Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T16:31:02.537Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Enough! Electoral Fraud, Collective Action Problems, and Post-Communist Colored Revolutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 August 2007

Joshua A. Tucker
Affiliation:
New York University, E-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In countries where citizens have strong grievances against the regime, attempts to address these grievances in the course of daily life are likely to entail high costs coupled with very low chances of success in any meaningful sense; consequently, most citizens will choose not to challenge the regime, thus reflecting the now well-known collective action problem. When a regime commits electoral fraud, however, an individual's calculus regarding whether to participate in a protest against the regime can be changed significantly. This argument yields important implications for how we interpret the wave of “colored revolutions” that swept through Serbia, Georgia, Ukraine, and Kyrgyzstan in the first half of this decade. Applying the collective action framework to the colored revolutions also yields a parsimonious contribution to the political science literature on social protest: electoral fraud can be a remarkably useful tool for solving the collective action problems faced by citizens in countries where governments are not, to use Barry Weingast's language, appropriately restrained by the populace. While modest, such an observation actually can speak to a wide-ranging number of questions in the literature, including why people choose to protest when they do, how protests at one place and time can affect the likelihood for future protests, and new aspects of the relationship between elections and protest.Joshua A. Tucker is Associate Professor of Politics at New York University ([email protected]). He would like to thank participants in the First and Second Danyliw Research Seminars in Contemporary Ukrainian Studies hosted by the Chair of Ukrainian Studies at the University of Ottawa and the Kennan Institute Workshop on Ukrainian Civil Society for many helpful comments and suggestions on developing the arguments contained in this article. He would also like to thank Dominique Arel, Jessica Allina-Pisano, Mark Beissinger, Valerie Bunce, Paul D'Anieri, Jerry Hough, Jason Lyall, Grigore Pop-Eleches, Lucan Way, and William Zimmerman for their time in commenting on earlier drafts of the paper, as well as the anonymous reviewers at Perspective on Politics. Marc Berenson and Matthew Berner provided excellent research assistance.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© 2007 American Political Science Association

“Razom Nas Bahato! Nas ne podolaty!”

(‘Together we are many! We can not be defeated!”)

—Chant in Kiev's Independence Square during the Orange Revolution.1

Karatnycky 2005, 35. This was taken from the rap song Razom Nas Bahato by the Ukrainian rock group GreenJolly, available for download at http://www.greenjolly.net/media/razom.mp3.

The mission statement of Perspectives on Politics states as one of its primary goals “showing what political science can offer to help people understand a crucial political event or tendency”. One such crucial political event is the recent wave of “colored revolutions” that swept through Serbia, Georgia, Ukraine, and Kyrgyzstan in the early to mid-part of this decade, all of which brought down regimes following allegations of electoral fraud in national elections. In many ways, these revolutions came as a surprise to much of the international and scholarly communities. In response, numerous explanations have been put forward to explain their occurrence, including geo-strategic politics, CIA-organized plots, elite-based modular learning, and the inability of government elites to successfully consolidate authoritarian rule. Although all over the map in terms of causal explanations, almost all of these proposed explanations share a common feature in their focus on the actions and decisions of elites. As these revolutions clearly could not have taken place without the mass protests that accompanied them, it seems important to consider the motivations of the masses as well.

For this reason, the aspect of political science to which I turn in this article is one that focuses on mass motivation for participation in protest: the now well-known collective action problem. First introduced to the study of political science by scholars such as Thomas Schelling and Macur Olson, collective action problems characterize situations in which groups would benefit from collective action that may not occur because individual incentives push people away from participating in the group activity.2

See Schelling 1960; Olson 1971.

Following in the line of work initiated by Dennis Chong and Timur Kuran, who apply collective action frameworks to the study of social movements and revolution generally, in this article I apply the collective action framework specifically to the question of why protestors choose to take to the streets following instances of electoral fraud.3

See Chong 1991; Kuran 1991, 1995.

My argument, explained later in greater detail, is relatively simple. I suggest that in cases where citizens have strong grievances against the regime, attempts to address these grievances in the course of daily life are likely to entail high costs coupled with very low chances of success in any meaningful sense; consequently, most citizens choose not to challenge the regime. Therefore, although everyone would benefit from living in a country where the government is restrained by the citizenry—indeed, Weingast refers to this as the very foundation of democracy itself—citizens choose not to take the steps necessary to do so because of the costs they will bear as individuals, and the regime continues to be able to abuse its power.4

See Weingast 1997, 2005.

When the regime commits electoral fraud, however, an individual's calculus regarding whether to participate in a challenge to the regime can be changed significantly. The likelihood of protests occurring following electoral fraud can greatly lower the perceived costs to any individual of participating in a challenge against the regime. Similarly, if the electoral fraud calls into question the very outcome of the election, then it can significantly increase the expected benefit from participating in the collective action, as the bums literally can be tossed out if things go well. Taken together, the logic of collective action problems can explain why citizens in oppressive societies that seemingly tolerate government abuses most of the time can rise up in the face of electoral fraud to say, as the Georgian opposition group named itself, “Enough!”5

The group was called Kmara in Georgian, which means enough. A Belarusian opposition campaign was named “Hopits”, which also means “enough” (Schipani-Aduriz and Kudrytski 2005).

In my opinion, there is value sui generis to thinking about protests in terms of the motivations of the people who actually participated in them, which to date have not played a particularly large role in the admittedly still new literature on the colored revolutions.6

Although see Fournier forthcoming and Way 2006.

However, even though my argument only attempts to explain why protests occur following electoral fraud and not the ultimate success or failure of that protest, it still leads to a new set of interpretations of the colored revolutions, many of which have potentially important policy implications. These include not overestimating the domestic support for leaders brought to power in colored revolutions, caution against interpreting colored revolutions as necessarily pro-Western, as well as the possibility for authoritarian learning in response to these revolutions and the form this might take.

Applying the collective action framework to the colored revolutions also yields a parsimonious contribution to the political science literature on social protest: electoral fraud can be a remarkably useful tool for solving the collective action problems faced by citizens in countries where governments, to use Weingast's language, are not appropriately restrained by the populace.7

See for example Weingast 1997, 2005.

While modest, such an observation actually can speak to a wide-ranging number of questions in the literature, including why people choose to protest when they do,8

See for example Kuran 1991; Tarrow 1994.

how protests at one place and time can affect the likelihood for future protests,9

See for example Chong 1991; Tarrow 1994.

and new aspects of the relationship between elections and protest.10

See for example Javeline 2003b.

Furthermore, applying the collective action framework to the colored revolutions produces a number of interesting testable hypotheses, as well as more general thoughts about directions for future research.

The remainder of the article is organized as follows. I begin by more precisely defining a few terms crucial to the argument: colored revolutions and electoral fraud, as well as what I mean by citizens with grievances against their governments or abusive governments. For those unfamiliar with the colored revolutions, I then provide in a brief descriptions of the events that comprised these revolutions in Serbia, Georgia, Ukraine, and Kyrgyzstan. In the following section, I detail a number of the existing explanations for these colored revolutions, before presenting my own argument regarding the value of thinking about electoral fraud as a focal point for solving collective action problems in societies where citizens have strong grievances against the regime. The next section then assesses the implications of this collective action framework for our understanding of both what has happened and what may happen in the future in these (and potentially other) countries. The penultimate section addresses theoretical contributions to some of the existing questions on social movements and protest in the political science literature. I then conclude the article with a number of avenues for future research.

Defining Terms and Concepts

Two terms in this article warrant attention in an effort to ensure precision in interpretation. First, I use the phrase colored revolutions to refer to the “Bulldozer Revolution” in Serbia in 2000, the “Rose Revolution” in Georgia in 2003, the “Orange Revolution” in Ukraine in 2004 and the “Tulip Revolution” in Kyrgyzstan in 2005.11

In some ways, the naming of these revolutions also has drawn attention to their similarities with one another. Interestingly, some had initially hoped to call the Tulip Revolution in Kyrgyzstan the “Lemon Revolution” in relation to the color yellow, which on a stoplight in that part of the world signifies “get ready to go” or “change” (Page 2005a). For a much broader conception of the second group of post-communist countries to join the “democratic club” that considers the events that transpired in the colored revolutions in conjunction with democratization in Slovakia, Croatia, Bulgaria, Romania and other countries, see Bunce 2005; Bunce and Wolchik 2005.

Although only one of these revolutions actually had a color as its symbol, the term colored revolutions has become a popular shorthand for referring to the events in these countries among regional specialists and local politicians. The use of the word “revolution” is not meant to imply any long-term consequences of these events, but rather only to identify that the anti-regime forces were in fact successful in overthrowing the current regime.12

McFaul 2005 refers to these events as the “second wave of democratization in the postcommunist world” (p. 8); Silitski 2005 calls them “Post-Soviet Electoral Revolutions”. In some ways, “democratization” is a less loaded term than revolution, but it similarly carries implications about the long term future. The reality of the situation is that it is still too early to know whether these events will end up either being revolutionary or leading to successful democratic consolidation in the long run.

Second, the term electoral fraud is intended to refer to situations in which electoral results were knowingly tampered with in an effort to advantage one candidate (or set of candidates) over another. One can conceive of two different types of fraud: minor electoral fraud, which affects elections in which results were tampered with but in which the tampering is perceived to have had little effect on the overall outcome of the election, or major electoral fraud, which affects elections in which electoral fraud is suspected to have influenced the overall outcome. In the context of the colored revolutions, this would imply a belief that either a different candidate would have been elected president or a different party would have controlled the parliament if the fraud had not occurred; and indeed, all four colored revolutions featured instances of what I have labeled major electoral fraud. The ideas contained in the remainder of this article focus on circumstances following this kind of major electoral fraud. Put another way, the arguments that follow assume that if the fraud is corrected, there is a strong chance that a different group of political forces would come to power.

Additionally, it is worth clarifying what exactly I mean by “grievances against the government” or “government abuses” of its population. Here I build on Barry Weingast's concept of citizens who are or are not able to place “appropriate limits on the state.”13

See Weingast 1997, 246.

One would expect citizens living in such countries to have “grievances against the government” and to suffer from “government abuses.” Examples of such behavior could include state agents engaging in acts of petty corruption, such as demanding bribes to perform routine state functions, or grand corruption, such as outright theft of state resources by upper level members of the government. It also could include a state that does not respect its citizens' political or civil rights. Even beyond examples of corrupt behavior or specific violations of rights, this sense of a non-limited or abusive state may extend to the feeling that citizens are not treated with the respect and dignity they deserve. This sentiment is well captured in a quote from Katya Kishinskaya, a 32-year-old pro-Western marketing executive for Nestlé in Kiev who before the Orange Revolution said of her trips abroad, “every time I return to Ukraine, I feel how different the regime is here. I feel it at the border, at customs. The people who have power don't respect you.”14

Jeremy Page 2004. Another nice description of such sentiments can be found in the work of anthropologist Anna Fournier, who documents the desire of participants in the Orange Revolution in Ukraine for poriadok, or “order”. What Ukrainians meant by order varied widely, but when Fournier asked Yushchenko supporters protesting she “got answers such as, order is ‘when the government doesn't steal’; ‘when salaries are paid on time, like they used to be’. Order is when ‘there are no bums on the street’, or when ‘one can start one's own business without problems’” (Fournier forthcoming, p. 3 of draft). In the language of this article, the lack of poriadok was a grievance Ukrainian citizens held against their regime.

Obviously this is a fluid concept, and one that can be operationalized in many ways. We could think of it dichotomously: countries where Weingast's conditions for restraining the state either are or are not met. We also could think of it as more of a continuous variable, with citizens in countries such as the Khmer Rouge's Cambodia or Idi Amin's Uganda facing a much more abusive state than in Kuchma's Ukraine, which in turn was more abusive of its citizenry than, say, the Swedish government at the time. While there is no perfect measure of government abuse, certainly one potential proxy would be the overall level of corruption in a country; another could be the extent to which basic civil rights are respected. But regardless of how the concept may best be measured for empirical tests in the future, this general description should be sufficient for characterizing the basic argument of this article. For people with serious grievances against their government, it is difficult to act upon these grievances in day-to-day life; electoral fraud and, especially, major electoral fraud can change this situation significantly.

The Colored Revolutions

Before presenting my argument, I want to first provide some background information on the colored revolutions discussed in this article. Each shared the common feature of being centered around a fraudulent election. In all four cases, an election was held and results were widely viewed to have been seriously manipulated by the current regime. As a result, mass protests broke out in all four countries, although the size of these protests varied. After some period of uncertainty, the incumbent president either resigned from office and/or the election results were overturned, resulting in a member of the opposition becoming the new president of the country.15

See as well Beissinger 2007, 261–263, for a slightly more detailed description of the common features across these events. As will be noted, in Georgia and Kyrgyzstan, although the fraudulent elections were for the legislature, the conflict was still resolved by the resignation of the current president and the election of an opposition leader in a subsequent early election.

Of course, in practice this played out in a different manner in each of the four countries. In Serbia, incumbent president Slobodan Milošević scheduled early presidential elections for September 24, 2000, assuming that he would easily win, even though his term as Yugoslavia's president did not expire until July 2001. His primary opposition was Vojislav Kostunica of the Democratic Party of Serbia, who was the nominee of the Democratic Opposition of Serbia (DOS), a broad alliance of Serbian opposition groups.16

Todorovic 2000, Racin 2000a. The two also faced competition from another opposition leader, Belgrade mayor Vojislav Mihajlovic of the Serbian Renewal Party. Fears that he would split the opposition vote later proved unfounded; see Guzelova 2000.

On September 26, the Yugoslav Election Commission announced that Kostunica had gained the most support with 48.2 percent of the vote and in a second round run-off with would face Milošević, who had come in second place, since neither candidate had received the necessary 50 percent of the vote to be declared the winner.17

Racin 2000b.

The DOS, on the basis of its 25,000 election monitors, announced that by its count Kostunica had won 55 percent of the vote to Milošević's 35 percent with 97.5 percent of the ballots counted, and Kostunica immediately announced that he would not participate in the run-off because the official results represented “political fraud and obvious stealing of votes.”18

“Kostunica rejects run-off against Milosevic.” Agence France Presse, September 26 2000, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.

The following day, opposition leaders called for a “total blockade” of all institutions in Serbia and over 200,000 people took to the streets of Belgrade.19

“Yugoslav opposition calls for “blockade” to force Milosevic's hand,” Deutsche Presse-Agentur, September 27, 2000, accessed through Lexis-Nexis, and Irena Guzelova and Stefan Wagstyl, “Serbs mass to push Milosevic out,” Financial Times, September 28, 2000, p. 1, accessed through Lexis-Nexis. Estimates of the size of the crowd vary; Thompson and Kuntz 2004 report that there were 700,000 people in Belgrade on the 5th; McFaul 2005 describes the march on Belgrade as a “million-strong” (p. 13).

On October 5—the day after the Serbian Constitutional Court had annulled the election results, effectively denying Kostunica victory—over half a million people marched on Belgrade and quickly seized control of major government institutions including the parliament and Serbian state run television. Protestors used a front-end loader to break through barricades, thus earning the events the name of the “Bulldozer Revolution.”20

Savic 2000. “Protesters enter Parliament Building,” UPI, October 5, 2000, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.

The following day, Milošević resigned in a late night television appearance and the Yugoslav Constitutional Court declared Kostunica the winner of the election.21

“Popular Revolt Sweeps Yugoslav Opposition Into Power; President Milošević Concedes Defeat—Protesters Over-run Parliament,” Facts on File World News Digest, October 5, 2000, p. 729A1, accessed through Lexis-Nexis, and “Yugoslav Constitutional Court Confirms Election Irregularities,” Beta News Agency (Belgrade), in Serbo-Croat, 1618 GMT, October 6, 2000, in BBC Monitoring Europe—Political, October 6, 2000, accessed through Lexis-Nexis. For more on the Serbian Bulldozer Revolution, see Birch 2002; Bieber 2003; Tunnard 2003; Thompson and Kuntz 2004.

The Georgian Rose Revolution unfolded in a similar manner almost three years later, although the crisis was sparked by a legislative, as opposed to presidential, election.22

This fact is occasionally overlooked given that the crisis ended with the resignation of the president and new presidential elections. It has been suggested that the Georgian opposition leaders themselves had not expected the legislative elections to lead to the overthrow of Shevardnadze, but instead had thought their own revolution would take place following the 2005 presidential elections (personal communication with Valerie Bunce, October 6, 2005).

Following the November 2, 2003, Georgian parliamentary elections, small-scale protests began in Tbilisi as various reports of fraud began to accumulate. However, after the release of a set of particularly suspect results from the region of Ajaria, the size of the crowds began to increase substantially.23

Fairbanks 2004, 116.

By the time the Georgian Central Election Commission proclaimed the “official” results, handing victory to the pro-President Eduard Shevardnaze “For a New Georgia” bloc, the crowds had swelled to over 100,000 people.24

Johnson 2003.

On November 22, these protests came to a head as Shevardnaze tried to address the inaugural session of the newly “elected” parliament.25

Topuria 2003a.

Led by opposition leader Mikhail Saakashvili—holding a rose to show he was unarmed26

Eudes and Topuria 2003.

—protestors stormed the parliament demanding Shevardnadze's resignation; Shevardnaze was ushered out of the building by his bodyguards without a shot being fired.27

Badkhen 2003; Topuria 2003b; Johnson 2003.

After originally claiming that he would not step down, Shevardnaze resigned the following day.28

“Shevardnadze Resigns in Georgia's ‘Velvet Revolution,’” ONASA News Agency, November 23, 2003, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.

Shortly thereafter, Georgia's Supreme Court annulled most of the results from the parliamentary election, and new presidential elections were set for January 4, 2004, which Saakashvili would go on to win with 96.2 percent of the vote in what was essentially an uncontested election.29

See Fairbanks 2004, 118, and “Georgia's Velvet Revolution; Shevardnadze Toppled,” Economist.com, Tuesday, November 25, 2003, accessed through Lexis-Nexis. Of course, ushering in a “democratic” revolution with a Soviet-style 96.2% of the vote raises its own questions for the future of Georgian democratization. For more on the Rose Revolution, see Devdariani 2004; Fairbanks 2004.

The following winter, a presidential election set the stage for Ukraine's Orange Revolution. On October 31, 2004, Viktor Yanukovich, the officially anointed successor to the regime of outgoing president Leonid Kuchma, and opposition leader Viktor Yushchenko received 39.3 percent and 39.9 percent of the vote, respectively, in the first round of the Ukrainian presidential election.30

Kuzio 2005b, 119.

As neither surpassed the 50 percent threshold necessary for a first-round victory, the two advanced to a November 21 run-off. Following a second round of voting marked by wide-spread instances of voter fraud—including the illegal expulsion of opposition representatives from election commissions, multiple voting by busloads of people, absentee ballot abuse, and an extraordinary high number of mobile ballot box votes31

U.S. State Department, 2005a.

as well as dramatic changes in turnout figures in eastern Ukraine, where Yanukovich's support was stronger32

See Karatnycky 2005, and Arel 2005,

—the Central Election Commission declared Yanukovich the winner by a 49.5 percent to 46.6 percent margin.33

See Kuzio 2005b, 119.

Armed with nonpartisan exit polls suggesting that actually Yushchenko had won by a 52 percent–43 percent margin, supporters of the challenger took to the streets of Kiev in protest, now famously adorned in orange clothing representing the color of Yushchenko's “Our Ukraine” parliamentary bloc.34

See Karatnycky 2005.

The extremely well-organized opposition settled in for the long haul, complete with tents for housing, stages for bands and speeches, bans on the use of alcohol and even regularly scheduled garbage removal.35

See Way 2005a, 143, Gruda, 2004, and Holley 2004

Over the following weeks, the protests continued in Kiev despite frigid conditions as the crisis was resolved peacefully through the use of existing institutions. Following a parliamentary resolution declaring the results invalid (November 27) and a vote of no confidence in the government (December 1), Ukraine's Supreme Court on December 3 somewhat stunningly—and in marked contrast to the actions of the Serbian Constitutional Court during the Bulldozer Revolution—declared the second round election results to be invalid and ordered that the round be run again on December 26.36

See Karatnycky 2005 and U.S. State Department, Country Background Notes: Ukraine. The question of why the Serbian and Ukrainian courts diverged in their approaches to their respective revolutions remains an excellent subject for future research. In particular, it would be interesting to gauge the extent to which the members of the Ukrainian Supreme Court were aware of the role previously played by the Serbian Constitutional Court.

This “second” second round went more smoothly with over 12,000 international observers present, and Yushchenko won by a 52.0 percent to 44.2 percent margin.37

Wheeler and MacKinnon 2004. For more on the Orange Revolution, see Karatnycky 2005; Kuzio 2005a, 2005b; Way 2005a.

As in Georgia, the Kyrgyz Tulip Revolution took place after allegations of major electoral fraud in a legislative election, although again it culminated with the resignation of a president. The February 27 and March 13, 2005, parliamentary elections followed a change in the composition of the Kyrgyz parliament and the election rules used to select the members for that body; both sets of changes were seen as an effort by current Kyrgyz President Askar Akayev to stack the parliament with his allies, including members of his own family.38

Heintz, 2005.

After two rounds of elections marred by accusations of fraud and regime interference—Kilmo Kiljunen, the Finish head of the OSCE observer mission, reported that the election was “undermined by vote buying, deregistration of candidates, interference with media and worryingly low confidence in judicial and electoral institutions on the part of voters and candidates”39

McLaughlin 2005.

—the opposition won a total of only 6 out of 75 seats.40

Page 2005b.

On March 15, protests began in the southern Kyrgyz city of Jalalabad demanding Akaev's ouster, and over the next week would spread to other parts of the country including Talas and Osh.41

Ibid.; see as well Stephen 2005, “People Power, Perhaps; Central Asian Unrest,” The Economist, Economist.com, March 22, 2005, accessed through Lexis-Nexis; Page 2005c.

These protests would culminate nearly two weeks later with 30,000 protesters converging in the main square of Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan's capital, and the subsequent flight of Akayev to Russia.42

Curtis 2005, Spencer 2005, and “3rd Roundup: Kyrgyz Opposition Seizes Power, President Flees,” Deutsche Press-Agentur, March 24, 2005, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.

Unlike the Georgian and Ukrainian protests, however, the Tulip Revolution had its violent aspects, with the reported death of six protestors and looting associated with the protests causing an estimated $100 million in damage.43

“No One Behind Kyrgyz Revolution—Leader,” ITAR-TASS News Agency, Moscow, May 8, 2005, 7:00 GMT, in BBC Monitoring International Reports, May 8, 2005, accessed through Lexis-Nexis (on the number of protestors killed) and U.S. State Department 2005b (on the estimated damage from looting).

Although Akayev eventually agreed to resign on April 4, leading to the election of opposition leader Kurmabek Bakiyev as president on July 10 with over 88 percent of the vote, the fraudulently elected parliament was allowed to continue to operate without new elections as part of negotiations among the various opposition figures.44

Weir 2005.

One additional common feature across the four colored revolutions is that they all took place in extremely corrupt societies. At the time of the Bulldozer Revolution, Serbia ranked 89th out of the 90 countries in Transparency International's Corruption Perception Index (CPI), scoring a 1.3 on a 0 (highly corrupt) to 10 (highly clean) score; only Nigeria was judged to be more corrupt.45

According to Transparency International, the “CPI score relates to perceptions of the degree of corruption as seen by business people, risk analysts and the general public”. In 2000, the CPI ranked Yugoslavia as opposed to Serbia individually. See http://www.transparency.org/cpi/2000/cpi2000.html.

The year of the Rose Revolution, Georgia ranked 124th out of 133 countries, with a score of 1.8.46 In 2004, Ukraine scored 2.2, which was good enough to tie with five other countries for 122nd–128th out of 145 countries.47 And in 2005, Kyrgyzstan tied for 130th–136th place out of 159 countries.48 So not only were all four of these countries plagued by corruption, they were actually some of the most corrupt countries in the entire world.49

Other surveys confirm this as well; see, for example, Cokgezen 2004.

Put in the context of the terminology of the previous section, therefore, there would be little reason to expect citizens of these countries not to hold significant grievances against their respective regimes.

Explaining the Colored Revolutions

Broadly speaking, two general sets of explanations for the colored revolutions have been proposed in the academic literature.50

For work taking a systematic approach exploring the degree of support for a number of different factors that could explain these second wave revolutions, see in particular Beissinger 2007; Bunce 2005; and McFaul 2005.

The first set of explanations places these events in a larger framework of the post-cold war world of East vs. West in Europe. This argument usually takes one of two related forms. The first approach stresses the lure of the West for members of the opposition fearful that their countries' current leadership could be leading the country down a path of permanent exclusion from “Europe” generally and European institutions such as the EU more specifically.51

Obviously, this particular explanation is less cited in the Kyrgyz case.

For example, Kuzio notes that in Ukraine, “inspired by the transformation of their country's western neighbors from Soviet satellites to EU members, the young generation supported Yushchenko's vision of a democratic and ‘European’ Ukraine.”52

See Kuzio 2005b, 127.

In Georgia, a bodyguard of one of the opposition leaders reflected on the success of the Rose Revolution by noting that “we have done it without bloodshed. This is the first time such a thing has happened in Georgia. It means that finally we deserve our place in Europe.”53

Strauss 2003.

This draw of Europe was not lost on the opposition leaders either. In Georgia, Saakashvili described the Rose Revolution as a “European-type velvet revolution,”54

“Opposition Leader Describes Movement As ‘Velvet Revolution,’” Rustavi-2 TV, Tbilisi, in Georgian, November 21, 2003, BBC Monitoring, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.

while in Ukraine Yushchenko promised in his inaugural speech to lead the country “into the mainstream of Europe” stating that “we are no longer on the edge of Europe… We are situated in the center of Europe.”55

Myers 2005.

Especially popular in Russia is a second form of this East-West story, which places these revolutions squarely in the context of post-cold war geopolitical struggles for dominance between Russia and the West, particularly in areas that had long been considered in the Soviet sphere of influence. For example, noted Russian political consultant Vyacheslav Nikonov commented before the Ukrainian elections:

I can often hear that it doesn't really make any difference to Russia who wins the elections, Yanukovich or Yushchenko. Actually there are two differences. Yushchenko and his victory will mean Ukraine will become a NATO member in a couple of years. This has been stated by Yushchenko and the leadership of the US and NATO. Second, under Yanukovich Ukraine will be part of the common economic space that is being created by Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan. Under Yushchenko it won't. So, basically what is being decided now is whose ally Ukraine will be in the next 100 years as a minimum. The victory of one candidate will mean that Ukraine will be an ally of the United States. The victory of the other candidate will give us hope to think that it may become an ally of Russia.56

“Radio Interview with Politka Fund President Vyacheslav Nikonov on the Upcoming Presidential Elections in Ukraine,” Radio 24 Mayak (Moscow) in Russian 15:15, October 29, 2004, in Official Kremlin International News Broadcast, October 29, 2004, accessed through Lexis-Nexis (emphasis added).

The more nefarious view of this struggle attributed the success of the various colored revolutions to CIA plots carried out by American-sponsored NGOs, and in particular George Soros and his Open Society Institute.57

It was not only Russians who ascribed an important role to Soros. Zaza Gachechiladze, editor of the Tbilisi-based English-language daily, The Georgian Messenger, stated that “it is generally accepted public opinion here that Mr. Soros is the person who planned Shevardnadze's overthrow.” Phillips 2003.

As an article in Russia's Nezavisimaya Gazeta noted, “Russian political analysts are fond of referring to divisions of the Soros Foundation and Carnegie Center that ‘force democracy’ all over the world.”58

Lantukhina and Glikin 2005. For similar sentiments, see the quote by Russian commentator Tatiana Netreba in Herd 2005, 4.

Kuzio also highlights “the fact that [Ukraine's student-led movement] PORA! was modeled on Serbia's OTPOR and Georgia's Kmara gave substance to the allegation that the Orange Revolution was imported from the United States via Serbia and Georgia…. Claims that it was an American plot … were widely accepted in Russia.”59

See Kuzio 2005b, 127. Although by the time of the Ukrainian elections many Russians were subscribing to the geo-political struggle viewpoint, it is important to note that Russian Foreign Minister Igor Ivanov most likely played an important role in getting Shevardnaze to step down in Georgia. At the height of the opposition protests, Ivanov shuttled back and forth in Georgia between Shevardnadze and the opposition. Crucially, upon arriving in Tbilisi, he went first to see the opposition at their rally in front of the parliament, and only then went to see Shevardnaze (see “Shevardnadze Resigns In Georgia's ‘Velvet Revolution,’” ONASA News Agency, November 23, 2003, accessed through Lexis-Nexis, and Stier 2003). Moreover, not all Russians supported the allegedly pro-Russian Yanukovich. Most notably, Russian democratic opposition leader Boris Nemtsov was a visible figure at the opposition rallies in Kiev (see Cullison and Chazan 2004).

The fear in Moscow was that all of these revolutions were merely a prelude to the big prize—the overthrow of the Russian government. As Andrei Vladimirov put it in Itogi, a Russian political weekly, at the time of the Orange Revolution, “The day before yesterday: Belgrade. Yesterday: Tbilisi. Today: Kiev. Tomorrow: Moscow.”60

Vladimirov 2005.

A slightly less conspiratorial and geo-strategic version of this explanation nonetheless continues to place the focus on the role played by external actors in assisting domestic opposition leaders, especially in terms of election monitoring.61

This argument is spelled out most clearly, although not necessarily supported, in Herd 2005, but see as well as the copious evidence of democracy assistance on the part of the United States and the Open Society Institute in Georgia in Fairbanks 2004. Beissinger 2007, Bunce 2005, and McFaul 2005 all also note the role of international actors.

The second general approach to explaining the colored revolutions has been to focus on the nature of the opposition movements in each of the countries. In particular, commentators have highlighted how opposition groups learned over time to become more effective, be it through their own experiences or through the transmission of information from external actors (and in particular actors from countries that had already experienced their own colored revolution). For example, in referring to the “Kuchmagate” scandal which began with revelations of corruption and impropriety in the regime of President Leonid Kuchma in November 2000, Kuzio notes that in Ukraine:

Civil society and opposition groups had been organizing and preparing for the 2004 election since the Kuchmagate crisis ignited exactly four years earlier. None of them doubted Kuchma's warning that the election would be Ukraine's dirtiest. In 2000–2003 these groups had been able to mobilize a maximum of 50,000 people on Kiev's streets. Their experience in crowd management ensured that the narod could be well organized, orderly, and peaceful.62

See Kuzio 2005a, 39–40. “Kuchmagate,” began in November 2000 when one of the president's own bodyguards came forth with hundreds of hours of conversations on tape in which President Kuchma was alleged to have been distributing favors to allies, ordering the payment of massive kickbacks, plotting illegally against opponents, and, possibly, even ordering the murder of opposition, muckraking internet journalist Heorhiy Gongadze. Other allegations included acts of violence against journalists and politicians, election fraud and arms trafficking; for more see Karatnycky 2005; Kuzio 2005a.

Similarly, Bieber focuses on the importance of unified civil society in Serbia, and McFaul notes the importance of a unified opposition more specifically.63

See Bieber 2003 and McFaul 2005, especially 9–10.

Likewise, Beissinger applies the concept of modular revolution he previously used for understanding nationalist movements in the former Soviet Union to the colored revolutions and highlights the effects of “structural advantages” for revolution (which includes the presence of transnational NGOs) in conjunction with “the power of example,” by which opposition elites learn from prior revolutions.64

See Beissinger 2002, 2007. Bunce 2005 also notes that prior revolutions can serve as models for subsequent revolutions (see 7).

Evidence of links across opposition elites are prevalent in media descriptions of the revolutions as well. For example, during the anti-Shevardnadze protests in Georgia, supporters of Saakashvili were seen waving a sign with the Serbo-Croat words “Gotov Je” (“He is through”),65

Topuria, 2003a.

and both Ukrainian and Georgian activists had traveled to Serbia for training in the period before the Rose and Orange Revolutions but after the Bulldozer Revolution.66

See Fairbanks 2004, Lowe 2003, Gruda 2004. In addition to Soros, non-governmental organizations such as the National Democracy Institute (NDI) and the International Republican Institute (IRI) also played a role in financing training seminars (personal communication with Valerie Bunce on the basis of her personal interviews, October 6, 2005).

A third important line of explanation has been advanced by Lucan Way. Building on his previous work on the phenomenon of “unconsolidated authoritarian regimes”,67

See in particular Levitsky and Way 2002.

Way has argued that the success of the Orange Revolution can best be understood as a consequence of Kuchma's inability to successfully “consolidate” an authoritarian regime in Ukraine.68

See Way 2005a, 2005b.

Here, the emphasis is on the inability of government elites to prevent a successful uprising, as opposed to either the ability of international forces or opposition elites to deliver one.

My goal in this article is not to deny the importance of any of these explanations—and clearly, all of them do add in important ways to our understanding of the colored revolutions—but it is interesting to note that they are all essentially elite-based analyses. In the following section, I explore what happens when we place the mass publics that participated in the protests leading to these revolutions closer to the center of the analysis.

Collective Action Problems, Major Electoral Fraud, and Grievances against the State

One way to think about the challenges faced by citizens with strong grievances against their governments is the framework of the collective action problem.69

Indeed, Weingast uses the language of collective action problems when he writes that “democratic stability occurs when citizens and elites construct a focal solution that resolves their coordination dilemmas about limits on the state” (Weingast 1997, 246).

The idea of a collective action problem is a very familiar one for social scientists; indeed, typing “collective action” into Google Scholar results in over 100,000 hits. Simply put, collective action problems characterize situations in which a group would benefit from cooperation, but the lack of individual incentives to engage in the actions necessary to achieve this cooperation prevents the goal from being attained. Each individual faces a cost to participating in the action necessary to achieve the group goal, a benefit that they will enjoy from the group goal being attained, and a belief about the likelihood of the group successfully attaining that goal. If individuals believe that their cost of participation outweighs the benefits to be gained from the group goal, then they will choose not to participate. And if enough individuals choose not to participate—the threshold obviously varies widely across different collective action problems—then the goal will not be achieved. Similarly, if individuals value the group goal but believe that the likelihood that it can be achieved is sufficiently low, then again they will choose not to participate and the goal will not be achieved. Solving collective action problems, therefore, depends on the costs of participation, the benefits of the goal being sought, and beliefs about the likelihood that the goal can be achieved.70

For a more thorough explication of collective action problems and their application in particular to social movements, see Chong 1991, especially 4–5. For a clear and easily accessible formal explication of some of the characteristics of collective action problems, see Shepsle and Bonchek 1997, ch. 9.

Abusive or unrestrained states present a classic collective action problem.71

See Weingast 1997, 2005.

Most members of society would likely agree that society as a whole would be better off with a less abusive and appropriately restrained state. This is not to deny that there are individual actors in society who clearly benefit from these types of arrangements. Nevertheless, the assumption that most citizens would prefer not to have to pay bribes to policemen, health care workers, and government bureaucrats, and would also prefer not to have government officials stealing public funds and using their public positions for private financial gain, seems to be a reasonable one. Achieving this goal in states where such abusive actions regularly take place, however, requires confronting these abuses and attempting to stop them. This can take a variety of forms, but all share two common features. First, there is a cost to any individual in taking any of these steps, from the relatively minor loss of time to the potentially major loss of livelihood or life. Second, the likelihood of success is always questionable, and this is especially so for individuals facing petty corruption in the course of daily life. While it may be possible to avoid one bribe at one point in time, the chance of this action affecting the overall nature of state behavior is beyond minimal. This combination yields the familiar result predicted by the collective action framework: individuals “shirk” and tolerate whatever actions on the part of the state that have given rise to their grievances, and as a result everyone is worse off from having to continue to live under an abusive regime. Readers should note that in order for the following argument to hold, it is not in any way necessary that all citizens perceive the same level of grievances, or even the same grievances for that matter. The key point is that enough citizens hold grievances against the regime that they could effect change if they managed to work together, but are customarily prevented from doing so by the logic of the collective action framework.

Major electoral fraud, however, can help solve this collective action problem.72

I am not the only scholar attempting to leverage the collective action framework in an effort to make sense of revolutions following periods of electoral fraud. In a recent conference paper, Thompson and Kuntz also make use of this theoretical framework in an attempt to explain a set of revolutionary events in countries that go beyond the post-communist cases but share the common feature of following instances of electoral fraud. For more on their approach, see Thompson and Kuntz 2005; for an earlier application of a similar approach to just the Serbian case, see Thompson and Kuntz 2004.

It can do so by both lowering the costs of participating in anti-regime actions or increasing the likelihood of a successful result stemming from those actions. In terms of costs, we need to compare the likelihood of punishment from combating an unrestrained state in standard situations with the likelihood of punishment from attempting to combat such a state in the circumstances following major electoral fraud. If an individual refuses to pay a bribe to a policeman, it is possible that the policeman will just get frustrated and eventually walk away. But it is also possible that the individual will be hauled into the police station, spend time in jail, and end up being forced to pay an even bigger bribe to be released.73

And indeed, journalists Peter Baker and Susan Glasser relate that in Moscow “the husband of a Russian friend made the mistake of refusing to pay $100 demanded by a particularly greedy gaishnik [slang for Moscow's notoriously corrupt traffic police] and insisted on being taken to the police station instead. In the end, he was forced to pay a $200 bribe to the station commander” (Baker and Glasser 2005, 246–7).

If an entrepreneur refuses to pay a bribe to fire inspectors, then she may find the opening of her new restaurant delayed inevitably while she continues to face all of her overhead expenses. And if an investigative journalist chooses to expose corruption in the press, then it is possible that she will pay for this decision with her life; indeed, in Ukraine, the “Kuchmagate” scandal referred to earlier in this article focused on the decapitation of journalist Georgi Gongadze, “a longtime critic of the [Kuchma] regime and a crusader against corruption.”74

See Kuzio 2005b, 119.

While the “costs” associated with combating an unrestrained state differ significantly across these examples, they all share the common feature of almost complete certainty that if there is punishment associated with defying the regime, it will be borne by the person doing the defying. There is usually little room for group solidarity in any of these actions, whether it involves being alone with a policeman in a dark alleyway or having one's name in a newspaper byline.

Major electoral fraud, however, changes this calculation dramatically. For once, the entire country is experiencing the same act of abuse simultaneously; in the language of the collective action literature, major electoral fraud provides an obvious focal point for action.75

On focal points, see Schelling 1960, Chong 1991, Weingast 1997. Thompson and Kuntz (2005) take this one step further, arguing that not only does electoral fraud present an act of abuse aimed at everyone at the same time, but that it actually “creates an ‘imagined community’ of robbed voters, in which people can suppose that also their attitudes towards the regime's latest behavior are shared by their fellow-citizens” (11).

People no longer have to choose whether to react alone. Especially as crowds grow, individuals know that they will only be one of many, many people protesting, and thus much less likely to be punished individually. (Indeed, observers of the Orange Revolution in Ukraine suggest that during the first days of protest some supporters held back precisely to gauge the likelihood of punishment in the form of an armed response.)76

Personal communication with Oxana Shevel, October 5, 2005.

This does not mean that there is no chance of punishment—and it is certainly not meant to deny the bravery of citizens who risked harm to participate in the revolutions described above—but only to note that major electoral fraud presents an opportunity to act on grievances against the current regime without a high degree of certainty that punishment—if it is forthcoming—will be felt by you individually.

Simultaneously, major electoral fraud followed by large scale protests can dramatically increase the likelihood of a successful “result” from one's participation in an anti-regime protest. As Thompson and Kuntz noted in Serbia, “people showed greater readiness to take part in antiregime protests because such activities were now considered much more likely to succeed. The sense of powerlessness that had kept Serbian society paralyzed for so long gave way to a pervasive feeling of political possibility, as Milošević's image of omnipotence was fundamentally shaken.”77

Thompson and Kuntz 2004, 168.

This is of course not to say that all large scale protests against abusive regimes are successful. But as my point here is not to explain successful regime change but rather the individual-level motivation that leads people to participate in protests, a belief in at least the possibility of success is important. Again, it is instructive to consider the conditions created by major electoral fraud in comparison to the conditions faced by people in their day-to-day lives. There is almost no chance that the refusal to pay a bribe will lead to any noticeable change in the overall level of abusive behavior by a regime. Perhaps a particularly influential journalist could effect important change—and here the case of Gonganze in Ukraine is at least somewhat illustrative—but this is not an opportunity that most citizens have every day. By contrast, major electoral fraud offers hope for greater success in two important ways. First, if protests follow the fraud, then immediately there is the opportunity to speak out with a much stronger voice than anyone could have alone. But perhaps even more importantly, fighting major electoral fraud holds open the hope of changing who actually wields political power in a country: if you are successful, the bums actually can be thrown out.

Belief about the likelihood of success is also likely to be affected by past experiences. Previous mass protests—such as the Kuchmagate protests in Ukraine or the Serbian protests in the winter of 1996–97—can teach citizens important information about the likelihood of punishment for participating in future protests. Similarly, the experiences of other countries can provide important lessons about the potential likelihood of success. Once the Serbs have successfully thwarted Milošević's attempt to steal a Serbian election, Georgians who have to decide whether or not to protest Shevardnaze's attempt to steal a Georgian election have that much more reason to be optimistic about success in their own country. So the collective action framework allows for learning across revolutions as well, but emphasizes learning that goes on at the mass level as opposed to merely at the elite level.78

Of course, the observation of mass-based learning can also lead to learning among autocratic leaders concerned with the possibility of facing similar crises in the future, a point I return to later in this article.

Moreover, there are additional reasons why elections can be particularly effective focal points for solving collective action problems. First, they come with a limited time frame—the matter generally needs to be resolved before the fraudulent winners take office—which again can encourage citizens to participate by enhancing the belief that other citizens will participate at this point in time as well.79

Beissinger 2007, 264. Javeline 2003b also makes a similar point about the ability of elections to facilitate the apportioning of blame by politicians to other political forces because “this information is provided in a finite amount of time” (109).

Put another way, this can explain away a part of the free rider problem associated with collective action problems. I may prefer to sit on my couch and let someone else do the protesting, but I know that if enough protesters do not appear in a very short time frame, then the opportunity to confront the regime will be lost. If I care about confronting the regime, then the costs of inaction at this particular moment are significantly higher than they normally are. Second, elections draw international attention. This can take many forms, including international elections observers, foreign media, statements by foreign leaders, and even direct attempts at mediation of post-election crises (as was the case in the Orange Revolution). Regardless of the form it takes, international attention—especially for regimes holding elections in part to seek international legitimacy—should serve to decrease the perceived likelihood of an armed response to protests. To the extent that citizens believe an armed response by the regime to be less likely, this should also help decrease the perceived costs of participating in protests against the regime. This, too, can be thought of in terms of reducing the appeal of free riding; I will likely find the free rider option much more attractive if I have concerns that participation will lead to me being shot. Additionally, elections can help provide an incentive for reducing divisions among opposition leaders. Crucially, this incentive develops in the time leading up to the election, especially if opposition leaders are able to agree on a single opposition candidate. Thus when the electoral fraud does occur, citizens are more likely to get a clear signal from opposition leaders regarding both the logistics and goals of the protests, which in turn should help increase their belief in the likelihood of the protests succeeding.80

If taken as a sign of opposition competence, it could even help decrease beliefs about the likelihood of punishment, if citizens believe that a more organized opposition is more likely to have assured the support or neutrality of security forces a priori.

Finally, elections occur at regular and repeated intervals, which increases the likelihood that both of these events—international attention and opposition coordination—can occur.

It is important to note what major electoral fraud does not do as well, which is to completely solve the free rider problem associated with all collective action problems. There is nothing inherent in the nature of elections or electoral fraud that explains why once there are 100,000 protestors on the street, the 100,001st protestor might not prefer to stay home where it is warm than to join the protests. That being said, thinking of citizens with grievances against abusive regimes in terms of a collective action framework points us towards the importance of individual considerations of the expected costs and benefits of confronting an abusive regime. This in turn leads to all of the preceding observations in this section regarding how major electoral fraud both lowers the costs and increases the expected benefits of anti-regime activity as compared to normal day-to-day life. So, put another way, major electoral fraud may not be able to explain the presence of the 100,001st protestor, but it can help us to understand why all 100,001 people are more likely to be engaging in anti-regime action at that time than any other time. This is of course not to say that changes in individual cost-benefit analyses are the only reason why people take to the streets. There are obviously many reasons why people could have chosen to participate in the protests of the colored revolutions, including feelings of duty, the sense that it was something fun to do, and the desire to be on the winning side of a conflict. Nevertheless, the fact that major electoral fraud can help solve a collective action problem for citizens with grievances against an unrestrained regime deserves scrutiny as an important factor as well. Furthermore, if the mechanism I have described here is important, then it leads to a number of interesting implications for how we ought to interpret these colored revolutions.

Implications of the Collective Action Framework for the Colored Revolutions

In this section, I highlight five particularly important implications of thinking about the colored revolutions through the lens of major electoral fraud as a means of solving collective action problems. First, this framework clearly warns against overstating the likely reservoir of public support for the new regimes that emerged after the colored revolutions. For example, the Orange Revolution in Ukraine should not be interpreted as outrage over the fact that Yushchenko specifically was denied the presidency, but rather over the abuse of power by the Kuchma regime that could allow Yushchenko to be denied the presidency. This subtle distinction is meaningful, as it implies that Yushchenko should have a shorter leash from the Ukrainian public than we might normally expect from a conquering hero swept into office by an adoring public.81

One possible useful comparison here is someone like Vaclav Havel, who may have eventually worn out his welcome in the Czech Republic but certainly was given a much longer period of time to do so.

And in fact events in Ukraine seem to confirm that Yushchenko was indeed on such a short leash. As early as March 2005, Ukrains'ka Pravda had published an article entitled “Did We Win?” noting that “What specifically has changed around here? Only the faces.”82

“Did We Win? Or, the Notes of an ‘Orange’ Official,” Ukrains'ka pravda, March 15, 2005 (http://www2.pravda.com.ua/archive/2005/march/15/1.shtml) in Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 343 (April 9, 2005), translated by Peter Larson for UKL.

Within half a year of the conclusion of the Orange Revolution, the Kiev Post—an English-language Ukrainian newspaper that strongly supported the Orange Revolution—was running editorials entitled “An Utter Disgrace” and asking “Just how is President Yushchenko's government more honest than former President Kuchma's?”83

“An Utter Disgrace”, Kiev Post, May 17, 2005, in Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 349 (May 19, 2005).

Similarly, we should be cautious about assuming that whenever pro-democracy forces have overthrown illiberal regimes in post-communist countries, pro-Western policies will follow. If the revolution is in large part a reaction on the part of the mass public to a domestic problem (grievances against an insufficiently restrained state), then attaching excessive geo-strategic significance to the change in regime may not be warranted. Thus, it is not surprising that in Serbia Kostinica could over throw Milošević, a long-standing foe of the West, and yet continue to pursue a brand of Serbian nationalism that was at times hostile to Western interests. Nor should it be surprising when the new foreign minister of Kyrgyzstan following the Tulip Revolution declares that “Russia is our close ally” and visits Moscow within weeks of coming to power.84

“US-Russian Rivalry On Hold Over Kyrgyzstan,” Turkish Daily News, April 3, 2005, accessed inLexis-Nexis and “Kyrgyz Interim Government Seeks Stabilization,” Deutsche Presse-Agentur, April 12, 2005, accessed in Lexis-Nexis.

Moreover, it suggests that those who want to read a Western victory over Russia into the Orange Revolution ought to pay closer attention to opinion polls taken in Ukraine around the time of the rerun of the second round of the election showing that 83 percent of Ukrainians had a favorable opinion (generally good or very good) of Russia.85

“Over 80% of Ukrainians Approve of Russia”, Interfax, January 4, 2005, in Johnson's Russia List (JRL), No. 9004 (January 4, 2005.)

The third implication of applying the collective action framework to these revolutions is that it suggests that so-called “delegative democracies” or “competitive authoritarian” states may be somewhat more fragile than originally thought.86

See Levitsky and Way (2002) and the many works they reference in their first endnote.

The events in these four countries demonstrate that there are inherent risks in trying to falsify election results. As I have noted previously, this article makes no predictions concerning when protests will successfully dislodge regimes from power. That being said, it is clear from the colored revolutions that one consequence of protest following major electoral fraud can be regime change. Thus trying to repeatedly carry out “fake” elections so as to maintain the international appearance of a democratic regime could turn out to be a problematic strategy. There are of course many examples of authoritarian or quasi-authoritarian countries that have carried out “fake” elections without losing power. Nevertheless, the examples of the colored revolutions demonstrate that such outcomes are not necessarily guaranteed a priori. Ironically, this may end up pushing some of these competitive authoritarian regimes back towards the old Soviet-style elections where even the pretense of competition is abandoned as these regimes learn that trying to manage exactly how many votes the opposition can accumulate on election day may prove dangerous. Or, put another way, leaders may learn that the safer way to manipulate election results is in controlling access to the ballot box (and media) as opposed to trying to change results once voting has begun. Just as pro-democracy forces have learned from past experiences, so too can leaders of quasi-authoritarian regimes.87

Lukashenka in Belarus is an obvious example here, but many of Putin's actions in Russia look logical from this framework as well. See as well Silitski 2005, which is provocatively titled “Is the Age of Post-Soviet Electoral Revolutions Over?”

With this in mind, a fourth implication of this article is that it calls attention to the importance of the way in which the existing regime reacts to opposition protests. More specifically, it highlights the fact that in all four of the colored revolutions addressed in this article, the military and security services refrained from carrying out any armed attacks against opposition protesters.88

Of course, the relationship between the use (or lack thereof) of repression and democratization more generally has long been an important topic in the literature on democratization; see for example O'Donnell and Schmitter 1986, especially p. 26–32, and Acemoglu and Robinson 2005, especially p. 162–7.

Such an outcome was not foreordained, but it all four cases it kept the cost of participating in protests for individuals lower than it would have been had security forces interfered.89

For an account of why the security forces stayed on the sidelines in the Orange Revolution, see C. J. Chivers 2005, although see as well Wilson 2005, 137–138 for concerns about the content of Chivers' story.

This observation, too, likely has not escaped the notice of leaders of other quasi-authoritarian regimes. Indeed, it seems quite plausible that future potential victims of colored revolutions will have concluded from the cases discussed in this article that a commitment to using force if necessary will be a crucial component of maintaining power. Although it did not follow an election, the May 2005 crackdown by security forces in Andijan, Uzbekistan, where hundreds if not thousands of people were killed, may forebode similar actions in the wake of post-election protests of the future.90

For more on the crackdown in Andijan and its aftermath, see “Uzbekistan: The Blood Red Revolution,” Economist, May 19, 2005, http://www.economist.com/PrinterFriendly.cfm?story_id=3992111 and “Uzbekistan: Black is White,” Transitions on Line, September 15, 2005, http://www.tol.cz/look/TOL/article.tpl?IdLanguage=1&IdPublication=4&NrIssue=133&NrSection=3&NrArticle=14707.

Finally, the argument somewhat more optimistically suggests that even people in states with little prior tradition of restraining their government in the manner suggested by Weingast can in fact come together to do so in the right situation. Weingast was primarily interested in the role that constitutions can play in this process, but he did note as well that “a galvanizing event such as a major riot, or a pact can serve to coordinate citizens' reactions so that citizens can police the state.”91

Weingast 1997, 251.

The experience of the colored revolutions reveals that major electoral fraud can also be such a galvanizing event.

Contributions to the Literature

In addition to offering new insights into the colored revolutions, applying the collective action framework to these events also offers a modest contribution to the existing literature on protest. Simply put, electoral fraud, and especially major electoral fraud, can be a remarkably powerful device for solving the collective action problems normally associated with preventing citizens from taking action against a regime towards which they hold serious grievances and, thus, facilitating protest. The many ways in which electoral fraud can accomplish this have already been detailed earlier, but in this section I highlight a number of important contributions of this insight for the existing literature on protest.

First and foremost, such an observation can help provide an answer—in certain circumstances—to what Sidney Tarrow calls the one of the big three questions of social movements: why do people protest when they do?92

The other two are why people protest at all and what determines success; see Tarrow 1994, 10.

This is always a difficult question for any explanation of protest that revolves around structure: if structure is ripe for protest, why does the protest not take place a month earlier or a month later? In a similar vein, Timur Kuran argues that rational choice theories do a very good job of explaining why protest should not break out, but notes that “from time to time revolution does break out, and this presents a puzzle that the standard theory of rational choice cannot solve.”93

Kuran 1991, 14.

While my contribution is far from a general theory, it does offer one specific answer to this question: publicized major electoral fraud can alter both the perceived costs and benefits of participating in protest in a way that ought to make participation more likely after the fraud has been committed but before the results of the fraudulent election have been implemented. In this way, it does help to point to at least one answer to the question of why people protest when they do.

Kuran rightly notes that perhaps the biggest challenge for rationalist explanations of protest is to explain why the first protestor takes to the streets. I would argue that under the framework put forward here, the first protestor takes to the streets for the same reason that subsequent protestors take to the street: the knowledge of major electoral fraud has altered her beliefs about the likelihood of success and punishment following anti-regime actions. Although these beliefs should change even more as crowds grow, the mere knowledge of the fraud should change the calculation enough for some to allow them to begin the protest, especially if there are prior examples of protest upon which they can draw.94

This also represents a good example of a how a mass-based account like the one I am proposing can interact with some of the elite-based explanations that are popular in the literature. More specifically, the extent to which opposition elites have prepared for such a situation by taking the kind of steps described earlier in the articles (e.g., coordinating on where protest will take place, having stages for protesters complete with sound-systems ready to be deployed, arranging for garbage pick-up, etc.) will also serve to decrease individuals' estimation of the costs of participating in protests.

While Kuran has a more complex mechanism for how subsequent protestors choose to join a protest, it is very interesting to note that one of the reasons he puts forward for that first protestor is that he or she “has an unpleasant encounter at some government ministry.”95

Kuran 1991, 19.

This is of course similar to what I have labeled grievances against the state. So while in Kuran's story a grievance causes the first protestor to take to the streets, in my account grievances create a reservoir of potential protestors should external circumstances change. In both cases, though, grievances provide the spur to protest. In my account, however, I also highlight a specific event—major electoral fraud—that can change external circumstances.

As I will discuss in the following section, electoral fraud is of course not the only event that can alter external circumstances. However, in focusing on an event related to elections, I augment Debra Javeline's arguments on the relationship between elections and protest.96

Javeline 2003b, 2003a.

Javeline's work on the relationship between blame and protest in Russia identifies three ways in which elections can facilitate protest: by providing a “purposively informative political environment,” by providing this information in a finite period of time and by providing people with a limited set of options for expressing blame.97

Javeline 2003b, 109.

I suggest a fourth way that elections and blame can lead to protest, which is by the election itself—once it has been fraudulently manipulated—becoming a source of blame against the current regime, and therefore functioning as a focal point for resolving collective action problems in the manner described previously.

Additionally, scholars of social movements have long noted that protest tends to occur in waves. Previous attempts have been made to explain the temporal dimensions of protest from a collective action framework. Tarrow writes that “once a cycle [of protest] begins, the costs of collective action are lower for other actors; new movements that arise in such contexts do not need to depend as much on internal resources as on the generalized opportunities of cycles of protest.”98

Tarrow 1994, 7.

Chong argues that “the availability of successful models of protest raises expectations about the chances of success,” which in turn makes people more likely to participate in future protest.99

Chong 1991, 96. Chong also argues that repeated opportunities for protest can help change what is essentially a prisoner's dilemma game concerning participation into an assurance game; see Chong 1991, ch. 5.

I add to this line of argument by proposing that protests to overturn electoral fraud can be another of these “successful models of protest” that can spur additional protest in the future. Furthermore, I suggest that it is not merely the likelihood of success from past instances that is important, but rather beliefs about the expected costs of participation that can be learned as well. When Ukrainians see that international attention to Georgian elections helped prevent an armed response to protest by the Georgian state, they can update their beliefs about the likelihood of similar restraint in a similar context in Ukraine. Moreover, unlike Chong's work, which is focused explicitly on experiences in one country (the United States), I have identified a context in which this phenomenon may be occurring across national borders.

Finally, and perhaps a bit more broadly, in an argument I have referred to previously in this article, Weingast has argued that in order to maintain democracy citizens need to be able to restrain the state. This can happen “only if they react in concert to violations of fundamental limits by withdrawing their support from the sovereign or political officials”100

Weingast 1997, 261.

and “have the ability to act in concert against political leaders who transgress constitutional rules.”101

Weingast 2005, 3.

Clearly there must be variety in the types of transgressions political leaders carry out. Some will facilitate and some will hinder the ability of citizens to react in the way Weingast suggests they must; the occurrence of the colored revolutions suggests that attempting to manipulate election results belongs in the former category.

Directions for Future Research

A final benefit of applying the collective action framework to the relationship between electoral fraud and anti-regime protest is that it yields a number of interesting avenues for future research, both in terms of specific hypotheses and some more general areas for research. At the micro-level, these hypotheses are quite obvious: we ought to expect citizens with higher beliefs about the probability of success and lower expectations of costs of participating to be more likely to participate in protests following electoral fraud. Additionally, we ought to expect—all else being equal—that citizens with more grievances against the regime would be more likely to participate in protests following electoral fraud.

But perhaps more interesting is the set of macro-level hypotheses that can be generated by the emphasis on the cost-benefit analysis inherent in any individual's decision to join a protest following electoral fraud. These hypotheses can be formulated based on beliefs about the set of circumstances that ought to make individuals more likely to participate in protests, and thus ought to make protests more likely to occur. First, we can hypothesize that protest should be more likely following major electoral fraud than other forms of electoral fraud; the logic here is that major electoral fraud holds out the promise of regime change if it is reversed, which would be a more valuable “success” in the eyes of anti-regime protesters. Similarly, we can hypothesize that protest will be more likely as knowledge of major electoral fraud is both more certain and more widespread. Put another way, it is not the fraud itself that should lead to protest, but rather certainty in the belief that the fraud has occurred.

The collective action framework also leads us to hypothesize that prior examples of successful protest following electoral fraud will increase the future likelihood of protest following electoral fraud. Again, the emphasis here is on the individual's calculation of the likelihood of success from protests following the current instance of electoral fraud; anything that increases her belief that success is likely should increase her chances of participating in the protests. Prior instances of protest following electoral fraud that are unsuccessful in effecting change should correspondingly decrease the likelihood of protest following the current instance of electoral fraud. To put this in context, success in Georgia and Ukraine may have encouraged the protestors in Belarus that took to the streets following elections in March 2006, but the failure of the Belarusian protests to overturn these results may make protest in Russia in 2007 less likely. Thus the collective-action approach can explain both why we might observe a sequence of cross-national protests following electoral fraud along the lines of the colored revolutions, but also, importantly, why they might stop as well. This leads directly to a fourth hypothesis, which is that prior examples of citizens bearing costs from participating in protests—and here the most obvious example would be an armed response by the regime—will make protest less likely in the future. Of course, the tricky question for all three of these propositions is what exactly constitutes a prior “example.” Is it only within one's own country? If so, the earlier failed Serbian protests would seem to falsify the hypothesis. Or is it events in other countries within a certain time period? Clearly, many Ukrainians appeared motivated by the experiences of Serbians and Georgians to believe that victory was possible. Perhaps most intriguing is the question of whether there is some sort of regional boundary to examples. Can Egyptians be affected by what happened in Ukraine? Or is this mass-level learning limited only to experiences in countries of a similar type? Was there perhaps some sort of post-communist boundary to this learning effect?

We can also hypothesize that protest following electoral fraud should be more likely to occur in countries where citizens have more longstanding grievances against the state.102

One interesting example pointing in this direction is the “hanging chad” controversy of the 2000 U.S. presidential election. Occurring slightly more than a month after the Serbian Bulldozer Revolution, the U.S. Supreme Court ordered the state of Florida to stop counting ballots so as to effectively declare the winner of the election. In Georgia, Ukraine, and Serbia, announcements of the “official” results by central election commissions did nothing to stem the tide of protests and, if anything, probably only exacerbated the protests. In Serbia, the pronouncements of the Supreme Court did little to stem the tide of the Bulldozer Revolution. And yet in the United States, there was absolutely nothing reminiscent of large-scale protests. While there are obviously many, many differences between the United States and the colored revolution countries, it does call into question the extent to which abusive regimes are sowing the long term seeds of their own destruction. More specifically, would citizens in the United States have reacted differently to the Supreme Court ruling had the government been thought of as corrupt as Serbians considered their own government to be?

Operationalizing such a test would of course be difficult, although I suggested earlier that perhaps levels of corruption could function as a reasonable proxy. Understanding the functional form of this relationship would seem to be particularly important. Is it essentially a tipping model, where electoral fraud leads to protest in certain types of societies, but not in others? Or is it more linear, where incrementally more grievances lead to an incrementally greater likelihood of protest following electoral fraud?

In addition to generating specific hypotheses, applying the collective action framework to the colored revolutions also yields a number of interesting general questions for future research. First, I have argued here that electoral fraud is a particularly useful tool for solving collective action problems because of a number of special characteristics of elections—the fact that elections occur at repeated intervals, encourage opposition cooperation, invite international attention, etc.—but are there other events that can also fill this role? Certainly national holidays would seem to have the advantage of being regularly scheduled, and national disasters or political assassinations tend to invite international attention. How might such events compare to electoral fraud as facilitators of anti-regime protest?

Another interesting question is whether protest spurred by electoral fraud can be a long-term solution to Weingast's need for the citizenry to restrain the state, or whether there is something inherent in these types of protests that limit them simply to one-shot games. In the framework I have laid out here, the perceived chances of success in throwing the bums out motivates some of the individual decisions to act. It is interesting to consider what might happen a second time around. Would citizens emboldened by their previous success be that much more likely to act in the future? Or would the fact that the previous revolution had so quickly given way to yet another government willing to commit major electoral fraud decrease belief in the likelihood of real success, and therefore decrease the likelihood of a new set of protests?

Finally, history clearly offers multiple examples of major electoral frauds that have not led to protests, even in the post-cold war world.103

See Levitsky and Way 2006, ch.2, 71.

As my argument is not meant to be deterministic (e.g., electoral fraud always leads to protest), this raises the interesting question of whether there are systematic factors that can be identified that increase the likelihood of protests following electoral fraud. Many such potential factors have already been discussed in the article in the context of individual cost-benefit analyses—previous examples of successful protests, belief that the regime will not resort to force to counter protests, a unified opposition—but there may be other interesting factors to explore both within and beyond this framework. More generally, why are some regimes able to pull off fraudulent elections with much less response from the citizenry than others?

Regardless of what the answers to these questions turn out to be, they share the common feature of arising from thinking about the colored revolutions not primarily in terms of the actions of elites, but instead from considering the motivations of the individuals that came out on to the streets to participate in them. Doing so can add both to our understanding of the causes and implications of these revolutions, but also to our understanding of the phenomenon of protest more generally. In this way, the colored revolutions serve as another example of the importance of, to quote Pam Oliver's aptly titled article, “Bringing the Crowds Back In.”104

Oliver 1989.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2005. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Arel, Dominique. 2005. “The ‘Orange Revolution’: Analysis and Implications of the 2004 Presidential Election in Ukraine.” Third Annual Stasiuk-Cambridge Lecture on Contemporary Ukraine, Cambridge University, February 25, in Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 340 (March 9).
Badkhen, Anna. 2003. “‘Velvet Revolution’ in Georgia.” San Francisco Chronicle, November 23, A3, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Baker, Peter, and Susan Glasser. 2005. Kremlin Rising: Vladimir Putin's Russia and the End of Revolution. New York: Scribner.
Beissinger, Mark R. 2002. Nationalist Mobilization and the Collapse of the Soviet State. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.
Beissinger, Mark R. 2007. Structure and example in modular political phenomena: The diffusion of Bulldozer/Rose/Orange/Tulip Revolutions. Perspectives on Politics 4 (2): 25976.Google Scholar
Bieber, Florian. 2003. The Serbian opposition and civil society: Roots of the delayed transition in Serbia. International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society 17 (1): 7390.Google Scholar
Birch, Sarah. 2002. The 2000 elections in Yugoslavia: the “Bulldozer Revolution.” Electoral Studies 21: 499511.Google Scholar
Bunce, Valerie. 2005. “Domestic Conditions and Democracy Promotion.” Presented at Roundtable on U.S. Democracy Promotion in Post-Communist Societies, U.S. Department of State, May 18.
Bunce, Valerie, and Sharon Wolchik. 2005. “Promoting Democracy after Communism: Electoral Revolutions in Slovakia, Serbia, Georgia, Ukraine, and Kyrgyzstan.” Ithaca, NY. Manuscript.
Chivers, C. J. 2005Back Channels: A Crackdown Averted: How Top Spies in Ukraine Changed the Nation's Path.” New York Times, January 17, 1.
Chong, Dennis. 1991. Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Cokgezen, Murat. 2004. Corruption in Kyrgyzstan: The facts, causes, and consequences. Central Asian Survey 23 (1): 7994.Google Scholar
Cullison, Alan, and Guy Chazan. 2004. “Putin's Role in Ukraine Election Stirs Backlash.” Wall Street Journal, November 29. In Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 290 November 29, 2005.
Curtis, Jessicah. 2005. “The Day the Tulip Revolution Came.” The Independent (London), March 25, 2425, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Devdariani, Jaba. 2004. Georgia: Rise and fall of the facade democracy.” Demokratizatsiya 12 (1): 79115.Google Scholar
Eudes, Marielle, and Nikolai Topuria. 2003. “Georgia Plans Presidential Elections for January 4 after ‘Rose Revolution,’Agence France Presse, November 25, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Fairbanks, Charles H. 2004. “Georgia's Rose Revolution.” Journal of Democracy 15 (2): 11024.Google Scholar
Fournier, Anna. Forthcoming. “Ukraine's Orange Revolution: Beyond Soviet Citizenship?” In The Contest for Social Mobilization in Ukraine, ed. P. D'Anieri. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Gruda, Agnès. 2004. “Generation Orange: The protest's driving force is the fearless youth,” La Presse (Canada), December 5, trans. George Zakhem. In Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 301 (December 5, 2004).
Guzelova, Irena. 2000. “New Candidate May Split Serbia Opposition Vote.” Financial Times, August 7, 7.
Heintz, Jim. 2005. “Dissatisfaction High in Kyrgyzstan Ahead of Elections Seen as Test of Commitment to Democracy.” Associated Press, February 27, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Herd, Graeme P. 2005. Colorful revolutions and the CIS: “Manufactured” versus “managed” democracy. Problems of Post-Communism 52 (2): 318.Google Scholar
Holley, David. 2004. “Snowy Tent City Holds Soul of Ukraine Protest: Opposition backers at the huge encampment believe they can alter the course of history.” Los Angeles Times, November 28. In Johnson's Russia List (JRL), No. 8472 (November 28, 2004).
Javeline, Debra. 2003a. Protest and the Politics of Blame: The Russian Response to Unpaid Wages. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Javeline, Debra. 2003b. The role of blame in collective action: Evidence from Russia. American Political Science Review 97 (1): 10721.Google Scholar
Jeremy Page hears two views from the battlefront,” Times (London), November 27, 2004, in Johnson's Russia List (JRL), No. 8471 (November 27, 2004).
Johnson, Andrew. 2003. “Power Struggle Breaks Out in Georgia as Opposition Proclaims Velvet Revolution.” Independent on Sunday (London), November 23, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Karatnycky, Adrian. 2005. Ukraine's Orange Revolution. Foreign Affairs 84 (2): 3552.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1991. Now out of never: The element of surprise in the East European revolution of 1989. World Politics 44 (1): 748.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1995. The inevitability of future revolutionary surprises. American Journal of Sociology 100 (6): 152851.Google Scholar
Kuzio, Taras. 2005a. From Kuchma to Yushchenko: Ukraine's 2004 presidential elections and the Orange Revolution. Problems of Post-Communism 50 (2): 2944.Google Scholar
Kuzio, Taras. 2005b. The opposition's road to success. Journal of Democracy 16 (2): 11730.Google Scholar
Lantukhina, Kira, and Maksim Glikin. 2005. “Political Animals.” Nezavisimaya Gazeta, April 1, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan Way. 2002. Elections without democracy: The rise of competitive authoritarianism. Journal of Democracy 13 (2): 5165.Google Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan Way. 2006. “Competitive Authoritarianism: The Origins and Evolution of Hybrid Regimes After the Cold War.” Toronto, Canada. Manuscript.
Lowe, Christian. 2003. “People power wins the day as Georgian leadership crumbles.” Agence France Presse, November 22, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
McFaul, Michael. 2005. Transitions from oostcommunism. Journal of Democracy 16 (3): 519.Google Scholar
McLaughlin, Daniel. 2005. “Monitors Cite Flaws in Central Asian Polls.” Irish Times, March 1, 11, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Myers, Steven Lee. 2005. “Ukraine President Sworn In Promising to Promote Unity,” New York Times, January 24. In Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 336 (January 25, 2005).
O'Donnell, Guillermo, and Philippe Schmitter. 1986. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Oliver, Pam. 1989. Bringing the crowd back in. Research in Social Movements, Conflict, and Change 11:130.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action; Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Page, Jeremy. 2005a. “From West to East, Rolling Revolution Gathers Pace across the Former USSR.” Times (London), February 19, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Page, Jeremy. 2005b. “Poll Protest in Kyrgyzstan Echoes Orange Revolution.” Times (London), March 16, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Page, Jeremy. 2005c. “Opposition Seize Second City in Kyrgyzstan Election Revolt.” The Times (London), March 22, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Phillips, Leigh. 2003. “Sugar daddies and revolutions; Georgia's revolt was something to celebrate. Does it matter that it was funded by a billionaire?New Statesman, December 8, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Racin, Stefan. 2000a. “Serbia's Opposition Blocs Begin Mud-Slinging.” United Press International (UPI), August 7, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Racin, Stefan. 2000b. “Yugoslav Election Panel Says Milosevic, Rival to Vie in 2nd Round.” UPI, September 26, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Savic, Misha. 2000. “Angry protesters meet in Belgrade for anti-Milosevic rally.” UPI, October 5, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Schipani-Aduriz, Andres, and Alyaksandr Kudrytski. 2005. “Belarus: Banana Revolutions and Banana Skins.” Transitions Online, September 7. http://www.tol.cz/look/TOL/article.tpl?IdLanguage=1&IdPublication=4&NrIssue=132&NrSection=3&NrArticle=14432.
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Mark S. Bonchek. 1997. Analyzing Politics: Rationality, Behavior and Institutions. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
Silitski, Vitali. 2005. Is the age of post-Soviet electoral revolutions over? Democracy at Large 1 (4): 810.Google Scholar
Spencer, Richard. 2005. “Kyrgyzstan President Flees Tulip Revolution.” Daily Telegraph (London), March 25, 13, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Stephen, Chris. 2005. “Governor Held Captive in Election Protest.” Irish Times, March 17, 9, accessed in Lexis-Nexis.
Stier, Ken. 2003. “It Could Have Gone Badly.” Newsweek, December 8, Atlantic ed., 60, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Strauss, Julius. 2003. “‘He Left Us to Starve. Now He is Gone.’Daily Telegraph (London), November 24, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Tarrow, Sidney G. 1994. Power in Movement: Social Movements, Collective Action, and Politics. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.
Thompson, Mark R., and Philipp Kuntz. 2004. Stolen elections: The case of the Serbian October. Journal of Democracy 15 (4): 15972.Google Scholar
Thompson, Mark R., and Philipp Kuntz. 2005. “More than Just the Final Straw: Stolen Elections as Revolutionary Triggers.” Presented at the Conference on Authoritarian Regimes: Conditions for Stability and Change, Swedish Institute, Istanbul, Turkey, May 29–31.
Todorovic, Alex. 2000. “Serb Vote Holds Hope for Change.” Christian Science Monitor, August 2, 6.
Topuria, Nikolai. 2003a. “Georgian leadership on ropes as opposition launches ‘Velvet Revolution.’Agence France Presse, November 22, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Topuria, Nikolai. 2003b. “Mikhail Saakashvili, Architect of Georgia's ‘Velvet Revolution.’Agence France Presse, November 22, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Tunnard, Christopher R. 2003. The “anarchy” of the Internet: The changing influence of communications and information in Serbia in the 1990s. Southeast European and Black Sea Studies 3 (2): 97120.Google Scholar
U.S. State Department,, 2005a. Country Background Notes: Ukraine, February 2005. http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/3211.htm, most recently accessed September 15, 2005.
U.S. State Department. 2005b. Country Background Notes: Kyrgyzstan, July 2005 http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/5755.htm, last accessed September 18.
Vladimirov, Andrei. 2005. “Revoliutsiia na Eksport” (Revolution for Export), Itogi, December 7, 2004.
Way, Lucan. 2005a. Kuchma's failed authoritarianism. Journal of Democracy 16 (2): 131.Google Scholar
Way, Lucan. 2005b. Rapacious individualism and political competition in Ukraine: 1992–2004. Communist and Post-Communist Studies 38: 191205.Google Scholar
Way, Lucan. 2006. “Identity and Autocracy: Belarus and Ukraine Compared”. Presented at 2nd Annual Danyliw Research Seminar in Contemporary Ukrainian Studies, Toronto, Canada, October 12–14.
Weingast, Barry M. 1997. The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law. American Political Science Review 91 (2): 24563.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry M. 2005. Self-Enforcing Constitutions: With an Application to Democratic Stability In America's First Century. Palo Alto, CA. Manuscript.
Weir, Fred. 2005. “Kyrgyz Politicians Strike Deal That Could Undo ‘Tulip’ Revolt.” Christian Science Monitor, March 29, 7, accessed through Lexis-Nexis.
Wheeler, Carolynne, and Mark MacKinnon. 2004. “Yushchenko claims victory in Ukraine election.” Globe and Mail, December 27. In Dominique Arel, “The Ukraine List (UKL),” No. 327 (December 27, 2004).
Wilson, Andrew. 2005. Ukraine's Orange Revolution. New Haven: Yale University Press.