhelmingly business school undergraduates. None of the participants had previously participated in any related studies.

4 Behavioral results

Our data consist of 80 indefinitely repeated contests (rounds) for each treatment and a total of 1920 individual contests (periods). We report the analysis in two subsections. The first examines aggregate behavior between treatments and the latter discusses the behavior of contestants by role and treatment. Throughout the results, claims of statistical significance use α = 0.05 .

4.1 Aggregate expenditure between treatments

Figure 1 plots the average combined expenditure of both players in a pair by period for each session. The figure suggests that total expenditure is greater in the Winner Carryover treatment than in the No Carryover baseline. Further, expenditures in both treatments appear to exceed their predicted levels from Sect. 2.Footnote 6

Fig. 1 Average total expenditure by a pair in each period. The figure shows average total expenditure by a pair per session each period. Horizontal lines indicate the theoretical predictions of 500 for No Carryover and 451.6 for Winner Carryover. Vertical lines indicate the start of a new round

To statistically test the difference between the two treatments, we estimate the following regression with standard errors clustered at the session level:

(14) T o t a l E x p e n d i = β 0 + β 1 W i n n e r C a r r y o v e r i + β 2 L a s t T w o R o u n d s i + β 3 W i n n e r C a r r y o v e r i × L a s t T w o R o u n d s i + ε i .

The dependent variable is the total expenditure in contest i excluding any carryover, referred to as T o t a l E x p e n d i . W i n n e r C a r r y o v e r i is a dummy variable that equals 1 if the observation is from the Winner Carryover treatment and 0 otherwise. To allow for the possibility that behavior changes as subjects gain experience, we include L a s t T w o R o u n d s i , which is a dummy variable that equals 1 if the observation is from the last two rounds and 0 otherwise. ε i is contest i's unobserved disturbance. Because the first period of each round differs from subsequent periods in that there can be no carryover, we estimate the above regression model using two separate data sets. The results of this regression are presented in Table 1. The estimation in column (1) includes only data from period 1 of each round, while the estimation in column (2) includes data from periods 2 to 12.

Table 1 Regression analysis of treatments and rounds

Variable (coefficient)

(1)

(2)

Constant ( β 0 )

664.0000***

693.6909***

(21.5677)

(32.9562)

WinnerCarryover ( β 1 )

251.2750***

263.7841**

(31.7314)

(97.0780)

LastTwoRounds ( β 2 )

- 36.6250

- 50.1182**

(34.8875)

(20.2573)

WinnerCarryover × LastTwoRounds ( β 3 )

312.9500***

130.4773

(68.3053)

(73.9738)

R 2

0.3188

0.1468

Number of Observations

160

1760

The dependent variable for each estimation is the total expenditure for each subject pair. Estimation (1) uses only the data from period 1 of each round, while Estimation (2) uses the data from periods 2 to 12. The base category of each regression is the first two rounds of the No Carryover treatment. Standard errors are in parentheses and are clustered at the session level. Significance levels: * p < 0.10 , ** p < 0.05 , *** p < 0.01

From column (1) of Table 1, it is clear that winner carryover leads to higher initial expenditures. The average total expenditure in period 1 is 664.00 in the first two rounds of the No Carryover baseline, which is statistically higher from the theoretical prediction of 500.00, and only nominally decreases by 36.63 in the last two rounds. By contrast, in the Winner Carryover treatment, average total expenditure in period 1 is 915.28 = 664.00 + 251.28 in the first two rounds, which is statistically greater than the average in the No Carryover baseline and statistically greater than the theoretical prediction of 451.60. In the last two rounds, the average total expenditure is 276.32 = - 36.63 + 312.95 , which is a statistically significant increase from the first two rounds and statistically greater than the average in the last two round of the baseline.

Now, we turn to the estimation in column (2) for which we use the data from periods 2 to 12. In the No Carryover baseline, the average total expenditure is 693.69 in the first two rounds, which is statistically higher than the theoretical prediction. For the Winner Carryover treatment, in the first two rounds, the average total expenditure is 957.47 = 693.69 + 263.78, which is statistically greater than the theoretical prediction and greater than the average in the baseline. For No Carryover, the average significantly decreases by 50.12 in the last two rounds, but remains significantly above the theoretical prediction. In the Winner Carryover treatment, the average total expenditure increases by 80.36 = - 50.12 + 130.48 to 1,037.83, which is statistically greater than the theoretical prediction and the average in the baseline.

4.2 Individual expenditure between roles and treatments

Fig. 2 Histogram of individual expenditure in no carryover. Bins include all expenditures greater than or equal to the the lower bound and less than the upper bound with the exception of the last bin that includes expenditures equal to 1000. The number of observations is 1760. The mean is 334.32 and the standard deviation is 233.26. Data from the first period of each round are omitted

Figure 2 shows the distribution of individual expenditures in the No Carryover baseline. For consistency with the subsequent analysis of the Winner Carryover treatment, this figure excludes data from the first period of each indefinitely repeated contest. There is overbidding with an overall average expenditure that is 133% of the stage-game prediction, but this is not as great as what is typically observed in one-shot Tullock contests (see Dechenaux et al., Reference Dechenaux, Kovenock and Sheremeta2015).Footnote 7 In this regard, our findings are consistent with Brookins et al. (Reference Brookins, Ryvkin and Smyth2021), who also found the repeated play reduced expenditure relative to one-shot behavior. However, Brookins et al. (Reference Brookins, Ryvkin and Smyth2021) found that repeated play with either a finite horizon or an indefinite horizon with the same expected duration both yield behavior close to the stage-game prediction, whereas we still observe sizeable overbidding.

Next, we consider individual expenditure in the Winner Carryover treatment where we exclude data from the first period of each round as there is no Incumbent and there can be no carryover. Figure 3 plots the distribution of expenditures separately for Incumbents and Challengers. The distribution of expenditures by Incumbents in panel (a) appears to be a rightward shift from the distribution in the baseline (Fig. 2). It also appears that expenditures by Challengers as shown in panel (b) are more dispersed than those by Incumbents from the same treatment and those in the baseline. It is worth noting that these results contrast with Schmitt et al. (Reference Schmitt, Shupp, Swope and Cadigan2004) who also investigate the effect of carryover. However, in their experiment, there was no advantage to being the Incumbent as both players could carry over expenditures from one period to the next and this likely explains the behavioral difference.

Fig. 3 Histograms of expenditure by Incumbents and challengers in winner carryover. Bins include all expenditures greater than or equal to the the lower bound and less than the upper bound with the exception of the last bin that includes expenditures equal to 1000. The number of observations for each histogram is 880. In panel a, the mean is 498.21 and the standard deviation is 267.23. In panel b, the mean is 499.45 and the standard deviation is 321.73. Data from the first period of each round are omitted

We now consider how behavior in the winner carryover treatment depends not only on role, but on the amount of carryover as well. In the top row of Fig. 4, we present box plots of expenditures by role conditional on the amount the Incumbent spent in the previous period on the x-axis. Thus, carryover in each period is δ = 3 5 of this amount. It seems that both Incumbents and Challengers spend more when the carryover is larger. However, it is not clear if the participants are reacting to the carryover per se or simply reacting to the behavior in the previous period. To address this, in the bottom row of Fig. 4, we plot the data from the No Carryover treatment as if it had been from the Winner Carryover treatment to use as reference point for our analysis. That is, we evaluate expenditures by the winner in the previous period and the loser in the previous period conditional on the Incumbent's expenditure in the previous period. From the figure, we find that both Incumbents and Challengers in the baseline spend more when the Incumbent spent more in the previous period, just as in the Winner Carryover treatment. However, the Challengers in the Winner Carryover treatment appear to be somewhat more responsive to the Incumbent's previous expenditure than are Challengers in the baseline.

Fig. 4 Box plots of expenditure in the current period contingent on previous winner's expenditure in the previous period. Bins on the x-axis include all expenditures by the previous winner in the previous period of greater than or equal to the the lower bound and less than the upper bound with the exception of the last bin that includes expenditures equal to 1000. The top portion of the figure shows expenditure of the Incumbents and the challengers in winner carryover. The lower portion of the figure shows expenditure of the previous winners and the previous losers in No Carryover. The number of observations in each plot is 880. Data from the first period of each round are omitted

To statistically evaluate the effects of player i's role and the carryover amount on their expenditure in period t, E x p e n d it , we employ the following dynamic panel data model:

(15) E x p e n d it = β 0 + β 1 E x p e n d i t - 1 + β 2 E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 + β 3 I n c u m b e n t it + β 4 I n c u m b e n t it × E x p e n d i t - 1 + β 5 I n c u m b e n t it × E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 + u i + ε it ,

where E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 is expenditure of player i's opponent in period t - 1 , I n c u m b e n t it is a dummy variable equal to 1 if player i is the Incumbent in period t and 0 otherwise, u i is player i's individual effect, and ε it is an individual and period specific disturbance which captures residual variations in expenditure for player i in period t.

By construction of the dynamic panel data model in (15), an endogeneity issue arises, because E x p e n d i t - 1 is correlated with the unobserved individual effect u i . Differencing the above model can eliminate u i , but there will be another endogeneity issue, because we have Δ E x p e n d i t - 1 and Δ ε it on the right-hand side of the differenced model and both are also correlated, because E x p e n d i t - 1 is in Δ E x p e n d i t - 1 and ε i t - 1 is in Δ ε it . To address this issue, we follow Gill and Prowse (Reference Gill and Prowse2014) in constructing GMM estimators based on moment equations derived from further lagged levels of the dependent variable and the first-differenced errors (Holtz-Eakin et al., Reference Holtz-Eakin, Newey and Rosen1988; Arellano & Bond, Reference Arellano and Bond1991). Specifically, we use up to six lags of E x p e n d it as instruments for the differenced equation in the two-step Arellano–Bond estimation to obtain consistent and asymptotically efficient estimators even in the presence of heteroskedasticity.

We conduct the analysis on four separate data sets: (1) data from all rounds of Winner Carryover; (2) data from the last two rounds of Winner Carryover; (3) data from all rounds of No Carryover; and (4) data from the last two rounds of No Carryover. While the first specification is the primary focus of the analysis, the second specification allows for learning in the Winner Carryover treatment, while the third and fourth specifications provide a reference point for the impact of Winner Carryover relative to No Carryover. For each specification, we report the estimated coefficients along with standard errors from the two-step estimates with Windmeijer finite-sample correction (Windmeijer, Reference Windmeijer2005) in the top section of Table 2. Even though E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 and I n c u m b e n t it are not endogenous, because they are not correlated with ε it (or even ε i t - 1 ), they are weakly exogenous, because they might be correlated with ε i t - 2 . Thus, we treat both variables as predetermined in our estimation and include up to three lags of the variables, i.e., how much their opponent invested and the win/loss outcomes in the previous three periods, as instruments for the differenced equation. We also include interaction terms between E x p e n d i t - 1 and I n c u m b e n t it , and between E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 and I n c u m b e n t it as instruments. Finally, we use the generated random number which is used in the experiment to determine the winner of each contest period as an exogenous instrument.Footnote 8

Table 2 Dynamic panel regression analysis of individual expenditure

Variable (coefficient)

Winner Carryover

No Carryover

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Constant ( β 0 )

500.19***

601.25***

244.11***

222.58***

(60.92)

(79.70)

(42.65)

(57.59)

E x p e n d i t - 1 ( β 1 )

0.2493***

0.2205**

0.3024***

0.3229***

(0.0797)

(0.0901)

(0.0849)

(0.1173)

E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 ( β 2 )

- 0.1693**

- 0.2674***

0.0037

0.0304

(0.0708)

(0.0869)

(0.0871)

(0.1043)

I n c u m b e n t it ( β 3 )

210.88***

275.19**

181.92***

205.06***

(67.65)

(119.67)

(44.45)

(56.07)

I n c u m b e n t it × E x p e n d i t - 1 ( β 4 )

- 0.7536***

- 0.8191***

- 0.6541***

- 0.6621***

(0.0811)

(0.1351)

(0.1131)

(0.1353)

I n c u m b e n t it × E x p e n d O p p o n e n t i t - 1 ( β 5 )

0.2093***

0.2340**

0.0270

- 0.0094

(0.0757)

(0.1015)

(0.0868)

(0.1038)

Linear combinations of coefficients

       β 1 + β 4

- 0.5043***

- 0.5686***

- 0.3517***

- 0.3392***

       β 2 + β 5

0.0400

- 0.0334

0.0307

0.0210

       β 3 + β 4 Expend ¯ + β 5 Expend ¯

- 60.91**

- 28.96

- 27.68*

- 10.12

Number of

      total observations

1600

800

1600

800

      groups

160

80

160

80

      observations per group

10

10

10

10

      instruments

83

83

83

83

p-value of

      Sargan Test

0.4732

0.4303

0.1716

0.4890

      Arellano-Bond Test

0.2236

0.1971

0.2009

0.1608

The dependent variable for each specification is E x p e n d it . The results are based on Arellano–Bond two-step estimation. Data from the first period of each round are omitted. Estimations (2) and (4) use only the data from rounds 3 and 4. Standard errors are in parentheses and are based on the Windmeijer finite-sample correction. Significance levels: * p < 0.10 , ** p < 0.05 , *** p < 0.01 . Expend ¯ is an average expenditure per period from period 2 to period 11 based on the sample used for each estimation, i.e., 499.34, 519.82, 334.23, and 320.44 for (1), (2), (3), and (4), respectively

To address the validity of the specifications, we also report the results from two related tests in the bottom section of the table. First, we use the Sargan test to check the validity of the instruments used in the model ( H 0 : overidentifying restrictions are valid). Second, we use the robust version of the Arellano–Bond test to determine if the first-differenced error terms are second-order serially correlated ( H 0 : zero autocorrelation). Based on the p values reported in the bottom section of Table 2, we do not reject any of the null hypotheses for any specification indicating that the reported analysis is valid.

From column (1) of Table 2, which uses data from all four rounds of the Winner Carryover treatment, we find the marginal effect of a participant's previous expenditure on his current expenditure is 0.2493 for Challenger and - 0.5043 = 0.2493 - 0.7536 for Incumbent and both effects are statistically significant. The estimated difference between the two coefficients is 0.7536, which is also statistically significant. Moreover, we find that the marginal effect of the previous expenditure by a participant's opponent on the participant's current expenditure is - 0.1693 for the Challenger and 0.0400 = - 0.1693 + 0.2093 for the Incumbent. While the marginal effect on the Challenger is statistically significant, the marginal effect on the Incumbent is not. The negative effect on the Challenger can be explained by the discouragement effect on a player in a contest when the other player has a head-start advantage (see Dechenaux et al., Reference Dechenaux, Kovenock and Sheremeta2015). Finally, given an average expenditure from period 2 to period 11 of 499.34, we find that after controlling for the behavior in the previous period under the assumption that both expenditures are equal to each other, and at the average level, Incumbent's expenditure is 60.91 lower than Challenger's expenditure and this difference is statistically significant. If attention is restricted to the last two rounds, the results are largely unchanged as shown in column (2) of the table, although the discouragement effect becomes more pronounced.

For the No Carryover baseline, we create a pseudo-role variable, I n c u m b e n t it , to denote if player i in period t won in period t - 1 . As shown in column (3) of Table 2, the marginal effect of a participant's previous expenditure on his current expenditure is 0.3024 for Challenger and - 0.3517 = 0.3024 - 0.6541 for Incumbent. Both effects are statistically significant. The estimated difference of 0.6541 is also significant despite the lack of actual carryover in the baseline. These values are similar to the ones found in the Carryover treatment suggesting that it is not the carry over per se that is driving the difference in how players respond to their own prior expenditure. However, in contrast to the Winner Carryover treatment, in the No Carryover baseline, the opponent's previous expenditure does not have a significant impact on the Challenger's expenditure. Thus, there is no evidence of the discouragement effect in the baseline. Moreover, given an average expenditure of 334.23, we find that after controlling for the behavior in the previous period, Incumbent's expenditure is on average only 27.68 lower than Challenger's expenditure and this difference is less pronounced that what we observe in the Winner Carryover treatment. Finally, the results in column (4) are similar to those in column (3) indicating that behavior does not change with experience.

In summation, we find that Carryover leads to greater expenditures. Incumbents and Challengers respond differently to the behavior of the previous contest. Incumbents’ expenditures decreasing with their own previous expenditure similarly in both treatments. In contrast, Challengers’ expenditures increase in their own previous expenditure in both treatments. We do not find any effect of the previous expenditure by the opponent on the current expenditure of the Incumbent or the Challenger in the No Carryover baseline. However, in the Winner Carryover treatment, we find a positive effect of the opponent's expenditure on the Incumbent and a negative effect on the Challenger. This suggest that an aggressive action by the Challenger will lead to retaliation by the Incumbent, but a similar action by the Incumbent will discourage the Challenger.

5 Conclusion

Because many naturally occurring situations, like political campaigns, can be modeled as contests, an extensive theoretical and behavioral literature has developed on this topic. Scholars have recently begun considering the effects of repeated interactions in contests as part of the growing interest in repeated play games more generally. This paper contributes to that literature as we consider indefinitely repeated play Tullock contests with dynamic linkages between stage games. Specifically, we consider the effects of the winner in one period being able to carry forward a portion of their expenditure to the next period as such an incumbency advantage is likely to accrue in settings like political campaigns.

In a series of controlled laboratory experiments, we find that winner carryover substantially increases total expenditure in comparison to the indefinitely repeated game with no carryover. Further, in both cases, the observed level of expenditure far exceeds the theoretical predictions. Such a pattern is consistent with popular press accounts of large spending by political campaigns. We find that Incumbents and Challengers respond differently to the behavior of the previous contest when deciding how much to expend in the current contest. Incumbents’ expenditures are decreasing with their own previous expenditure similarly in both treatments. This suggests that even though players with an incumbency advantage reduce their expenditure, this is not due to the carryover per se, but rather a behavioral reaction to having won the previous contest. By contrast, Challengers’ expenditures increase in their own previous expenditure in both treatments. In the No Carryover baseline, we do not find any effect of the previous expenditure by the opponent on the current expenditure of the Incumbent or the Challenger. However, in the Winner Carryover treatment, we find a positive effect of the opponent's expenditure on the Incumbent and a negative effect of the opponent's expenditure on the Challenger. This suggest that an aggressive action by the Challenger will lead to retaliation by the Incumbent, but a similar action by the Incumbent will discourage the Challenger.

While our experiment is meant to mimic naturally occurring settings like political campaigns, there are a myraid of differences between the two. For example, in practice, the Challenger may receive some carryover benefit, even if it smaller than the benefit to the Incumbent. In such a setting, the effect of carry over may be smaller than what we observe. Further, the benefit to the incumbent may depend on the duration of the incumbency, while we modeled the benefit extending to only one future contest. We hope that our study spurs further research on these issues and on indefinitely repeated games with intercontest linkages more generally.

Acknowledgements

This study was funded by The University of Alabama. The authors thank Natalie Millar for her contributions to the early stages of this project and to the Editor for helpful suggestions regarding the data analysis reported in the current version of the paper.

Data availability

The replication material for the study is available at https://osf.io/nhyq2/.

Declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.

Appendix A: Theoretical derivations

1. Baseline with no carryover

In this subsection, we consider the possibility of collusion in the baseline setting. While there is a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium in which both players play the stage-game equilibrium, there is also a class of subgame perfect Nash equilibria supported by grim trigger strategies. In such equilibria, both players collude by choosing an expenditure that is lower than V 4 until one of the players defects. After the defection period, both players play the Nash equilibrium strategy of the stage-game in every period. Suppose that the colluded level of expenditure is c and the defector chooses an expenditure of c + ϵ where ϵ > 0 . Let π C and π D be a player's expected payoff in a period that he colludes and defects, respectively. Such collusion can be sustained if

(16) 1 1 - β π C π D + β 1 - β V 4 ,

which can be written as

(17) 1 1 - β V 2 - c c + ϵ 2 c + ϵ V - c - ϵ + β 1 - β V 4 .

Let β ¯ be the minimum discount factor to sustain collusion. Then, in the socially optimal collusion, c = 0 and (17) implies

(18) β ¯ = 1 2 V - ϵ 3 4 V - ϵ .

Since c = 0 , the optimal expenditure in the defection period, ϵ , is the least non-zero expenditure allowed in the contest.Footnote 9 Since β ¯ is decreasing in ϵ , we find that if β is not lower than 2 3 , then collusion with c = 0 can be sustained for any minimum value of expenditure allowed in the contest. On the other hand, if c > 0 , we derive the defector's optimal expenditure, which maximizes π D in the defection period. We find that the optimal value of ϵ is

(19) ϵ = cV - 2 c .

Since c < V 4 , ϵ is positive. It follows that the maximum value of π D is:

(20) π D = ( V - c ) 2 .

Given (16), collusion with c > 0 can be sustained if

(21) 1 1 - β V 2 - c ( V - c ) 2 + β 1 - β V 4 ,

which implies that

(22) β ¯ = 1 2 V - 2 Vc + 2 c 3 4 V - 2 Vc + c = 2 ( V - 2 c ) 3 V - 2 c .

We find that β ¯ is strictly decreasing in c, lim c 0 β ¯ = 2 3 , and lim c V 4 β ¯ = 0 . Therefore, given any β ( 0 , 1 ) , there exists a level of c ( 0 , V 4 ) , such that collusion can be sustained. To achieve the socially optimal collusion, i.e., c = 0 , it is necessary that β 2 3 . If β < 2 3 , then collusion can still be supported in equilibrium, but the expenditure level will be strictly greater than zero. Given (22), we can derive the minimum expenditure that can be supported given β as

(23) c ¯ = ( 2 - 3 β ) 2 4 ( 2 - β ) 2 V if β < 2 3 0 if β 2 3 .

For example, if V = 1000 and β = 3 5 , then the colluded amount of investment for each player in equilibrium is between 5.1 and 250.

2. Winner carryover

In this subsection, we provide the derivatives required in Eqs. (11) and (12) from the main text of the paper and then derive Eq. (13).

The derivatives are

(24) p I , 1 e I , 1 = e C , 1 ( e I , 1 + δ e C , τ + e C , 1 ) 2 , p C , 1 e C , 1 = e I , 1 + δ e C , τ ( e I , 1 + δ e C , τ + e C , 1 ) 2 ,
(25) p I , τ e I , τ = e C , τ ( e I , τ + δ e I , τ - 1 + e C , τ ) 2 , p C , τ e C , τ = e I , τ + δ e I , τ - 1 ( e I , τ + δ e I , τ - 1 + e C , τ ) 2 ,

for τ 2 , and

(26) u I ( e C , τ ) e C , τ = p I , 1 e C , τ V + β [ v I ( e I , 1 ) - u C ( e C , 1 ) ] = δ e C , 1 ( e I , 1 + δ e C , τ + e C , 1 ) 2 V + β [ v I ( e I , 1 ) - u C ( e C , 1 ) ] ,
(27) v I ( e I , τ ) e I , τ = p I , τ + 1 e I , τ V + β [ v I ( e I , τ + 1 ) - u C ( e C , τ + 1 ) ] = δ e C , τ + 1 ( e I , τ + 1 + δ e I , τ + e C , τ + 1 ) 2 V + β [ v I ( e I , τ + 1 ) - u C ( e C , τ + 1 ) ] ,

for τ 1 . In steady state e i , t = e ¯ i , so that p i , t = p ¯ i and, given the Bellman equations in (5), (6), (7), and (8), we find that

(28) v I ( e ¯ I ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) = ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) + β p ¯ I [ v I ( e ¯ I ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) ] - p ¯ C [ u I ( e ¯ C ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) ] ,
(29) u I ( e ¯ C ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) = ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) + β p ¯ I [ v I ( e ¯ I ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) ] - p ¯ C [ u I ( e ¯ C ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) ] ,

where

(30) v I ( e ¯ I ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) = ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) + β p ¯ I [ v I ( e ¯ I ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) ] - p ¯ C [ u I ( e ¯ C ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) ] ,
(31) u I ( e ¯ C ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) = ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) + β p ¯ I [ v I ( e ¯ I ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) ] - p ¯ C [ u I ( e ¯ C ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) ] .

Therefore

(32) v I ( e ¯ I ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) = u I ( e ¯ C ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) = ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) 1 - β ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) .

and

(33) v I ( e ¯ I ) - u C ( e ¯ C ) = u I ( e ¯ C ) - v C ( e ¯ I ) = [ ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) V - ( e ¯ I - e ¯ C ) ] [ 1 + β ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) ] 1 - β ( p ¯ I - p ¯ C ) .

Appendix B: Instructions for the experiment

All subjects observed the instructions for Part 1 and then participated in four unpaid practice periods involving standard one-shot Tullock contests played against the computer. Next, subjects read treatment-specific instructions for Part 2 of the study. Note, terms in [ ] next to section headings were not shown to the subjects. They are provided to distinguish in which treatment the instructions were shown.

Part 1

This is a study on economic decision making. You will be paid at the end of the study based on the decisions you and others make in this study, so it is important that you understand these instructions fully. If you have a question at any point, please raise your hand. Also, please make sure that you have turned off and put away all personal electronic devices at this time.

In this study, you will participate in several series of raffles. This set of instructions will first explain how a basic raffle works. Then, you will have the opportunity to go through four practice raffles. The practice raffles will not impact your payment in any way; rather, the practice raffles are meant to help you understand how a basic raffle works. After you complete the practice raffles, you will then read instructions describing the slightly more complicated raffles in which you will participate during the main part of the study.

There are eight people in your group equally split into two sub-groups: Crimson and Gray. Color assignment is random and everyone retains the same color throughout the study.

Your color is (Crimson/Gray).

How Raffles work

The basic raffle works as follows. First, you and a contestant from the other color group each privately decide how many tickets you want to buy. Each ticket you buy costs you 1 lab dollar. You can buy any whole number of tickets from 0 to 1000 in a raffle. Each ticket the other contestant buys costs that person 1 lab dollar. One (and only one) raffle ticket is drawn at random by the computer. If the ticket that is drawn belongs to you, then you receive a prize of 1000 lab dollars and the other contestant receives 0 lab dollars. If the ticket that is drawn does not belong to you, then you receive 0 lab dollars and the other contestant receives 1000 lab dollars.

For simplicity, let us call the number of tickets the Crimson contestant buys CrimsonT and call the number of tickets the Gray contestant buys GrayT. Therefore

  • If your ticket is drawn you earn 1000 - # Tickets.

  • If your ticket is not drawn you earn 0 - # Tickets.

  • The probability Crimson receives the prize = CrimsonT / (CrimsonT + GrayT).

  • The probability Gray receives the prize = GrayT / (CrimsonT + GrayT).

If neither you nor the other contestant buys any tickets, there is a 50% chance that you will receive the prize and a 50% chance the other contestant will receive the prize.

You will now go through four unpaid practice raffles. During the practice raffles, the computer will serve as the other participant. The computer is programmed to buy a random number of tickets.

Part 2

Rounds of Raffles

In the main portion of the study, you will complete four sequences of raffles. A sequence of raffles is referred to as a round. A round consists of several periods, and during each period, you will participate in a raffle like the practice raffles you just completed, but now the other contestant will be another person in this study.

After all contestants have recorded their decisions about how many raffle tickets to buy in a period, the computer will randomly draw one raffle ticket. You will then see 1) if you received the prize or not and 2) how many tickets the other contestant purchased and 3) how many tickets you purchased that period.

How much you earn in a round is simply the sum of how much you earned each period in the round. That is, every period, there is a prize of 1000 lab dollars and every period you pay 1 lab dollar for every raffle ticket you buy. If you buy raffle tickets but are not awarded a prize for the period, your profit for that period will be negative.

Number of periods in a round

The number of periods in a round was predetermined by the researcher using a random process before the study began. To determine if the round will continue for another period, a regular 6-sided die was rolled. If a 6 was rolled, the round would end. Otherwise, the round keeps going. Therefore, from your perspective at any point, there is a 5/6 chance that the round continues for at least one more period. There is a 5/6 x 5/6 chance it continues for at least two more periods, and so on.

Although the number of periods in a round was determined in advance by a random process, the number of periods in a round will not be revealed to you until after the round has ended. Instead, you will make decisions for at least 12 periods in each round. If a six was rolled after one of the first 12 periods, then you will only complete 12 periods and we will only calculate your earnings for the round up until the point that the first 6 was rolled. That is, the round official ended once a six was rolled. However, if it turns out that no six was rolled in the first 12 die rolls, then the round will continue until a six is rolled. This means that the round could last 13, 14, 15 periods (or more) and you would have to make as many decisions as there are periods in the round. Because of this process, it is always in your best interest to behave as if the current period counts toward your payoff and that there is a 5/6 chance that there will be another period that also counts toward your payoff.

Let us look at an example. Suppose the die rolls for each period were as shown in the table below. You would go through 12 periods in the round, and then, it would be revealed that the round actually ended after period 5. Your payoff for the round would only be the sum of what you earned in periods 1 through 5, since the first 6 was rolled after period 5.

Period

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

Roll

3

4

1

4

6

4

5

2

6

1

4

2

Now suppose that instead the die rolls were as shown in the following table:

Period

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

Roll

2

3

5

4

1

1

3

1

2

5

2

2

5

You would complete period 12 and it would be revealed that no 6 had been rolled. Therefore, the round would continue to period 13. Since a 5 was rolled after period 13, the round would continue to period 14. This would continue until a 6 was rolled

The other contestant

As we indicated before, the eight people in your group were randomly split into two sub-groups: Crimson and Gray. Your color is (Crimson/Gray).

Each round you will be matched with a different person from the other color. This matching is done in a particular way, so that you will never interact with the same person for more than one round. Further, once you interact with someone that person will never interact with anyone that is going to interact with someone who will then interact with you. This means that nothing you do in one round can ever influence how someone else might interact with you in a future round.

Carryover [only visible for the winner carryover treatment]

Each period, the contestant who received the prize gets to carry over 3/5 (or 60%) of their raffle tickets to the next period at no additional cost. As an example, if the Crimson contestant buys 200 tickets in period 4 and receives the prize that period, then Crimson will get to carry over (3/5) x 200 = 120 tickets into period 5. Or if Gray buys 80 tickets in period 7 and receives the prize in period 7, Gray will carry over (3/5) x 82 = 49.2, which rounds to 49 tickets, into period 8. The contestant that does not receive the prize does not carry over any tickets.

Tickets that are carried over to a period are added to the raffle tickets purchased that period before the raffle is conducted. Notice that the carryover is only on tickets the contestant that received the prize bought in the previous period. The number of tickets carried over to one period has no impact on the number of tickets carried over to a subsequent period. Further, tickets are not carried over from one round to the next.

The person who did not receive the prize does not get to carry over any tickets.

For simplicity, let us call the number of tickets the Crimson contestant carries over to the next period after Crimson receives the prize CrimsonCO. And let us call the number of tickets the Gray contestant carries over to the next period after Gray receives the prize GrayCO.

If Crimson received the prize in the previous period, then

  • The probability Crimson receives the prize = (CrimsonT + CrimsonCO) / ( CrimsonT + CrimsonCO + GrayT).

  • The probability Gray receives the prize = GrayT / (CrimsonT + CrimsonCO + GrayT).

If Gray received the prize in the previous period, then

  • The probability Crimson receives the prize = CrimsonT / (CrimsonT + GrayT + GrayCO).

  • The probability Gray receives the prize = (GrayT + GrayCO) / ( CrimsonT + GrayT + GrayCO).

Your payment

After the study is complete, one round will be randomly selected and used to calculate your payment. Your earnings from the randomly selected round will be converted to US dollars at the rate 100 lab dollars = 1 US dollar.

You will also receive a 1500 lab dollar endowment. If your earnings are positive in the randomly selected round, these will be added to your endowment. However, if you have losses in the randomly selected round, these will be deducted from your endowment. You should note that this endowment is in addition to the 5 dollar participation payment you are receiving for this study.

If no one has any questions, then we will begin.

Footnotes

1 Indefinitely repeated contests are themselves a special case of the more general topic of indefinitely repeated play games (see Dal Bo & Frechette, Reference Dal Bo and Frechette2018, for a survey.).

2 This is not the only equilibrium in the infinitely repeated contest. There is also a class of subgame perfect Nash equilibria supported by grim trigger strategies. See Appendix A.

3 In the first period of the round, neither player had an advantage.

4 All instructions are provided in Appendix B. The computerized study was conducted using z-Tree (Fischbacher, Reference Fischbacher2007).

5 In a session of the Winner Carryover treatment, a participant selected 0 every period. After the study, the participant indicated he was unwilling to risk leaving with anything less than the endowment. Contestants matched with this individual quickly learned they could spend a trivial amount and win with certainty. For this reason, an additional session was completed. While the qualitative results presented in the next section remain unchanged if the data from the session in which the person spent 0 every period are included, we omit it from our analysis as the subject's local satiation means subject incentives did not align with the model being tested resulting in a loss of experimental control.

6 As discussed in Appendix A, collusion can be supported in this setting. However, the evidence suggests that subjects are not colluding, because expenditures are not below the level identified in Sect. 2.

7 Even in the final round, the average stage-game bid is 128% of the predicted level.

8 This approach was introduced by Ham et al. (Reference Ham, Kagel and Lehrer2005) and adopted by Gill and Prowse (Reference Gill and Prowse2014). For each contest round in our experiment, the computer generated a random number between zero and one to determine whether the contest winner is the crimson player or the gray player. The crimson player wins the contest if the generated number is lower than his probability of winning calculated from each player's expenditure and the expenditure carried over from the previous period. To construct an instrumental variable that is positively correlated with the winning outcome of each player and uncorrelated with each player's expenditure, we let the value of this instrumental variable for the gray player be the generated number and the value for the crimson player be one minus the generated number. Descamps et al. (Reference Descamps, Ke and Page2022) use an alternative instrumental variable approach in a contest experiment, but that approach relies on contestant matching generating players with more equal probabilities of winning.

9 Brookins et al. (Reference Brookins, Ryvkin and Smyth2021) derive β ¯ for the case c = 0 and the least non-zero expenditure allowed is 1.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

References

Arellano, M, Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: MonteCarlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 2, 277297. 10.2307/2297968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azrieli, Y, Chambers, C, Healy, P. (2020). Incentives in experiments with objective lotteries. Experimental Economics, 23, 1, 129. 10.1007/s10683-019-09607-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baik, KH, Lee, S. (2000). Two-stage rent-seeking contests with carryovers. Public Choice, 103, 3–4, 285296. 10.1023/A:1005003713923.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brookins, P, Ryvkin, D, Smyth, A. (2021). Indefinitely Repeated Contests: An Experimental Study. Experimental Economics, 24, 13901419. 10.1007/s10683-021-09703-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R, Dejong, D, Forsythe, R, Ross, T. (1996). Cooperation without Reputation: Experimental Evidence from Prisoner's Dilemma Games. Games and Economic Behavior, 12, 2, 187218. 10.1006/game.1996.0013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bo, P, Frechette, GR. (2018). On the Determinants of Cooperation in Infinitely Repeated Games: A Survey. Economic Literature, 56, 1, 60114. 10.1257/jel.20160980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechenaux, E, Kovenock, D, Sheremeta, RM. (2015). A survey of experimental research on contests, all-pay auctions and tournaments. Experimental Economics, 18, 4, 609669. 10.1007/s10683-014-9421-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Descamps, A, Ke, C, Page, L. (2022). How success breeds success. Quantitative Economics, 5, 1, 355385. 10.3982/QE1679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 2, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gill, D, Prowse, V. (2014). Gender differences and dynamics in competition: The role of luck. Quantitative Economics, 5, 2, 351376. 10.3982/QE309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossmann, M, Dietl, H, Lang, M. (2010). Revenue sharing and competitive balance in a dynamic contest model. Review of Industrial Organization, 36, 1, 1736. 10.1007/s11151-009-9236-x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hafer, C. (2006). On the origins of property rights: Conflict and production in the state of nature. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 119143. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.00371.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häfner, Samuel, Nöldeke, Georg. (2019). Sorting in iterated incumbency contests. Economic Theory, 10.1007/s00199-019-01205-8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ham, JC, Kagel, JH, Lehrer, SF. (2005). Randomization, endogeneity and laboratory experiments: The role of cash balances in private value auctions. Journal of Econometrics, 125, 1–2, 175205. 10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.04.008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holtz-Eakin, D, Newey, W, Rosen, HS. (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica, 56, 6, 13711395. 10.2307/1913103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konrad, KA. (2009). Strategy and Dynamics in Contests, Oxford University Press. 10.1093/oso/9780199549597.001.0001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polborn, M. (2006). Investment under uncertainty in dynamic conflicts. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 505529. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.0385.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitt, P, Shupp, R, Swope, K, Cadigan, J. (2004). Multi-period rent-seeking contests with carryover: Theory and experimental evidence. Economics of Governance, 5, 3, 187211. 10.1007/s10101-004-0075-9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Virág, G. (2009). Efficiency and competition in the long run: The survival of the unfit. Games and Economic Behavior, 67, 1, 315330. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.10.008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126, 1, 2551. 10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Fig. 1 Average total expenditure by a pair in each period. The figure shows average total expenditure by a pair per session each period. Horizontal lines indicate the theoretical predictions of 500 for No Carryover and 451.6 for Winner Carryover. Vertical lines indicate the start of a new round

Figure 1

Table 1 Regression analysis of treatments and rounds

Figure 2

Fig. 2 Histogram of individual expenditure in no carryover. Bins include all expenditures greater than or equal to the the lower bound and less than the upper bound with the exception of the last bin that includes expenditures equal to 1000. The number of observations is 1760. The mean is 334.32 and the standard deviation is 233.26. Data from the first period of each round are omitted

Figure 3

Fig. 3 Histograms of expenditure by Incumbents and challengers in winner carryover. Bins include all expenditures greater than or equal to the the lower bound and less than the upper bound with the exception of the last bin that includes expenditures equal to 1000. The number of observations for each histogram is 880. In panel a, the mean is 498.21 and the standard deviation is 267.23. In panel b, the mean is 499.45 and the standard deviation is 321.73. Data from the first period of each round are omitted

Figure 4

Fig. 4 Box plots of expenditure in the current period contingent on previous winner's expenditure in the previous period. Bins on the x-axis include all expenditures by the previous winner in the previous period of greater than or equal to the the lower bound and less than the upper bound with the exception of the last bin that includes expenditures equal to 1000. The top portion of the figure shows expenditure of the Incumbents and the challengers in winner carryover. The lower portion of the figure shows expenditure of the previous winners and the previous losers in No Carryover. The number of observations in each plot is 880. Data from the first period of each round are omitted

Figure 5

Table 2 Dynamic panel regression analysis of individual expenditure